Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Central Association of Agricultural Valuers

INQUIRY INTO IMPLEMENTATION OF CAP REFORM

  The Central Association of Agricultural Valuers (CAAV) represents, briefs and qualifies some 2,000 professionals who advise and act in a wide range of matters effecting rural and agricultural businesses throughout England and Wales. Instructed by a wide range of clients including farmers, landowners, lenders, public authorities, conservation bodies and others, this work does not simply consist of valuations but of an understanding of practice in all aspects bearing on rural land and business. As such, the work of CAAV members means they have a practical view of the issues involved in any such policy change, not limited by the interests and perspectives of any single client group.

1.  THE REFORM AND THE NEW MARKET PLACE

  1.1  The result of the Mid Term Review, as agreed in June 2003 and recorded in the Council Regulation 1782/2003 finally negotiated in September 2003, represents a radical change in the relationship between the state and agriculture and in the financial support offered to farmers.

  1.2  For the first time in most farmers' working lives most of the enterprises in which UK agriculture is involved will be producing for an essentially unsupported market place as the payment of future subsidies becomes decoupled from production decisions. This is a key change with potentially far reaching consequences as farmers will be now be free to respond primarily to the market rather than to the stimuli of product-related subsidies as has been the case for many decades and, particularly and most recently, under the MacSharry system with direct payments for each unit of production capacity (acres of eligible arable land in combinable crops, headage of suckler cows and ewes). Farmers will no longer be required to produce at all and, where they do produce, the subsidy system will not encourage them to stay with traditional commodity enterprises.

  1.3  While it is easy to focus on the requirements and opportunities of the Regulation, the new market place is the most important fact to come out of the reform and is the point that faces all farmers. Policy implementation should focus on farmers' need to make that essential adaptation.

  1.4  No commentator can foresee accurately how the new market place will develop. That lies in the hands of farmers reacting to the removal of subsidy linked payments, the probable reductions in marginal production, resulting price changes and new business opportunities—as well as all the impacts of each season's circumstances. For every general rule and trend, there will be individual exceptions. Basic analysis suggests that the suckler beef sector faces a particular issue as not only is keeping suckler cows decoupled from subsidy but at first the calf price may be reduced by the withdrawal of Beef Special Premium and Slaughter Premium. There is likely to be an overall reduction in EU cereals production, perhaps particularly in the Mediterranean areas where the subsidy already exceeds income from low yields. Many UK farms, perhaps concentrated in some areas, are also likely to reduce cereals areas in most years. Subject to issues of access to the EU market, lower production might increase prices for those who can remain in production. Equally, the reform removes obstacles to considering other non-traditional enterprises where these appear viable. Farmers will react to the stimuli around them, just as they did to production subsidies. Much will be new and uncertain at first and farmers should be given the greatest opportunity to make this transition effectively, after the years of hard economics they have seen as well as BSE and Foot and Mouth.

2.  PRINCIPLES FOR IMPLEMENTATION

  2.1  The unwinding of a long history of subsidy-influenced production decisions will be a major task. The CAAV urges that a key principle of the implementation of the Mid Term Review package should be that it is done in ways which ease the introduction of this new approach rather than complicate it. The successful delivery of this objective with the least damage to British farming is of great importance.

  2.2  Within this key focus, the CAAV proposes four principles:

    (i)  That the implementation be sensible and workable without pointless complication, needless bureaucracy or practical absurdity.

    (ii)  That the transition be as simple and as swift as possible without undue distortion of markets.

    (iii)  That the practicalities of what is proposed for the farm businesses that will have to live with the reform are understood.

    (iv)  That wherever possible the implementation gives affected farm businesses early certainty as to where they stand. As most farm planning is a long term matter for the small businesses involved, there is a business need for early decisions. Among other matters, these should cover the basis of allocation of entitlements, early notification of entitlements, early access to and decisions from the national reserve and perhaps forward validation of prospective transfers of entitlement. Such assistance would reduce the long hiatus during which many will anyway need to make major decisions—reform has been in the air for over a year yet the first payments and transfers under the new system may not be for another two years or more. Such an approach would make the transition both more smooth and more effective.

  2.3  While an obvious point, it must be stressed that the Government, British farming and its advisers can only work with the rules of the Regulation as agreed and the options it offers. The CAAV fears that a number of the points debated this autumn in England relate variously to options that are not available under the Regulation, regrets that the Regulation was not drafted to different effect and taking positions to influence future reforms. While understandable, this can obscure the practical job that is to hand.

  2.4  The CAAV supports full decoupling at the earliest possible date: 2005. The policy decisions have been taken in the agreed principles of the Regulation. Many British farm businesses have begun to prepare for the change and we see no gain that arises from delay in implementing the core principle of decoupling. It is expected that it is going to happen, delaying it simply freezes the business environment for even longer than is anyway the case. There seems no practical merit in trying to continue to run parts of the old system in conjunction with the new, requiring two sets of bureaucracy for both Government and farmers. It is recognised that there may be a competitive issue with those countries that delay until 2006 or 2007, and with those that retain partial coupling.

  2.5  The CAAV takes the same approach to the dairy premium and additional payment—they should be decoupled in 2005. We suggest that both payments should be allocated on a simple per litre basis, using the volume of quota available to the farmer on 31 March 2004 for the first payment. They should then be decoupled on the same per litre basis as at 31 March 2005. The short period in which it would necessarily be a coupled payment seems too short to develop other patterns of payment: these payments are to compensate for cuts in support prices for milk.

  2.6  One important consequence of the need for certainty is that (as has largely been followed in previous reforms) such matters as the allocation of entitlement are based on extant facts rather than on future facts. Extant facts are very largely unchangeable making it easier for businesses to understand their position and their options and then to decide how to proceed. If allocation of entitlement is made significantly dependent on future facts (such as the area of land held in 2005), then every business and owner is likely to seek to maximise its opportunities. It is unfortunate that the dairy premium is to be allocated in this way—the consequences of this are to be seen in the milk quota markets since late June when sale prices lifted from 10-11p per litre to 17-18 ppl—more recent rises reflect fears of superlevy.

3.  WITHIN THE UK

  3.1  The implementation of the Regulation is likely to differ between each of England, Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland. The allocation and calculation of farmers' entitlement to the new subsidy may vary and may not be transferable between them. Wales could elect for an historic calculation with no national envelope; England for a regional average allocation with a deduction for a national envelope. This could be a complication for the many farm businesses which operate in more than one part of the UK, including those that physically straddle the boundaries. They should not be at a disadvantage because of this.

  3.2  In order to reflect this freedom of implementation by the devolved administrations, this submission is now couched in terms addressing England. The points may be argued equally for the other territories.

  3.3  DEFRA is to be commended for starting consultation on implementation as early as it did. Unfortunately, there has been much slower progress in developing the implementing Commission Regulations—perhaps an inevitable (and, we believe, sad) consequence of the delay in implementation from 2004 to 2005.

4.  ALLOCATION OF ENTITLEMENTS

  4.1  The one remaining fundamental decision is the basis on which the transferable producer-controlled entitlement will be given to farmers. Once this decision is taken, businesses will know where they stand and can begin to plan for the future. The issues remaining, albeit important in themselves and to many farmers, are then about developing that structure.

  4.2  The CAAV believes the allocation should be on an historic basis, in accordance with the main architecture of the Regulation. It is perhaps regrettable that the choice is only between the options made available by the Regulation, as, naturally, none of them are perfect or suit English circumstances. However, using an historic basis will more generally see most businesses receiving a payment reflecting their circumstances than is likely under an area system. Farms will have made investments in equipment, taken on debts and employed staff on the basis of their recent structure. It is wrong to redistribute these payments in ways which do not reflect general business circumstances. A major redistribution of subsidies between businesses offers no obvious policy gain and would be very disruptive when they are adapting to the unsupported market.

  4.3  To offer some measure of the money at stake:

    —  an arable farmer would this year expect to receive some £101 per acre of combinable crops

    —  many cattle farms might receive between £100 and £250/acre

    —  as would dairy farms once the dairy premium and additional payment compensating for cuts in price support are included (otherwise dairy farms naturally have lower rates of historic payment)

    —  at the top end, some cattle businesses (including those in the LFAs) might receive £900/acre

    —  at the other extreme, extensive sheep farms on the high hills might receive £20/acre

    —  nothing is paid directly on land in pigs, roots, vegetables, sugar beet.

To an extent, land and livestock values and rents reflect these existing patterns of payment—and so do the commitments, liabilities, investments and staffing of farms. Hill land generally produces less and attracts less subsidy and is generally of lesser value. The arbitrary classification of eligible arable ground under the MacSharry reforms gave that land a value, most obvious for the poorer land often now worth more than ineligible land. Unsupported crops are generally grown on better (and eligible) land as a deliberate alternative to subsidised arable crops and so do not reflect this pattern.

  4.4  Even an historic allocation of entitlement will see businesses receive the same level of payment as the various deductions imposed by the Regulation (modulation, national reserve, financial discipline, etc) will be applied to it. Nonetheless, it would result in payments reflecting previous levels.

  4.5  In its simplest form, a regional average area-based approach would see a single rate paid on almost every acre of agricultural land in England, irrespective of the type of land, whether heather or fen, arable or daffodil bulbs. It would be irrespective of the type of farm or its circumstances, or even the environmental costs or benefits that might flow from cross compliance. We do not see that such an approach would be just, serve any public policy purpose or be regarded as fair.

  4.6  The estimates of the size of the payment vary according to the assumptions and methods used but they generally appear to be in the range £55-80/acre. Wherever the true figure lies (the CAAV suspects it is at the lower end of the range), it entails a major redistribution of support between farmers, sectors and regions. A similar outcome was found in the change from the headage-based HLCAs to the area-based HFA scheme, when the safety-netting needed to cushion redistribution for LFA livestock businesses required a first year injection of £19 million on top of the £25 cost of the scheme. There is no extra money available to cushion this reform.

  4.7  In practice, the winners from such a major redistribution would be those in intensive unsupported enterprises (a serious root growing business might receive payments increased by some 30% as well as those engaged in the more extensive forms of livestock production. In principle, the very extensive high hills could see payments per acre more than treble, on very large numbers of acres—whose value might rise in response. Growers of combinable crops would probably be general losers while those in more intense cattle and dairy businesses are likely to be significant losers. Businesses currently receiving £900/acre would be £820-840/acre poorer—such a business on 42 acres could be £35,000 worse off.

  4.8  The Regulation allows a division of payments on land use in 2003, basing:

    —  one area payment on whether the land was in one of permanent pasture or grass (which includes temporary grass but may exclude other permanent grazing) The distinction between these two measures of pasture would be important in affecting payment levels.

    —  a second payment on all land not covered by the first payment.

As either approach to assessing grazing land is likely to see a lower area payment for that land, this would produce a more extreme redistribution between livestock farmers around that lower level. The scheme does not allow a payment specifically for ground cropped by traditional arable crops (with or without horticulture)—only one across all land that is not, according to the choice made, permanent pasture or grass.

  4.9  The losses will be felt more sharply by affected businesses as they will be around the lower averages created by deductions for modulation and other matters.

  4.10  There is then a difficulty over the treatment of dairy premium and the payments likely to arise from sugar and hops reform. Are these compensation payments for reduced price support to be lumped in with the area payment, benefiting all farmers pro rata to their area, or added to the affected farmers' area payments?

  4.11  There are administrative difficulties in the approach then applied to determine the ability of fruit, vegetable and potato growers to claim entitlement, turning on individual areas grown in 2003, 2004 and 2005 and the 2000-02 English average.

  4.12  One major problem with regional average systems, whether simple or complicated, is that the allocation of entitlements would turn only on the area of land held in 2005. The payment would simply be a reward for holding as large an area of land as the business or owner can secure for 2005—farmers with large areas in 2005 will be given correspondingly large entitlements.

  4.13  This reliance on "future facts" is likely to lead to significant distortions in the market for land that has usually been let short term and other markets. If a significant payment turns on that area, farmers and owners are likely to retain land that they would have ordinarily let out or that they might otherwise have surrendered or sold in order to maximise their entitlement under the new system. Farms dependent on taking short term land, such as grass keep for dairy and stock farms or land for specialist root cropping, may find such tenancies harder to win in 2005 so that, even if allowed access by licence to the land, they would not be allocated an entitlement that would reflect their true business position.

  4.14  If entitlement is allocated on area declared in 2005, this creates a stimulus to declare land that has not previously been in the system, so diluting payments. That will turn on the level of payments and the cross-compliance commitments but the CAAV suspects there is a significant are of grass that could come forward.

  4.15  The same objections apply to many of the hybrid schemes that have been canvassed. While each proposal needs to be analysed on its own merits, insofar as a significant payment turns on occupying as much land as possible in 2005 it will have damaging and distorting effects. One model under active discussion takes 10% of total English livestock payments (including dairy premium) and allocates it as an area payment of some £8/acre to pasture land (not clearly answering the important point as to whether this is permanent pasture or all grass). This payment would then be topped up with individuals receiving 90% of their historic allocation. That would remove many of the problems that a 2005 basis for allocation poses for the livestock sector—it is unlikely either that many would distort the land market or that previously unclaimed grass would be declared for a right to £8/acre. However, the Commission is understood to have indicated that a basic area payment at 10% is too low and that 25% is preferable—a right to £20/acre does threaten to distort markets in the poorer grazing districts. Arable payments would be simply spread over all non-grass land with the consequent distortions for short term cropping land remaining unaltered.

  4.16  Some support simple area payments as cheaper to administer. This is not a good reason for rewriting the financial position of individual businesses. If a more complex or hybrid system is chosen to temper the redistribution, the system becomes as, or more, complex as an historic allocation.

5.  NATIONAL RESERVE

  5.1  Once it is decided how entitlement is to be allocated, it becomes important to consider the issues of managing the transition. For an historic allocation, these concern handling of claims for entitlement under the hardship or national reserve provisions. There appears to be much greater discretion in establishing the regional frameworks for the National Reserve. It would be helpful if this were set in hand early so that farmers who might rely on it can understand their prospects.

  5.2  As farmers seem expected to claim in May 2005 on the basis of national reserve allocations, it would help if applications were received and processed in late 2004 so that either businesses were approved for an allocation when entitlement is available ready or a partial allocation made to them from the 3% potentially available (which could then be topped up as entitlement is released by non-claimants in 2005). This would help achieve a greater measure of certainty for all involved.

  5.3  In principle, the national reserve should cater for those who have started farming since the last date of which they could have claimed a subsidy in the base period and those who have been expanding. There may also be a case for those who have changed enterprise—as, for example, those who left dairying after foot and mouth. Cases should be provable by contemporaneous evidence with investments committed no later than the date of the Council Regulation last September. The object is to aid those who were caught unwittingly by the reform, not those who have taken business decisions when they should reasonably have known about it. Indeed, there may be justice in focussing help on those who acted before the package was developed and agreed in June when much less was known.

  5.4  In operating the national reserve, it is important that Article 42(9) of the Regulation is not implemented in this country. It appears to be a matter of national discretion whether entitlement can be taken from vendors and lessors where land was sold or leased for more than six years during the reference period or where premium rights (sheep and suckler cow quota) were sold in that period. The provision appears to be about feeding the National Reserve rather than providing any benefit to the purchaser while its operation would introduce a considerable element of instability into the system. The RPA can have no means of telling whether land has been sold or let for more than six years while the disruption caused by chasing sales of premium rights would be considerable. It would be absurd in the cases where the vendors have then bought other farms or premium rights—and more complex still where they have moved into another territory in the UK. In short, operating this sub-article would be to make matters capricious where there is no need.

  5.5  Much less thought has been given to the application of the national reserve to a regional average basis for allocation. The most obviously deserving claimants would be those whose land holdings in 2005 were unrepresentatively smaller than their normal business size because of the distortions inevitably arising in the land market in that year. It is uncertain whether the Regulation allows for this.

6.  CROSS COMPLIANCE AND GOOD AGRICULTURAL AND ENVIRONMENTAL CONDITION

  6.1  While the reform is not expressly a new environmental settlement—thoughts that it might (or ought to) be have confused much of the debate—it does allow part or all of the payment to be taken in penalties where the farmer breaches the cross compliance conditions. The requirement for land to be kept in "Good Agricultural and Environmental Condition" sets the minimum that is required for farmers (as defined) to receive the subsidy without producing.

  6.2  As well as the statutory management requirements (for which this is an extra form of penalty), Annex IV lays out the key requirements for this regime. It requires a minimum level of maintenance and concern about soil erosion, structure and organic content. Implementation of this framework faces several problems. It has to confront the very wide range of farm types, geographies, soil conditions and climates that exist in England and other parts of the UK. While there is considerable guidance available as to good practice, it is not easy to turn practical advice (which can be tempered to individual circumstances) into a legal framework to be used for levying penalties. It is one thing to suggest that maize should not be grown on slopes of more than 11 but another thing to make that a legal requirement with detailed definitions capable of being considered at an appeal. Similarly for potatoes, a concern to increase organic content of soil can run counter to the demands of the market place which prefers the skins grown in soils with less organic content.

  6.3  In framing the cross compliance regime, it seems widely accepted that the drafting of the Regulation only allows for a light touch. Issues arise from interactions with the lower tiers of existing schemes under which farmers may be paid for some of the requirements that may become cross compliance conditions. There is concern that, in the new competitive market place, the cross compliance conditions could be developed so as to handicap English farmers if the result is well out of line with that in other significant member states or, indeed, other parts of the UK. Perhaps farm assurance schemes could offer a partial framework.

  6.4  Assessing compliance will be very much more subjective than has been the case under IACS where the issues are largely ones of numerical accuracy. Monitoring compliance will be much more onerous, and even more so if the requirements are made complex, never minding the resolution of disputes.

7.  NATIONAL ENVELOPE

  7.1  DEFRA has not yet issued its consultation on the possible use of the National Envelope. While DEFRA introduced this into the European negotiations to handle the problems that some foresaw from decoupling, the final result of the negotiations may not offer a useful tool. Not only must it be defined by August 2004, well ahead of knowledge of problems arising from decoupling, but it is specifically targeted on areas of spending which resemble Rural Development Regulation issues:

    —  specific types of farming important for protection or enhancement of the environment, and

    —  quality and marketing of produce.

  7.2  Where money is spent in a particular sector, it can only be money retained for the Envelope from that sector. That is potentially robbing Peter to pay Peter, an exercise in churning with administrative cost attached. The more focused (and potentially useful) the schemes, the greater the administrative cost. More generally, the 10% of the entitlement that could go to the National Envelope would otherwise be income to the farmer unmatched by cost but if offered through agri-environment type schemes it is more often simply intended to match costs, so reducing net income.

  7.3  It is not immediately obvious how far there is a role for the state to decide and then subsidise what is quality produce—that may be something left to the market rather than to encourage unsustainable patterns of production.

8.  ENERGY CROPS

  8.1  While the Regulation offers an energy crops scheme, the low level of payment means that this is not the key issue. It is more important for land in energy crops, whether annual or permanent, to be matchable against entitlement with the much higher levels of payment that would unlock. There appears to be no problem with annual crops and the rules for compliance with set-aside entitlement suggest (by implication) that it can be used against land in permanent energy crops. However, it has not been stated clearly in legislative form that ordinary entitlement can be matched against land in permanent energy crops such as miscanthus. It is very important to that sector that this be allowed.

9.  PERMANENT PASTURE

  9.1  The package imposes restrictions on permanent pasture but the Regulation does not define this. If the IACS type definition of permanent pasture (land in grass over the previous five years) is taken, this will cover much grass that might ordinarily be part of a rotation and which, being managed as temporary grass, may offer little environmental benefit. There are environmental benefits in enlarging the arable area in pasture districts and there seems little merit in trying to protect grass that does not fall within the commonsense definition of permanent pasture. In the newly flexible market place there seems no reason why grass that is unimportant should be protected.

10.  ENVIRONMENTAL ISSUES

  10.1  While some of the debates about environmental policy that attend English discussion of this package may, to an extent, be misdirected in the context of this Regulation, they may be very pertinent to the next round of reform. Few who have spent much time on this issue take the 2012 date seriously. Many anticipate a significant review before then. It might much assist that review if thinking and analysis were more advanced on how levels of payment to farmers might reflect the environmental benefits they can offer. The regional average area payment options in the Regulation are clearly not the vehicle for that, being unable to take any account of such issues. A standard pattern of payments would bear no logical relationship to either the costs of or benefits from delivering an environmental package. An historic basis of allocation (albeit reduced by the Regulation's deductions) would tend to support the current level of compliance; redistribution gives more finance to some to develop their businesses while weakening other businesses' ability to comply. This is a debate for the future for which it would be wise to be better prepared. It may rear its head earlier than expected if payments for agri-environment schemes and management agreements are reduced to reflect decoupling. Significant reductions may affect the voluntary co-operation inherent in these schemes so driving a review.

11.  EFFECTS OF IMPLEMENTATION ELSEWHERE

  11.1  It is too early to comment in depth on implementation of the reform across the EU. Many member states appeared not to recognise the scale of the reform during the negotiations, ultimately leading to the delayed implementation. Only a few states, fortunately including the UK, engaged closely with the detail as it emerged.

  11.2  As a result, DEFRA is probably more advanced than many other Ministries but all are evaluating their options, some faster than others. The allocation of entitlement may affect the financial standing of the more intense cattle and dairy farms. Wales and Scotland both expressed a basic preference for an historic allocation (Wales with an initial preference for no national envelope, preferring to use agri-environmental schemes directly) and Ireland is thought to have found this a very easy choice. Northern Ireland appears to be considering a more complex answer following concerns about its beef sector.

  11.3  Germany and Denmark are expected to run an area system, Finland is considering it, and this is the approach for the accession states. There are competition issues here, especially for unsupported crops. Holland is thought to be taking an historic approach, despite its large unsupported production sector, as are most states.

  11.4  Ireland has now swung to support full decoupling in 2005 so UK farmers will compete with Irish beef and dairy sectors on the same basis. There seems little discussion of any use of the arable partial coupling option, offering only a quarter of the payment but operation of the full scheme. There is more discussion of the livestock options but it is too early to know how many states will take up the various options available, all of which would require compliance with retention periods and other burdens of those schemes. Use of a major beef scheme by a significant country could have competition effects.

  11.5  It is too early to assess other states' approaches to more detailed matters such as national envelopes, especially as the Commission regulations are awaited.

Central Association of Agricultural Valuers

December 2003





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 6 May 2004