Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted Dr. Noel D.L. Olsen, MSc, FRCP, FFPHM.

WATER AND SEWAGE CHARGES—A FAILURE OF SOCIAL JUSTICE

  Over the last couple of years I have chaired WaterVoice in the South West, where average water and sewage charges are currently around 10% of a state pension. For negligible public health benefit and questionable environmental benefits water customers are again destined to see their bills rise substantially over the next five years. As a public health doctor I have been involved professionally with the links between poverty and health for many years, and I felt that I should add a personal contribution to the formal evidence you will be receiving from WaterVoice and others on the impacts of high water charges on poor, vulnerable people. I am particularly concerned at the inequity caused by current Defra and Ofwat policies and the resultant adverse effect on social justice.

  For many people in Devon and Cornwall water and sewage charges are a nightmare. They have reached a point where their affordability has become a threat to public health. Unlike fuel poverty, the government has failed to set a target level for reduction of "water poverty" and there has been no public funding for programmes to alleviate the resulting hardship in areas with exceptionally high water and sewage charges. There has been a failure to recognise that some costs are cumulative on very poor people. If avoiding falling into debt is to be achieved, a concern amongst many elderly, vulnerable people, water, energy, council tax, some basic transport facilities and housing costs have to be paid before any residual income can be used for food and other priorities. In all other policy areas government makes some social welfare or public spending provision for high unavoidable costs. For example, railways and roads are massively subsidised from the public purse. Our heritage is respected and partially supported; museums and art galleries in London are supported by taxation but beaches in Cornwall, another national asset are not. Fuel poverty has been a major concern of government and is the subject off major initiatives. But water customers are expected to pay all the water company costs and the effects of regulation and quality improvements even if they are not affordable. State pensions and other benefits are paid at a standard national rate which does not reflect local costs, leading to major problems for those with far higher but unavoidable costs such as water and sewage charges in Cornwall. A poor diet and social isolation are inevitable if debt is to be avoided and an excessive charge absorbed out of a standard pension income. In the "illustrative case histories" appended the impact of water charges on living standards are shown.

  Cornwall has the lowest wage economy in England, the highest charges for water, and a high proportion of the population are not on mains gas so there is an added component to fuel poverty. Public transport infrastructure is poor and for many people in rural areas there is no choice but to run a car, leading to the permanent residents running some of the oldest and most inefficient vehicles in the UK. Because of the superb environment the area is attractive to second home owners so house prices have been pushed to levels unattainable to the local population. The people with second homes come to enjoy the tremendous environmental benefits of the region, make great use of the surfing beaches, and tend to use their homes at peak (high cost) times. This uneven use has required higher capital investment in water and sewage services so that peak summer use can be met.

  In effect occasional metered summer residents receive a subsidy from local pensioners and others for sewage infrastructure and the resultant clean beaches and rivers because Ofwat's (and Minister's?) policies do not distribute the cost of the vast capital infrastructure in an equitable way. For bureaucratic convenience Ofwat have decided that the cost of capital infrastructure, (48% of the total bill in Devon and Cornwall) should be apportioned either by rateable value or on the basis of the metered volume of water used. There might once have been some social justice or relevance in rateable value, but the system is now flawed and out of date. Volume going through a meter is not a valid proxy for cost on its own without a substantial standing charge which Ministers and Ofwat have repeatedly rejected. Added volume through the sewerage system does add some marginal costs, but as with owning a car or a house many of the costs are fixed and extra use comes at marginal cost provided the infrastructure is adequate. With about half of the total water and sewage cost due to infrastructure capital costs, those who enjoy the amenity of a connection and the clean rivers and beaches but use relatively little metered water end up paying little towards the benefit. Thus an added burden falls inequitably on others, particularly families who inevitably consume a lot of water and pensioners who would usually be well advised to go onto a meter. Many old people while sparing in their use of water are unaware or afraid of meters and have not shifted over. If they all did there is cause for concern that the shift might bring forward the collapse of the financial systems of the water industry which are already stretched. This is demonstrated in the enclosed "illustrative case histories" to try to simplify some of the issues.

  "Objective one" status has recognised the economic problems of the region, but unlike the rest of Europe, this money has not been used to fund water and sewage infrastructure because technically these assets belong to a private company as a result of water privatisation. Lack of imagination on all sides has meant that solutions have not been sought, for example, the investment could be funded by Europe, the facility "owned" by a public sector organisation and then operated on a cost plus basis by South West Water. When water was privatised the SW peninsula was given far less than its fair share of the "green dowry" to fund the necessary infrastructure. While this is a fundamental cause of the present difficulties, I recognise that no Chancellor will now intervene to correct that historic injustice.

  A sustainable approach requires a concern for current affordability and some sense of social justice. While no doubt desirable in absolute terms, some of the wish list from the water quality regulators (Environment Agency, Drinking Water Inspectorate and English Nature) will, in my view, add an unjustifiable cost burden to vulnerable people and thereby create public health problems, not alleviate them. In terms of DALY's (disability adjusted life years—a WHO method for assessing the economic benefit of health procedures), removing nitrates to the level now being proposed is not justifiable on public health grounds. Yet the cost of removing them will fall on water customers, not on agriculture which is responsible for most "diffuse" pollution. This is a failure of the "polluter must pay principle". Methaemoglobinaemia in babies, the major public health justification for reducing nitrite levels, is not a risk even at current levels—there have never been cases at these levels. Indeed the only cases (?2) over many decades in the UK have come from unregulated private water supplies at vastly higher levels. Compare these "public health benefit" costs and their DALY's with the probable knock on effects on nutrition, and particularly fruit consumption, caused by high water bills and you see the fallacy of the so called DWI "public health justification" for action. Public health, like politics, requires a balancing act over priorities. I am not aware of any public health organisations or significant sources of balanced public health argument that would see further reductions in nitrate levels justifiable if much of the cost has to be borne by the poorest in the community with resulting increase in the health effects of poverty. Many would question if there is any value at all.

  Our long and beautiful coastline is enjoyed by people from all over the UK, but 3% of the population have to fund 30% of the nationally recognised "bathing water directive" beaches. Tourism is a major and important driver to the economy, but it brings few benefits to most pensioners surviving on state benefits. Indeed in many aspects it detracts from their standard of living.

  What is needed is a change of policy. There are a number of ways in which greater social justice could be achieved. At national level, a top-up voucher system could be introduced so that pensioners and/or all those on benefits could be subsidised to the level of the average water bill in the UK. If paid to water companies rather than to the beneficiaries it could be cheap to administer. The winter fuel payment is another precedent. The cost could either come from a redistributed national water levy or from general taxation. In view of the strong regulation that Ofwat exerts, the effect on company profits and efficiency and therefore shareholder value could be at whatever level the Chancellor decided. It would at least introduce a measure of equity to those on the lowest income who are dependent on state welfare alone.

  At a local level Ofwat could also change its policies. It would be entirely feasible to add a standing charge to reflect the proportion of the cost which is attributable to infrastructure and pay at a marginal additional rate for the water consumed. Alternatively, the standing charge could fund the average annual water requirements of a pensioner or pensioner couple, and all those using more would pay at an appropriate additional rate. Managing change would be difficult and those who have done well out of the present system would be annoyed. But to take no action is to continue an inequitable system for ever and sooner or later there is a danger that water charges will become the focus of "poll tax like" resentment. That can be in nobody's interest and the effect could be devastating on the water companies. The charging structure is largely imposed on them by Ofwat and they have little room for manoeuvre but it is demonstrably inequitable, and water companies have to take most of the blame from consumers.

  I am sending a personal copy of this paper to those MPs representing SW constituencies and to Phillip Fletcher, the Director General of Ofwat. I would be happy to expand on any of the issues and provide any further interest you would like.

18 October 2003


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 18 December 2003