Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Family Farmers' Association

IMPLEMENTATION OF CAP REFORM IN THE UK

  1.  The Committee of the Family Farmers' Association looks at this sort of question from a long-term point of view. We are interested in the whole future of the countryside, believing that much of the character of Britain still depends on the existence of family farms. We do not wish to see farming become an industrial type of activity, where only very large units, be they arable or livestock, produce food for the nation. It is believed by many that food imported cheaply from other parts of the world, where labour and land are cheap and regulations minimal, is liable to spell the end of family farming; also to produce a great deterioration in the appearance and general health of the countryside. We consider the likely effects of CAP reform in this light.

  2.  One of the main comments of the committee was that, in fact, the international balance of production and consumption would have more effect on the future of farming than the CAP has. Some countries, such as Brazil, are apparently set to increase their production enormously. Some NFU members believe that the increasingly affluent Eastern countries will happily absorb this production and it will not come this way. Some people feel that if beef production, for instance, becomes uneconomic after subsidies are decoupled, and less is produced, prices will rise. Others believe that the void will be filled by imports and there will be no consequential rise in prices.

  3.  Imports apart, it seems highly likely that cycles will develop in the absence of the stabilising effect of subsidies. Lower profitability of any product will reduce production. This reduced supply will raise prices. Greater production will follow which will, in turn, reduce prices, leading to restriction of supply and higher prices again. Such a cycle has bedevilled the pig industry for as long as anyone can remember. The grave disadvantage of cycles is that the period of low returns always eliminates smaller producers who have not been able to build up reserves. In the particular case of pigs the cycle phenomenon has led to the elimination of vast numbers of pig farmers and extreme concentration into very large units.

  Such a situation seems only too probable in dairying, and likely in most types of farming.

  4.  Another basic issue raised was the extent to which agricultural land will be used to produce fuel and power. Biomass to convert to electricity could use up an enormous amount of land if subsidised sufficiently to make it economic. Likewise a variety of crops can be converted to liquid fuel given the right incentive. Will we see subsidies for food crops replaced by subsidies for fuel crops? Another way of meeting Kyoto obligations would be to import the raw materials for manufacturing fuel and power. Can we afford this in addition to importing a large proportion of our food if it becomes uneconomic to produce it here?

  5.  More specifically to CAP Reform: The argument rages as to whether the single farm payments should be on a historic or an area basis, though this may possibly be settled before your committee reports. It does not seem necessary to rehearse all the arguments in detail, but a few comments must be made. In general, the case for area payments seems very much stronger. It will be manifestly simpler to administer and is more logical. Payment can hardly be called "decoupled" if it is based entirely on the level of production—even if that production is historic. Those who caused allegedly excess production in the past would be rewarded for ever more. Those who exercised restraint and sought to fill actual markets, rather than "chase subsidies", would lose.

  6.  There has not been much discussion of the proposition that historic payments would be tradable. This seems a totally illogical, almost abhorrent, idea. Surely there must be a reason or purpose for granting a subsidy? There can be no logic whatever in giving it to a person who has simply bought the right to it, even if he has also acquired some land to connect it to. The only remaining reason for paying a subsidy, if it is not to encourage food production, is to care for the land. Also, perhaps, to keep communities in the countryside. The simple and logical system must be to pay the subsidy to whoever is caring for the land now. Actively farming new entrants must be more deserving than elderly farmers who were drawing subsidies ten years previously!

  7.  Another argument against the historic method is that the more historic it becomes, the less happy people will be to pay it. One cannot imagine that in 2010 taxpayers will be happy to give large sums of money to a landowner because he produced intensively ten years previously. Still less if he never even farmed but has recently bought the entitlement and some land of some sort to attach it to. It has been suggested that if this course is chosen it is unlikely to last any longer than the reform of 2000, which was supposed to be the basis for many years to come.

  8.  Whichever method of calculation is used, we would, as usual, recommend that the payment should be tiered or tapered. The original intention was to give a band of small to-medium sized farmers exemption from deductions from their payments. This was quietly dropped from Mark II, with no explanation. Presumably because neither the government nor the NFU wished to give encouragement to smaller farmers. Our wish has always been that as subsidies reach a certain level, higher sums should have a progressive percentage reduction. For example, this might start at 5% on a payment over £20,000 and increase to the extent that a person who, according to the rule, was due £1 million should receive only half a million. In fact that could well be considered a ceiling. Large farmers should not object to such a plan, as it should ward off public objection to subsidies for non production.

  9.  Given the area system of payments should be adopted, there will be a problem of genuine hardship cases. The ones we would be concerned for would be smallish farmers who have worked hard and, of necessity, farmed fairly intensively to make a living. There would be a proportion who became non-viable with only area payments. The simplest solution would be to guarantee payment of not less than, say, 90% of previous subsidies, up to a certain limit. This was done for hill farmers when the Hill Farming Allowance was instituted. It could be time limited, and once the problem businesses were identified, serious efforts could be made to find solutions for them. What the solutions might be would depend on how the agricultural scene develops post decoupling.

  10.  A peculiar suggestion has been made about area payments. That is that payments for arable land should be much higher than for grassland. That would be manifestly unfair. If it is in fact the case that arable payments have always been higher than livestock ones, worked out in relation to area farmed, that does not make it any more fair! Arable farms tend to be larger, which will perpetuate the tendency for arable farmers to be richer than those who, on the whole, work harder caring for livestock year round. Some adjustment would be needed for hill and mountain land, but there does not seem any logical reason why well stocked lowland livestock farms, including dairy farms, should not receive the same payment per hectare as any arable farm.

  11.  As for the question of our competition with other European Union Member States, one can only assume that they will be better at adapting—or ignoring—the new rules and that this will be to our disadvantage. It has been a fact of life for decades that we have the lowest milk price in Europe. Many statistics show the profitability advantage—be it increase or absolute—to continental farmers and no doubt this will continue. What proportion of their advantage is due to more government backing and what proportion to better business acumen on the part of the farmers is difficult to tell.

  12.  What all farmers long for is to feel that the government values them. General opinion is that the fewer farmers there are the happier the government is. This theory is based on the government's regularly advocating "restructuring". This is proceeding apace, to the consternation of many, but apparently the government sees no harm in the large numbers of farmers exiting the industry. (Figures are quoted regularly, it does not seem necessary to repeat them.)

  13.  It would require an in depth study, for which we do not have the resources, to determine how many of Sir Don Curry's proposals have been implemented, or are in the process of implementation, and whether they have had any good effect. It seems that some are in operation, but it is probably too soon to judge if they are helpful. Although it is said that incomes have improved recently, that is only in certain sectors. The fact has not reduced the serious exodus from farming.

The Family Farmers' Association

December 2003


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 6 May 2004