Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the National Farmers' Union

IMPLEMENTATION OF CAP REFORM IN THE UK

  1.  The CAP Reform agreed by the Council of Ministers in Luxembourg in June 2003 was by far the most radical change in the history of the policy. The NFU had for long advocated the principle of decoupling support from production, and fully supported the main lines of the Commission's proposal of January 2003.

  2.  It was unfortunate that, in order to get the necessary majority for an agreement in June, it was necessary to introduce a number of compromises which allowed Member States to only partially implement the principle of decoupling, and gave a wide range of national options in implementing the changes. Furthermore, the introduction of the Reform was postponed from 2004 until 2005, with an option for countries to delay until 2006 or 2007. The NFU regretted this outcome at the time and expressed concern at the potential for distortion that would arise from running a series of different policies within a single market. In the event, the farming community itself in most countries now seems to be pushing for early and complete implementation of the reform, so the worst of these dangers may be avoided. Nonetheless, the possibility that different options will result in very different impacts on individual farmers and markets remains, even between the four nations within the UK.

  3.  At the time of writing, Defra has completed its consultation process on the two most important decisions that have to be taken in England, namely whether to introduce the single farm payment on the basis of individual historic payments (IHP) or regional average payments (RAP) and whether to make use of the facility to introduce a so-called "national envelope". A decision on these items is imminent. But as these fundamental choices will then open a number of further implementation issues; it is almost impossible to comment in any detail on these secondary matters in this submission. We would be happy to provide further views at a later stage, if requested.

PRINCIPLES AND METHOD OF IMPLEMENTATION IN THE UK

Individual Historic or Regional Average Payments?

  4.  The question whether the allocation of the single farm payment should be according to the "individual historic" or "regional average" method is the most difficult the NFU has had to face, because both choices have associated problems.

  5.  The NFU has carefully weighed up the two main allocation methods, and various "hybrid" systems, against four criteria that were unanimously agreed by the Council of the NFU. These are:

    —  Simplicity

    —  Minimising redistribution of existing support

    —  Ensuring that the payment goes to the working farmer

    —  Market focus.

  6.  In the light of these criteria, the NFU has come down firmly in favour of the individual historic approach. [1]

  7.  We accept that there is a tension between these criteria. That is why our decision has been a balanced one, and why it is impossible to find a perfect solution.

Simplicity

  8.  The NFU agrees that this is an important issue. More complex systems will almost certainly be more expensive to administer and money spent on this will be money that is not available for other purposes. For farmers, a more complicated system is likely to lead to appeals, expense and delay.

  9.  We also agree that the simplest form of regional average payment (where the total amount of payments in England is divided equally over the total English area) would be the easiest and least costly to administer. But this is precisely the form of regional averaging that would have the most drastic redistributional effects, and would, on these grounds, be totally unacceptable to the NFU.

  10.  We readily accept that the individual historic method is complicated as far as the initial allocation is concerned. The biggest problem is likely to be the transitional issue of those who have entered the industry or expanded since the end of the reference period. The NFU made a joint industry approach to the Commission with a proposal that would have greatly reduced this problem; regrettably it was not adopted. We will therefore be looking for any means possible in the implementing regulations to reduce the burden of this problem.

Redistribution

  11.  The issue of the redistribution of support is very important to the NFU, both in terms of the perception and acceptability of the reform and the business impact on the losers.

  12.  Defra's own figures indicate that the number of winners and losers would be broadly equal. In reality, the number who perceive themselves to be losers under a regional average system will be significantly higher, because the move to the single payment will take place at the same time as new deductions (higher modulation, national reserve, possibly national envelope) are made from the payments. This is likely to erode support for the reform at a critical time.

  13.  While Defra's figures also show a relatively modest redistribution between sectors; these are average figures and mask very large absolute changes between individuals, particularly in the livestock sector. [2]

  14.  The livestock businesses that would be threatened by a regional averaging system would be those who were the more productive and enterprising, often with higher investment costs. They are also the most likely ones to be able to survive in a post-Doha round environment with lower levels of trade protection.

Ensuring Payments go to Farmers

  15.  The European Commission's intention was that the single farm payment was a decoupled payment to farmers as managers of agricultural holdings, rather than to owners of land. This was the explicit rationale for making the payments a negotiable asset.

  16.  This is a particularly important issue in the livestock sector, because many tenants have themselves purchased the quotas that give rise to the entitlement to the single farm payment. If entitlements are not transferable, the capital value will unreasonably be transferred from tenant to landlord. Although trade in entitlements would be possible under a simple regional average system, the market would not be liquid because almost all land would have a payment and all payments would be the same value. This is, therefore, a further major reason why the simple regional average system is unacceptable.

  17.  In systems where there is less scope for trade in entitlements, the single farm payment will be more likely to be capitalised in land prices and rents. The single farm payment is then likely to set a floor in rents. This in turn will blunt the commercial and competitive focus of English agriculture.

  18.  Another difficulty with regional averaging is that the payments in the unsupported crop sector may be less likely to rest with the farmer. In the cereals and oilseeds sectors the price is principally determined by the world market (and in cereals by intervention and export licences); local supply and demand factors play relatively little part. In field vegetables and potatoes the reverse is the case. There is a significant risk that if growers of these crops receive a payment, part at least of this will be captured by the processor or retailer.

Market focus

  19.  The underlying rationale of decoupling is that farmers' business decisions will be driven by the market and not by the requirements of the subsidy system.

  20.  In our view, the individual method of allocation largely achieves that purpose.

  21.  There is, however, one major problem that will be created for some growers. This arises because those growing unsupported crops who, for commercial reasons, would like to switch to cereals will be forced to compete with existing cereal producers who will be receiving a substantially higher single payment. This in itself could unfairly tip the balance of commercial power between the grower and the processor. The NFU urges a serious investigation into this issue and would like to discuss possible remedies urgently with Defra.

Environmental concerns

  22.  The NFU is unpersuaded by arguments that one or the other models is more environmentally beneficial. In our view, there is no convincing case to be made either way.

  23.  Some environmental groups believe that the regional average method will extend cross-compliance over a wider area. This is, in our view, a misapprehension. Almost all grassland and all arable land that is in a rotation that includes supported crops will be subject to cross compliance under either system. Land that is exclusively growing unsupported crops would become subject to cross-compliance under a regional average system, but it is likely that many of these growers would not wish to claim a single farm payment as this would make them liable to set aside very valuable land.

Summary

  24.  The NFU has carefully weighed up the pros and cons of the individual historic and regional average method. The merit of the average approach is that it is simpler, but this only applies to the simplest regional method, which creates unacceptable redistribution. The individual method also, on balance, comes closer to meeting the NFU's concerns on ensuring the payments go to the farmer and avoiding distortions. There is no significant environmental difference between the two options.

  25.  We recognise that the individual method of allocation will create significant problems for some farmers and growers, and we urge that these issues should be seriously addressed and solutions found wherever that is possible.

POSSIBLE IMPACTS OF IMPLEMENTATION

The "National Envelope"

  26.  Defra is currently consulting on whether or not to use the "national envelope"—the facility to reduce the single farm payment by up to 10%, and to use the funds for the (closely defined) purposes allowed in the Regulation. The NFU is strongly opposed, for the following reasons.

  27.  The Article allowing the withholding of amounts to make up national envelopes is found within the section of the Council regulation that is entitled Partial Implementation. The NFU has consistently championed full decoupling as a matter of strong principle; at times almost standing alone in this position. The Secretary of State has consistently argued that the UK should fully decouple and the NFU has given its full backing to this aim. The national envelope is, in effect, partial decoupling of aid with remaining amounts being returned to producers on what will, in effect, be a coupled basis. It is clearly envisaged by the article that producers will have to be farming or producing (paragraph 3 of Article 69).  

  28.  We have no clear idea of the purpose for which the national envelope could be put. We understand that the Scottish Executive is minded to use the envelope to encourage suckler cow production in some areas of Scotland, supposedly for environmental reasons. If so, this will perpetuate all the negative consequences of coupled payments: those farmers directly concerned will be encouraged to continue uneconomic production in order to claim a subsidy, while all other beef farmers will suffer the consequences. Farmers in England will suffer from this just as much as those in Scotland. Defra may not be able to do anything about this, but they can avoid making the same mistake as Scotland.

  29.  The administration of the national envelope appears horrendously complicated. The Regulation states that the deduction must be made from the components of the single payment (ie beef, sheep, arable, dairy, seeds etc), not the total single payment. Once a deduction had been made from one sector, it would then be necessary to ensure that precisely that sum was spent in the "sector concerned by the retention". This seems to require a very sophisticated accountancy and audit procedure.

  30.  The deduction appears, under the regulation, to be a once and for all cut of up to 10% of the national ceiling. The actual proportion in terms of the payments themselves would be higher, after potential scale backs of reference amounts (Article 41.2) and deductions for the national reserve (Art 41.3). With national envelope amounts being deducted from the start in this way, there appears to be no mechanism for returning any undistributed sums to the industry. The use of the sheep national envelope in England has created a particularly baleful precedent here, where the decision to make the deduction has clearly taken precedence over any consideration of the use to which the money might be put.

  31.  Farmers are already going to suffer significant cutbacks to their payments, whether through national reserve contributions (up to 3%), modulation, both national[3] (possibly 7% or more in England) and European (up to 5%) and financial discipline (unknown). We calculate that these deductions, plus the national envelope, could easily amount to 23% in England in 2005; a significant cut in support from current levels. What is worse, most other European farmers would face a maximum cut of 6%.

  32.  The NFU believes that these are compelling arguments against the use of the national envelope. If DEFRA is still minded to follow this course, we would strongly urge the following approach:

  33.  DEFRA should come up with concrete proposals for schemes through which such funds should be made available, together with estimates of how much these will cost. There should then be a further round of consultation with stakeholders.

  34.  We cannot understate the importance of ensuring that all such funds are taken up. This means that schemes must have demonstrable benefits, be accessible and involve minimum bureaucracy. The cost of the administration is a charge to Defra, not to the national envelope, but Defra must ensure that the benefit of the measure outweighs the administrative cost.

  35.  Funds must be channelled to farmers. The Regulation is explicit in this regard: "In this case . . . the Member State concerned shall make, on a yearly basis, an additional payment to farmers in the sector or sectors concerned by the retention." The NFU would insist on this provision and would demand an annual audit to show that this had been the case.

Potential for Distortion in the Single Market

  36.  Both those who advocate the individual and the regional average approaches have concern at the potential for distortion of competition within the European single market. Most countries have not yet declared their positions, but our current knowledge is that:

    —  Ireland has announced full decoupling in 2005, on the historic model;

    —  Germany will operate on a Länder basis, with an average payment on arable crops and an historic on livestock, with a transition (as yet undecided) to a full regional average basis.

    —  Denmark will adopt a hybrid regional average system.

    —  Other EU15 countries are understood to be leaning strongly to an historic basis.

    —  Within the UK: England is undecided, devolved Ministers in Scotland and Wales have indicated they favour the historic approach, and Ulster is examining a hybrid averaging system.

    —  Eight of the 10 applicant countries (the exceptions are Slovenia and Malta) will adopt a simple average. [4]

  37.  Unsupported crop growers in England have been, understandably, concerned that if other countries adopt a regional average payment there could be a distortion in that competitors would be receiving single farm payments. If the list of likely options given in paragraph 36 is accurate, this concern seems to be exaggerated. Germany and Denmark are not major rivals. Poland is potentially more of a problem, particularly for potato growers, but these payments are being phased in over a long period. (There is also a device to ensure that the area of fruit and vegetables receiving the single payment cannot expand). The NFU has never envisaged this reform as the last word. There seems every chance that there will be a move to more uniform levels of payment throughout the EU at some point in the future and probably before the end of the transition period with the new Member States.

  38.  If there is a concern at the consequences of an IHP system for unsupported crop growers, there is an equivalent concern about an RAP system from both supported arable and livestock sectors. This concern is, arguably, greater because more of our direct competitors will be adopting an IHP basis. Thus if England has a regional payment, cereal growers will have a significantly lower single farm payment than their French counterparts (in addition to much higher levels of modulation, and, possibly a further deduction for the National Envelope, where the French farmer will have none.) On top of that, there is a distinct possibility that France will opt for partial decoupling, obliging the farmer to continue in cereal production if he wishes to obtain the full single farm payment. The consequence of all this is that production levels would be likely to fall in England, but not in France, even though this is not the result that the free market would have achieved. Naturally this will have an impact on the whole of the production chain in England.

  39.  Similar results might occur within the UK. If Wales and Scotland adopt an IHP while England opts for a RAP, the NFU predicts the following consequences:

    —  Beef production would be favoured in Scotland at the expense of England;

    —  Sheep production would be favoured in England at the expense of Wales and Scotland

    —  Dairy production would be drawn to Wales and Scotland

    —  Fruit and vegetables would be drawn to England

    —  Cereals production would be favoured in Scotland.

All of these would be very divisive and have serious social and regional implications.

CAP REFORM AND THE SUSTAINABLE FOOD AND FARMING STRATEGY

  The NFU supports the Strategy and many of its individual components. We think the CAP Reform and the SFFS should in many respects be mutually reinforcing. In particular we would like to draw attention to the following synergies:

    —  Food Chain. The Curry Report made a major feature of the need to reconnect farmers with their markets and to improve the functioning and efficiency of the food chain. Decoupling should greatly assist in these two objectives. It will mean that farmers should focus on the market rather than producing to obtain a subsidy. Removing production-linked subsidy will also make the food chain more transparent and require those who purchase from farmers to ensure their supply by offering remunerative prices.

    —  Consumer health needs. Again, decoupling will allow producers to focus on real market needs; if health is a consumer issue, farmers will respond. Decoupling will also remove the perception that support policies have encouraged unhealthy types of production.

    —  Better Regulation & Whole Farm Approach. The NFU sets considerable store by the "Whole Farm Approach" to the implementation of regulations at the farm business level. CAP Reform offers a great opening to take this approach further, provided the opportunity is grasped. We would like to see the annual application for the single farm payment, cross-compliance, agri-environmental schemes and, in future, the Farm Advisory System consolidated into the Whole Farm Approach.

    —  The Entry Level Scheme. Although not strictly part of the CAP Reform, the NFU sees the new Entry Level Scheme as an important complement to the Single Farm Payment. We have long campaigned for an agri-environment scheme available to all farmers, which rewards them for responsible stewardship, and we would like ambitious targets for take-up so that the majority of farmland enters into the scheme. In our view the Entry Level Scheme fits more coherently with the Individual Historic method of single farm payment allocations.

    —  Environmental Protection. Cross-compliance offers the opportunity to ensure that those in receipt of single farm payments respect minimum and consistent standards across the EU. It also offers the opportunity to reinforce the concept of good agricultural and environmental condition, which should complement EU legislative goals (eg Water Framework Directive). Defra, and other UK administrations, should take care in developing conditions to ensure that they do not disproportionately bear on UK producers; that conditions are practical at a farm scale and that they do not duplicate functions actions more appropriately funded through agri-environment schemes.

National Farmers' Union

December 2003

330,000 and the greatest loss

50,000. Sudden reductions on this scale are bound to be business threatening. Moreover, many of the enterprises facing extreme changes will be the same as those that encountered similar movements with the change from headage to area based payments in the LFA following the last CAP Reform. There would undoubtedly be enormous pressure for some form of safety net mechanism, or phasing in of the changes, which in turn would negate the benefit of simplicity that the regional average offers.




1   This view is not shared by the NFU Horticulture Board, whose remit includes potatoes. They prefer the regional average approach. Back

2   The NFU has examined figures from a number of real livestock farms from a small random survey. Within this small sample the range was extreme, with the greatest gain by a farm around Back

3   The UK will be the only country in Europe with any national modulation. Back

4   This is not surprising since they have no history of direct payments. Note also that these payments will start at 35% of the level in the EU, rising to 100% by 2011.


 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 6 May 2004