Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Processed Vegetable Growers' Association

IMPLEMENTATION OF CAP REFORM IN THE UK

INTRODUCTION

  1.  The Processed Vegetable Growers' Association (PVGA) has a membership of approximately 1,000 farmers covering around 400,000 hectares, growing field scale vegetables and potatoes for processing, in particular peas and beans for freezing and canning. The issues faced by our members under CAP Reform are shared by thousands of other farmers who have grown, or let out land for, unsupported crops in the reference period 2000-02.

  2.  This submission concentrates on the impact on growers of potatoes, vegetables and other unsupported crops, who operate in finely balanced markets, and are particularly vulnerable to the discrimination and market distortion that would result from the allocation of entitlements based on individual historical claims (IHC),

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  3.  CAP reform should ensure equal treatment between farmers, avoid market and competition distortion, minimise redistribution, keep money with working farmers, and be transparent and justifiable to the public. The allocation of Single Farm Payments based on individual historical claims (IHC) fails badly on nearly all counts. The regional average payment approach (RAP) causes too much redistribution in the livestock sector. The hybrid option is the only way forward.

  4.  IHC would be seriously damaging to some 10,000 farmers who would receive no entitlements for land occupied by unsupported crops in the reference period 2000-02, and would lose their right to return to supported cropping with equal treatment. They would be locked into reference period cropping and vulnerable to exploitation from buyers.

  5.  Under IHC unsupported crop growers will face unfair competition from farmers in other Member States, possibly other UK regions, and certainly the 10 Accession States that will have a regional approach. In the case of novel crops such as borage they will suffer direct competition form other farmers in England with aid.

  6.  IHC would distort land values and place disproportionate burden of cross compliance on unsupported crop growers.

  7.  The hybrid option would allow the livestock sector to remain 90% based on historical claims, supplemented by a 10% regional payment, while the problems of the unsupported arable sector would be resolved with a regional payment.

  8.  The hybrid solution would resolve a large number of transitional issues and reduce the cost and uncertainty of appeals. It would not be as simple and cheap to administer as RAP, but probably no more complex and costly as IHC.

  9.  CAP reform on the hybrid principle is a good fit with the vision of the Policy Commission on Farming and Food.

DETAILED SUBMISSION

  In addressing the questions raised by the Committee, we start by considering:

    WHAT IMPACT WILL IMPLEMENTATION HAVE ON THE AGRICULTURAL SECTOR, PARTICULARLY WHEN TAKING ACCOUNT OF APPROACHES TO CAP REFORM IN OTHER EU MEMBER STATES?

Historical approach disastrous for unsupported sectors

  10.  CAP reform would have a serious negative effect on the presently unsupported sectors of agriculture if the allocation of entitlements for the Single Farm Payment (SFP) is based on individual historical claims (IHC). Farmers would receive no entitlements for land occupied by unsupported crops in the reference period 2000-02. The effect would be to fix farm support for the next 10 years in an arbitrary time warp.

Large numbers affected

  11.  It might be tempting to think that those adversely affected by the IHC approach are an insignificant minority. Not so; according to the 2002 Agricultural Census, potatoes were grown on 7,728 holdings in England, field vegetables on 5,761 and other arable crops (which includes unsupported combinable crops such as borage) on 3,449. There will be some overlap in these numbers, but they are likely to total at least 10,000, representing some of the most dynamic, market-focused farming businesses in the country. These are the farmers who have responded to the challenge to diversify away from supported surplus commodities.

Loss of flexibility and market focus

  12.  Article 51 of the Regulation provides for "the negative list" which, under IHC, would prevent any farmer from claiming SFP entitlements on land used for potatoes, vegetables and soft fruit. This gives some protection to existing growers of unsupported crops from unfair competition from neighbours with entitlements. But, under IHC, the unsupported crop growers will lose their right to return to supported crops with equal treatment, losing flexibility and market focus.

  13.  Under IHC, unsupported crop growers will be locked into reference period cropping and vulnerable to exploitation from buyers. They would lose the market focus that de-coupling is intended to strengthen. In the past, the growers' negotiating position with his customer (dominated by large multinationals) has been underpinned by his ability to switch into supported combinable crops. The loss of this option will seriously weaken the growers' position, and we are already seeing signs that buyers will abuse this situation.

Example from the pea industry

  14.  A clear example of this problem can be seen in the vining pea industry. Over the years we have seen pea prices moving in a loose correlation with wheat prices, as one side or the other based its negotiating position on the returns from an alternative cereal crop. When wheat prices rose between 1993 and 1996, growers were able to push up pea prices. Since then it has been relentless downward pressure with buyers aware of the lower returns from cereals. Under IHC the alternative to growing vining peas is no longer cereals with area aid, but cereals without area aid, and the growers' position is hopelessly undermined. So instead of seeing pea prices rise for next year to reflect the 50%+ rise in wheat prices, we are now seeing growers squeezed even further.

  15.  We have already seen one of our member co-operatives lose its long-term supply contract for 2004 for refusing to accept a 16% price cut demanded by its customer. The growers will now have to face the future with neither pea contract nor entitlements. Some might argue that the position is caused by oversupply, but that itself is partly caused, and certainly exacerbated, by the loss of options to growers under IHE.

  16.  The UK is the largest producer of frozen peas in Europe—second only to the US in the world—but we can see growers under similar pressure in other negotiations and the future for the industry under IHC is bleak.

Why should unsupported growers need subsidy now when they resisted it before?

  17.  It might be argued that growers of unsupported crops chose to operate without subsidy in the past and should not now try to climb back on board the subsidy train. Indeed the vining pea growers, represented by this Association, campaigned successfully against the inclusion of the crop in the IACS scheme in the mid '90s. However, there is a big difference between growing without subsidy whilst retaining the option to revert to subsidised crops, and being permanently excluded with all the consequences outlined here.

  18.  It has been suggested that if unsupported growers benefited from a regional payment they would be squeezed by the big buyers—retailers and processors—and that aid would be passed on down the supply chain. Such an argument misses the point—there will be the same downward pressure on price whether or not vegetable growers receive aid.

Novel crop growers doubly hit

  19.  Growers of unsupported crops not protected by the negative list, such as borage and other novel crops, will face unfair competition from farmers who have not grown these crops during the reference period and who, under IHC, will have entitlements from supported combinable crops. There is already clear evidence that buyers are contracting with growers who will have entitlements under IHC when the new scheme comes into being. It is reasonable to suppose that this will lead to downward price pressure at the expense of the traditional growers.

Capital values

  20.  Unsupported crop growers will be further penalised by devaluation of their capital base. Land with payment entitlements will be worth upwards of £1,500 per hectare more than similar land without entitlements.

Farms in transition

  21.  Growers who have changed from unsupported to supported crops since the reference years will be particularly hard hit. Between 2001 (the middle year of the reference period) and 2003 22,800 hectares has come out of unsupported crops but will miss out on the allocation of entitlements under IHC:
Thousand hectares   2001  2003
Horticultural crops  154.9   157.8
Potatoes  126.0  108.8
Sugar beet  177.3   162.0
Other arable crops    11.8   18.6
2471.02450.2

Source: DEFRA June Census Stats 46/03 1 December 2003

Rotation and good agricultural practice

  22.  Growers of specialist crops frequently rent land from other farmers in the interest of good agricultural practice, to improve rotations and reduce pest and disease problems. The combination of IHC together with the three-year use it or lose it rule (Art 45) will put constraints on this essential land dynamics. Much of the national potato acreage is grown on land rented for the season by specialist growers from ordinary farmers who will lose their entitlements under IHC.

Cross-compliance

  23.  Unsupported crop growers will bear the same cross-compliance obligations over their entire farm area, but with less aid to fund them.

Market and competition distortion

  24.  The degree of Member State flexibility within the new Regulation opens the door for market and competition distortion between the Member States and between regions within a Member State. The adoption of IHC in England would leave our industry at a disadvantage compared to competitors in other Member States, the ten accession countries, and even possibly other UK regions, choosing a regionalised approach. Competition from potato and vegetable growers in those countries receiving decoupled aid would put at risk the future viability of vulnerable sectors of our industry. The only solution is to adopt regional averaging for the arable area of England.

  25.  Some have suggested that that our cereal producers would be at risk from competition distortion if they were at a disadvantage of approximately

55 per hectare, compared with continental producers, as a result of regional averaging. How much more devastating would it be for unsupported growers against competition with

300+ per hectare advantage?

FOLLOWING WHAT PRINCIPLES AND BY WHAT METHOD SHOULD THE UNITED KINGDOM IMPLEMENT THE PROPOSALS?

Purpose of public support for agriculture

  26.  There has been debate on the purpose of the Single Farm Payment. The argument that it is compensation for price cuts dating back to the commencement of IACS in 1992 is not sustainable through to 2012. Nor is it simply a payment for providing environmental services to the public. It is an income support scheme to enable farmers to farm the land in a way that keeps the countryside how the British public likes to see it. The alternative economics would drive us to farm the land on a prairie scale with as much regard for the environment as some of our international competitors.

Guiding principles

  27.  The UK should implement the reform in the way that best suits the interests of a dynamic and forward looking industry for the next ten years. It should ensure equal treatment between farmers; avoid market and competition distortion; minimise redistribution; ensure that losses for individual businesses are not punitive or financially crippling; and keep money with working farmers. Above all it should be transparent and justifiable to the public and the taxpayer.

Regional averaging

  28.  The regional average payments approach (RAP) achieves most of these principles. However, in the livestock sectors where current support is not area based, this would lead to an unacceptable degree of redistribution.

Hybrid option

  29.  The solution lies in the hybrid option—Option G in the DEFRA paper on regional options of October 2003. [4]This uses the provisions in the regulation for "part ceilings" to be distributed among all the farmers in the region, and for member states to fix a different unit value for grassland. This would allow the livestock sector to retain for example 90% of its decoupled aid on a historical basis, with the remaining 10% spread as a regional payment to all the grassland in the region. At the same time, the Arable Area Payment Scheme (AAPS) money could be spread across all the arable land as a regional payment. Whilst there would be some dilution of aid for the sector, there would be no major individual losers.

  30.  This would secure a fairer distribution of payments for the purposes of direct cross compliance, a significant reduction in the number of farmers forced to rely on the national reserve as well as fairer treatment for growers of unsupported crops, who would otherwise forgo all future entitlement to support. This option would avoid significant redistribution within the livestock sector and cross-subsidisation between livestock and arable sectors, whilst retaining much of the essential simplicity of the RAP approach.

Arable sector

  31.  In the arable sector, under the hybrid solution the AAPS money would be diluted by about 15% as a result of spreading it across all the arable land. Against this, however, should be offset the savings that would be available (compared with IHE) from the reduced call on the hardship fund and national reserve, which would probably bring the real dilution figure down to about 10-12%. The only farmers who would lose this much would be those who have grown nothing but AAPS crops, who have not let out any land for potatoes or vegetables, who have not taken on any land since the reference period, and who have not been involved in environmental schemes (eg NSA) in the reference period.

High administrative cost and uncertainty of IHC

  32.  One advantage of the regional approach is that it would be more up-to-date; entitlements going to those farming the land in 2005 rather than the reference period 2000-02. The allocation of entitlements under IHC would result in vast numbers of appeals by farmers who have expanded since the reference period or who claim under the "hardship cases" as a result of environmental schemes. This would give rise to a huge bureaucratic cost to farmers and Government, uncertainty for the individuals involved and for the industry as a whole since the call on the hardship fund and national reserve would be unpredictable. It would not be possible to resolve all such appeals until final allocations are possible in 2008, since farmers would have up to three years to claim all their entitlements before they would be lost to the national reserve.

  Loss to working farmers under IHC

  33.  The IHC approach would allocate entitlements to farmers who have retired or reduced their activity since the reference period. It would also give rise to "naked" land, leading to undue trade in entitlements and the temptation for retiring farmers to transfer high value entitlements to low value land.

Transitional problems resolved by regionalisation

  34.  The hybrid solution would resolve all these transitional issues at least in respect of the arable land. Transfers of entitlements should be restricted to those necessary to accompany bona fide land transfers, keeping more of the money with working farmers, and reducing the money flowing out of the industry in professional fees and retirement plans.

Regional approach simplest to administer

  35.  In terms of administrative simplicity, the RAP approach is by far the easiest and cheapest option. After that, there is probably not much to choose between the pure IHC and the hybrid option.

  36.  IHC would probably be more costly to set up initially, and would lead to large numbers of claims and appeals under the hardship and national reserve provisions. There would also be more transfers of entitlements to control and register. On the other hand, the hybrid solution would create some extra work as a result of the negative list and the additional claims that would probably arise.

HOW DOES IMPLEMENTATION OF THE PROPOSALS OF THE POLICY COMMISSION ON THE FUTURE OF FARMING AND FOOD MESH WITH WIDER REFORM OF THE CAP?

The Commission Vision

  37.  The Commission envisaged a profitable and sustainable farming industry, able to compete internationally, continuing to receive payment from the public purse, but only for public benefits that the public wants and needs. It saw farmers looking after the countryside, not just when they could afford to, but as core business; cropping decisions taken for good commercial reasons; close engagement with consumers; and the eventual removal of the existing CAP system.

RAP or Hybrid fits, not IHC

  38.  CAP Reform will fit this vision if implemented in a fair and equitable way under a regionalised or hybrid system. If the reform is based on history, some sectors will struggle to retain profitability and international competitiveness; cropping decisions will be based on the wrong reasons; and the environmental burden will be much more onerous for some than for others.

CONCLUSION

  39.  Given that there is probably little to choose between the hybrid option and the individual historical approach in terms of administration costs, then the decision on which to implement should be based on philosophy and public justification. In both respects, and in accordance with the true principles of de-coupling, only the hybrid option qualifies.

Processed Vegetable Growers' Association

December 2003






4   DEFRA paper Options for Regional Averaging (October 2003) outlines a number of options permissible within the terms of the Regulation. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 6 May 2004