Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Barclays Plc

IMPLEMENTATION OF CAP REFORM IN THE UK

INTRODUCTION

  Barclays Agricultural Banking is the largest single lending brand in UK agriculture, with lending exposure of over £2 billion and a team of over 100 specialist managers dedicated to the farming industry. Barclays have organised a series of confidential workshops with key stakeholders within the associated industries in order to explore and identify key implications. The learning points from these workshops, as well as over 20 years experience in the agricultural sector and agricultural banking, have been drawn on in this paper.

  This submission is prepared in response to a series of seven questions supplied by the committee, regarding aspects of the implementation of the CAP reform in the UK pertinent to the capital and financial markets. Some of these questions are based on assumptions regarding the impact of implementation, which are addressed in answer 8.2.

1.  IMPACT ON ASSET VALUES AND SECURITY FOR BORROWINGS

  From a security perspective the relevant assets are land/property, off farm investments, quota and trading stock, with land representing by far the majority of security. However the importance of trading stock and quota values is considerably higher for the tenanted sector, where land is not typically available for security purposes.

  It is also important to acknowledge that lending decisions are made on the basis of profit generation and ability to repay debt, and then subsequently under written by security. Therefore where cash generation is not reduced, a fall in security value will not of itself normally bring a loan into default. So it is the impact on cash generation which would be of primary concern.

1.1  LAND VALUES

  For the last 30 years, there has been little discernible link between land values and agricultural income for the UK as a whole. Values are significantly influenced by many factors such as development potential, fiscal policy, proximity to conurbations, amenity attraction and agricultural productivity. However, in some more remote areas, or those with low amenity and no developmental potential, then agricultural productivity and appeal are the main determinants of land value. Therefore in these areas, values would be expected to reflect reductions in farm income. There could then be a gradient in scale of value reduction proportionate to distance from the urban areas, reducing the influence on land value of non-agricultural aspects. However local conditions will always dominate.

  The current period of uncertainty has seen a significant reduction in both land area being offered on the market and on the number of agricultural buyers. Where agricultural transactions have been undertaken, this has often been accompanied by attempts to include the future entitlements through side letters and contracts. However the volume of farms sold to non-farming purchasers has remained level, where it is believed that amenity factors such as location and residence quality are more important. This situation is expected to be transitional, with trading returning to more normal levels once the uncertainty around the implementation of the MTR proposals is removed.

  Since the MacSharry reforms, the arable sector has seen some evidence of capitalisation of existing IACS payments eligibility into land values, with higher values being seen for eligible land compared to similar quality land without eligibility. In the future, this value could vary according to the likelihood of the Single Farm Payment (SFP) entitlements being separated from land or retained in association via Regional Average Payments or an equivalent hybrid (see answer 5 below).

  The livestock sector has not seen such capitalisation into land, possibly due to the requirement for quotas and the value of subsidy receipts being directly linked to individual farming systems. Some capitalisation would be a logical consequence if the entitlement becomes directly associated with land, potentially increasing values by around £2-300/acre (see answer 7.2).

  Overall, the banking perspective, having allowed a prudent discount in valuations assumed, and considering security at a portfolio level (rather than specific farm level), suggests land value changes are unlikely to cause significant security issues. However, significant specific issues may emerge in cases where land values have been significantly reduced. The impact would cause re-adjustment, after which the use of land as security is unlikely to be tarnished.

1.2  OFF FARM INVESTMENTS

  Clearly these are unlikely to be affected by any agricultural trends.

1.3  QUOTA

  The value of both livestock and especially milk quotas tends to be highly volatile, relating to agricultural profitability and supply and demand. From both perspectives the value of milk quota would be highly vulnerable and we would expect it to reduce in value after the de-coupling of the dairy sector. However the value of livestock quotas would be negated immediately post de-coupling.

  Due to the relative ease with which quotas can be traded they have rarely been considered a major item of security, though charges would often be taken when borrowed funds were used for their purchase. The value of livestock and milk quotas are more relevant in the tenanted sector, where they often represent a significant proportion of the balance sheet value.

  Of greater concern would be the residual debt used to purchase such assets which have lost their relevance and productive value (see also question 2).

1.4  TRADING STOCK

  These values will fluctuate directly in proportion to their associated profit potential. Therefore where they are covered as security under an Agricultural Charge, and they represent a major proportion of the overall security value, the security position will be weakened assuming the expectation of profit per item is reduced. This is most relevant in the tenanted sector where the balance sheet will not be insulated by the relative stability of land values and often little other security will be available.

1.5 OVERALL COMMENT

  The impact on security values will be most significant for the tenanted sector, where they could be reduced very substantially or even completely in the case of livestock quotas. Conversely owner-occupiers are likely to see less significant reductions due to lower proportionate impact on land value, combined with the lower gearing associated with land ownership, which is a reflection of the lower return on capital in land.

2.  THE IMPACT OF REGIONAL AVERAGING ON TENANT BORROWINGS INCURRED FOR LIVESTOCK QUOTA PURCHASE

  It is widely assumed that the use of Regional averaging would restrict the occupier's ability to trade SFP, to selling it to the subsequent occupier at the point of transfer in land occupation, with no other potential purchasers (see question 5 below). Negotiating from such a position of weakness suggests there would be little value attached to entitlements in this situation. Therefore tenants who purchased livestock quotas in the past, would see their value lost, rather than transferred into the new entitlements. They would of course retain any debt outstanding from original quota purchase and subject to the comments in 1.1 above, this would increase the financial pressure they might face.

  Combined with a reduction in trading stock values post MTR (see 1.4), it is possible that some tenants will face negative equity positions, reducing their ability to exit if faced with a non-viable business after the impact of the MTR.

3.  THE RISK OF LARGE SCALE BANKRUPTCY UNDER THE REFORMED CAP

  There is no expectation of large-scale bankruptcy as a result of UK implementation of the CAP reform measures.

  It is not possible to quantify whether any bankruptcies will result due to the ongoing uncertainty around various aspects of implementation. However it is not expected to be high, though some sectors and business types may be more vulnerable than others. Higher risk sectors will be those where income is reduced, as well as asset values, since the latter will reduce their options in subsequent restructuring, whilst it is the reduced income which drives the need to restructure.

  Initially there will be little income reduction, more a change in the way the subsidy income is achieved, though over time the SFP is widely expected to reduce, due to National Envelope, modulation, financial discipline and mounting financial pressure associated with EU enlargement. It is widely hoped that such reductions would be accompanied by increasing business efficiency and ability to source other income streams, to the extent that this reduces or even prevents a net impact on business profitability and this balance is critical to all assumptions around future asset values. However, in the Dairy sector, the proposals also include a significant reduction in the intervention support of prices, potentially reducing incomes significantly. When combined with reduced milk quota values (see 1.3) and dependant on the value attached to the entitlement (see 5), this will represent a significant increase in financial stress, to the point where some business failures are likely. This is especially true in the tenanted sector where balance sheet reserves are typically lower than that of owner-occupiers and may also be reduced by a greater proportion. It is important to remember that for the Dairy sector, these payments are meant to provide partial compensation for these expected price reductions and in this aspect the sector is different to others.

  The land owning sector may face similar income issues, but are more likely to be able to restructure through sale of lower productivity assets, to reduce debt or invest in higher return assets.

4.  CASHFLOW ISSUES ASSOCIATED WITH LATER PAYMENT OF THE SINGLE FARM PAYMENT

  Where individual businesses appreciate and plan for the delay in payment, it is unlikely that a timely request for increased overdraft facilities pending subsequent receipt, would cause any problems from a bank's perspective. However any extra borrowing would incur finance charges and so represent an extra cost for the farmer.

  Problems may occur from the bank's perspective where there is uncertainty regarding the customer's eligibility for the payment, as the bank is unlikely to be able to assess whether all conditions of payment, e.g. cross compliance, have been met. This could become a problem in marginal cases, if business viability would be significantly compromised in the event of non-receipt.

5.  OPPORTUNITY TO TRADE ENTITLEMENTS UNDER DIFFERENT SINGLE FARM PAYMENT OPTIONS

  To allow trade, the market requires a willing vendor, a willing purchaser and a mechanism to achieve the trade. To establish a market value, there would ideally be more than one potential purchaser.

  The different SFP options will impact on the number of potential purchasers, since to purchase entitlement for subsequent claim, a purchaser would need land in their control that is currently without entitlements. Conceptually they might have entitlements of a lower value such that they would be willing to discard the lower value in order to purchase and claim the higher value payments.

  The Individual Historic Entitlements (IHE) option would result in a small but significant area of UK farmland not having entitlements associated with it (the "naked acres"). The result is a greater supply of land than entitlements, which would allow a market to develop due to the increase in potential purchasers.

  The Regional Average Payment (RAP) option would allocate entitlement to all farm land, so that future trade would be almost entirely restricted to transfer between an outgoing and incoming occupier of the same land or other land under simultaneous transfer. It is conceivable in this situation that the market would acknowledge that the land occupancy is the dominant factor, so the value associated with the entitlement itself could be incorporated into the cost to access land, either rental or purchase values, with the Entitlement becoming effectively worthless.

  Hybrid models are more difficult to comment on due to the infinite number of such models. Fundamentally they will provide the same scenario as one or other of the two options above, depending on whether they involve entitlements being applied to all land (as per RAP), or just that which was historically subject to payments (as per IHE).

6.  QUANTIFYING THE AMOUNT OF "NAKED ACRES" THAT WOULD FACILITATE THE TRADE IN ENTITLEMENT

  This is not easy, due to uncertainty around how many forage acres are not currently associated with existing IACS declarations and so how such land might be registered in the future (examples would be land used for dairy and lowland sheep production). This data may be partially available to DEFRA via annual census returns and IACS database, but we do not believe it is in the public arena.

  Land utilised for non supported cropping during the reference period is all potential "naked acres", subject to current cropping usage, and for example, it is known that there has been a reduction in the area of land used for potato production since the reference period of 2000-02.

  Crude estimates might suggest as much as 1-2% of UK land might be "naked", assuming no further shift in cropping areas away from un-subsidised crops. Therefore it seems likely that there is sufficient over supply of land relative to entitlements to allow a market to be established under an IHE type regime.

7.  THE MECHANICS OF THE MARKET IN ENTITLEMENTS AND HOW PRICE WOULD BE SET

7.1  THE MECHANICS OF A MARKET

  The UK is well supplied with independent brokers who currently trade in both milk and livestock subsidy quotas, so would be well placed to make a market in entitlements.

  There will need to be a central administration process, possibly undertaken by the Rural Payments Agency.

  An important function of this body should be to register third party interest in these entitlements, to ensure transfers are made with the agreement of all such parties. Third parties might include lending institutions who have financed the purchase of the entitlements could also be interested parties. Such a process would give lenders comfort to provide further support to the ongoing restructuring of the sector through lending to individuals who are expanding, to purchase extra entitlements. This might be an important criteria for lenders in marginal cases, especially those with a weak balance sheet where a registered charge on the purchased entitlement may be the only available security. Further examples of third parties would be other partners in a business and in the future, newly established landlords who have provided entitlements to new tenants.

7.2  HOW MARKET PRICE WOULD BE SET

  Quota trading market precedents suggest that supply and demand, purchaser confidence, plus expectation of associated income will be the largest determinants in future entitlement values for trading.

  However, in trying to establish a logical value, a Discounted cashflow technique would suggest the entire income stream might represent a Net Present Value of around £450/acre for the cereals sector and a dairy sector payment value of around 9p/litre. This includes the entire value of national envelope funds, assumes a medium but increasing level of modulation and 10% discount rate. Depending on confidence regarding the longevity and the likelihood reduction of the payments, this might give a market value of around half of those total values, so £225/acre and 4.5p/litre. This assumes a willing purchaser would only pay a price that allowed them to achieve significant return on his investment over and above the purchase price.

  But it is worth noting that the market sophistication is not such that a discounted cashflow technique is likely to always be adopted and values significantly higher than this are being speculatively discussed by brokers.

8.  OTHER AREAS OF COMMENT

8.1  SPEED OF DECISION

  Whilst the implications of the payment regime chosen are very significant for certain sectors, this has to be balanced against cost of the current hiatus in business planning and evolution in all sectors, meaning there is an imperative need for a imminent decision. Once announced, the focus of the farm businessperson should return to evolving their business to maximise returns for the future either in or out of farming.

8.2  INCOME IMPACT OF MTR

  The questions submitted by the committee tend to assume a level of reduction in income and hence asset values for the agricultural sector. Whilst this is logical, it is important to remember that off farm incomes have increased dramatically over the last few years, making an important contribution to the cash surpluses of such farms. This trend is likely to continue.

  Another important factor is the increasing productivity, cost control and cash focus of the sector which are all likely to help mitigate the scale of impact which a simple projection might indicate.

  Therefore for most sectors, the balance between loss of income due to reduced subsidy and improved income from other sources is not easy to predict. This is more straightforward in the dairy sector where the price reduction is likely to be more distinct.

8.3  EXCHANGE RATE

  The impact of a further weakening of the pound to euro exchange rate has the ability to increase the pound value of the overall subsidy income to UK farmers, which would also be accompanied by an improvement in the competitiveness of UK products compared to the EU.

Barclays Plc

February 2004





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 6 May 2004