Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 183-199)

DR JAMES JONES, MR RICHARD LOLE AND MR STEVE ELLWOOD

11 FEBRUARY 2004

  Chairman: Can I welcome our witnesses this afternoon and thank them in advance for their written submissions to the Committee, they were much appreciated. For the record we have Dr James Jones, Head of Farm Management at the Royal Agricultural College, Cirencester and a Member of the Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors' Countryside Policy Panel; from Barclays Bank, Mr Richard Lole, who is their National Agricultural Policy Manager; and from HSCB, Head of Agriculture, Steve Ellwood. Gentlemen, you are very welcome. Apologies that the usual problems with the House of Commons voting delayed us starting and we will not delay any more. I would like Bill Wiggin to start the questioning.

  Q183 Mr Wiggin: A nice easy one to kick off with. What effect do you think the Single Farm Payment will have on land values?

  Dr Jones: This has been set out in a paper recently by Professor Alan Buckwell from the CLA. He set it out in some detail and I think you have had a copy of that paper[1]. I would broadly support all his conclusions. I think the difficulty is it depends whether the Single Farm Payment will be a separate tradable entity, not just legally, because we know that that is going to be the case regardless of the system, but actually in practice, and it will be most effective as a tradable entity under the historic system. If we move to a regional average payment system then effectively it will not be tradable. If it is not tradable then obviously the value attached to the subsidy can only attach to the land because it is referenced against it. Under the historic system the Single Farm Payment itself can be detached from the land and has an independent value, so I think it rather depends on the system.

  Q184 Mr Wiggin: Of course.

  Dr Jones: I think I would broadly agree with Professor Buckwell in that there are some pluses and minuses. Effectively, the subsidy becomes worth more because it is not attached to the same sort of farming obligations as it has been in the past; it is attached to some cross-compliance obligations but arguably that is a smaller requirement than having to keep suckler cows or keep sheep or whatever in terms of the costs. As a result of that it might be worth more but in turn the income stream from it will be reduced in time, so the two effects will counteract each other and I think the effect on land values broadly will be neutral.

  Q185 Mr Wiggin: You do not think that the type of model used will have an effect on the land value and rental value as well?

  Dr Jones: I think the type of model really affects individual cases because if we move, say, to an historic system then it is not only more tradable and therefore it is a separate entity that can be detached from the land so you would have to make your valuations separately, but it is also going to be more variable from one farm to another. If the payments are averaged and there is just a flat rate entitlement it then simply has to attach to land at a flat rate.

  Q186 Chairman: What do the bankers think? Which one do you want?

  Mr Lole: Just expanding on that, although I agree with the majority of what has been said, with a couple of other thoughts. One is that the existing arable land value usually has some value associated with that payment capitalised within it and that is not the case in the livestock sector, so the impact on land values could be different according to different sectors. The other point is obviously a caution that land value is not directly related to productivity but there are amenity values potentially which will insulate land value from the straightforward productivity of the land.

  Q187 Chairman: What does Mr Ellwood have to say on behalf of his bank?

  Mr Ellwood: The only other comment I would make that adds to that is that it would be fair and accurate to say that it is not just in farm incomes or even a part of farm incomes that Single Farm Payments affect land value. There is plenty of evidence over the last decade or two that land values are affected by the value of rural property by non-farm buyers as well as by agricultural issues. That is the only other bit that I would add to that equation. One further point if I may, clearly, the different sectors can be affected in different ways if we go for either an historic or regional payment basis. I would have expected to see more discrepancy or distortion in the livestock sector than the arable sector. I would not make a prediction as to what the percentage is but within that percentage there is more distortion within the livestock sector than the arable sector.

  Q188 Alan Simpson: Are we not being conned by all this into deciding which group of extremely rich people we subsidise? It seems to me that you have taken us into this trap that says, "Where is our angst, and should we stick with a model that funds historic payments to those large farm owners who produce arable crops or should we switch to a system based on acreage so we reward the largest landowners?" Surely this is just a scam to ensure that one way or another we continue to provide subsidies to the extremely rich?

  Dr Jones: It has another name, which is the Common Agricultural Policy! We are members of the European Union, we are members of the Common Agricultural Policy, and therefore this amount of money has to be made available to our farmers, and we are simply trying to decide which is the most effective, fairest and most desirable means of delivering it.

  Q189 Alan Simpson: Would we have been better off going for the proposals that came up at the Commission last year that suggested a cap on the payments to the largest farmers or landholders, the £187,000 ceiling on payments? That would still be redistributing the money but in terms of the objective of transfers towards sustainable farming and towards land management, would it not have been better to say that infrastructure payments will go to farming on a sustainable scale would and would have been a better system than one that locked us into this debate as to which group of rich landowners we want to shovel lots of cash to?

  Dr Jones: That has happened before. We have had those sorts of proposals coming up from time to time since the early 1990s. One of the reasons why it has never been adopted is partly because we have larger farms in the UK, for example, than is common elsewhere in Europe, so if you applied a larger farm cut-off in payments you would be cutting payments to the UK whereas you would not then be cutting payments to Portugal, say, where the farm size is very, very much smaller. That is one of the reasons why it has not been adopted. The other one is that you end up spending a lot of money chasing around after people who have taken professional advice to divide up their businesses so that they no longer appear to be large farms—and you are familiar with it in other contexts—and I think it is generally believed that it is simply not worthwhile. There is another Member State angle on this which is that there are some very large farms in Eastern Germany and of course there are some very large farms in the accession states. It is this business about the skewed farm structure that would cause a problem with capping.

  Q190 Alan Simpson: In terms of the land value aspect of this, if we take the current situation, as I understand it, if you take someone who is a definite beneficiary like Sir Gerald Cavendish Grosvenor, the Duke of Westminster, his farm, Grosvenor Farm in Chester, is eligible for subsidy payments which currently work out at about the rate of £1,000 a day. That is based on the historic payments model. If we shifted to another subsidy system would he end up having to struggle to work out who he would have to pay to get out of bed to pick up the subsidy for him on a larger scale or on a smaller scale if we changed the model?

  Dr Jones: If you average payments on an area basis, then obviously the larger the area you farm the more payments you get, so it does not necessarily mean that by spreading the farm payments out that larger farmers will be worse off. It has different sorts of redistribution effects and sometimes smaller farmers tend to be more intensive so that their subsidy per hectare might be higher even if they are farming less hectares. I am not sure that this idea that one system or another will redistribute wealth is quite the case.

  Q191 David Taylor: Can we move from Alan's subsidy payment that dare not speak its name to the area of taxation. You have said that you believe broadly that there will be little impact on land values if we went down the Single Farm Payment route. Can we infer from that also that there would be relatively little effect on capital tax payments due?

  Dr Jones: There are some specific capital tax issues tied up with any type of quota or any type of entitlement. We have already got that with the milk quota, beef quota, sheep quota, and so on. The system which attracts the highest entitlement value, if you like, because it is the most tradable, is the historic entitlement basis, so there are some specific capital issues tied up in that. There is only a finite amount of value in subsidy converted into a capital sum. Quite rightly, as Alan Buckwell points out in his paper, if you have a system where it is focused on a moveable element of subsidy then there has got to be rather less value in the land. In terms of the proportion it is still pretty small because the underlying value of the land is its amenity and its long-term value and the fact that, as Mark Twain pointed out, they do not make it any more. Obviously I would support what my colleagues here have said about the fact that we are not talking about a vast difference in land values based on the subsidy movement.

  Q192 David Taylor: So moving from capital tax to revenue tax, on the precedent of how set-aside payments are treated, there will be a situation, and you said so in your evidence Dr Jones, where the SFP will be treated as an income and the recipient of the payments will be regarded as a farmer engaging in a trade in most circumstances. There will be a temptation for a good number of farmers to simply abandon land, will there not, but that will be constrained by the tax implications of that which seem to sit between abandoning productive farming and merely doing a minimum for cross-compliance activity? Where will that boundary lie? At which point do you feel that the Inland Revenue say this is not a trading activity, we are not going to treat it as such and we will not allow expenses to be charged against it in terms of transport and buildings and so on? There is a dilemma here, is there not, for farmers?

  Dr Jones: There is a dilemma. The background to the dilemma is that the whole reason why we are decoupling subsidies is largely to avoid the trade distorting effects of subsidy. We must, as far as the WTO is concerned, put these subsidy payments into the "green box" and that means that they cannot be linked to agricultural production, even tenuously. On the other hand, it is hard to then argue with the Inland Revenue that they are linked with agriculture because they are not, they are simply linked with some cross-compliance conditions, and those cross-compliance conditions, whilst they might possibly encompass things like minimum stocking rates, if those minimum stocking rates are anything other than very slight and very focused on environmental care, then the subsidy will no longer be in the green box and we will have to start all over again. The answer is that they are under threat in terms of their tax status and I think the Inland Revenue will probably start to look differently at them if people are de facto not really engaged in farming.

  Q193 David Taylor: Have the RICS sounded out the Inland Revenue in any way to assess in what way tax treatment might change?

  Dr Jones: No, we have not. Although there has been a meeting of the Agricultural Law Association that discussed what the implications might be, we have not got as far as discussing it with the Revenue.

  Q194 Chairman: Can I ask the bankers have you had your tax experts crawl over this? If one of your customers came to you and said, "Right, well, I am going for the minimalist farm approach now," are you giving them some advice that they ought to take some professional tax advice because they might lose their position as a result of that?

  Mr Lole: We will be awaiting a clear understanding of what the finished situation looks like because the level of activity required for cross-compliance will clearly have an impact on that and some of the implementation will clearly have an impact on that.

  Q195 Chairman: Have either of you had any dialogue with the farming community in discussing with them their choice either of historic or regional averaging in terms of the implications that we have discussed both in terms of land value and tax so far? Have they come to you and said, "What do you as bankers to the agricultural industry think about it?", or do they see you waiting to give judgment when the facts are known?

  Mr Ellwood: I think in answer to your first question, and just to be clear, the answer is no, the HSBC have had no conversations whatsoever with tax experts. Clearly interacting with the farming community on a regular basis then all sorts of hypotheses are put forward as to what might be the outcome, but I can honestly say that no-one has talked to me about taxation in those conversations. At this moment in time income tax is not the primary concern for a lot of farmers.

  Q196 Mr Drew: I am sorry to have missed the early part of what you were saying, but if I can move us on to production and the environment. This is principally to Dr Jones. Can you give us a very quick synopsis of whether you think the view that there will be quite a production cut is likely to be what is now fulfilled or is there a rationalist view, which I gather is what Ben Gill has been putting around, that in fact there are some compromises that can be made which is going to result in less of a production cut for them than was originally anticipated?

  Dr Jones: I suppose it is difficult because Ben Gill made the point in his evidence, which I read from your last session, that whilst decoupling might mean something rather drastic to an economist, to a farmer, who is dedicated to farming, it might provide him with an opportunity of receiving his subsidy in a different way, possibly with different sorts of strings attached but otherwise he might carry on pretty much as he is at the moment. Personally I do not quite share that view. I think farmers are astute as businessmen as well as enjoying a certain lifestyle and I think they look pretty carefully at their costs and if something really is not making sense they will not necessarily continue with it. Of course it will vary considerably because production levels vary across the country and all the rest of it. I would like to take issue, if I may, with his response to a question that the Chairman asked him in the evidence last time which is this issue about beef farming which in particular I have suggested will see a downturn. I have suggested that that is on the basis that calves for beef fattening come either from the dairy herd, which we know is going to go through a process of rationalisation, and also from beef suckler herds, and beef suckler herds are supported by subsidy to an extraordinary extent. The level of headage payment at the moment is £158 a head. I have calculated that the possible amount of subsidy coming back through the calf, if you like, because of its fattening subsidies later on in the chain, might be worth, say, another £75 a head. The gross margin, which is the income from a beef suckler cow less its direct costs of feed and so forth, is around £212-£215 a head. That is less than the subsidy. So if you take the subsidy away you get a negative result, and I cannot see under those circumstances quite why people would want to keep them unless they are getting premium prices for their calves. His response to that was that beef is a "Cinderella" enterprise, it is maybe the second, third or fourth enterprise on a farm, but really, even if it is, under those circumstances and if subsidy is now being paid in a different form, why on earth do it?

  Q197 Mr Drew: We will take that as an imponderable about what really is going to happen with production but we do on the back of that then have a fairly stark situation with regard to the impact on the environment and there are those who say less farming potentially a better environment, particularly if you pay farmers then to be stewards of the countryside to put some positive public good back into the countryside. There are those who will then argue, well, if you have lost that subsidy the only way that farmers can really react is to farm more intensively with more artificial aids. Which of those points of view are likely to be the more predominant or will both be the case and it will depend on where and who is doing it?

  Dr Jones: In a rational market you would expect that if something were not profitable any longer enough people would get out of it, that supply would shorten and the price would strengthen and you would hit a new equilibrium. It might be at a lower level of output but nevertheless the thing would sort itself out by free market economics. The problem is that elsewhere in Europe three-quarters of the suckler cows might well continue to receive their full payment. We operate in a European market or a global market so what we do not really know is the extent to which these cutbacks in production might be compensated by better prices for farmers. We know that where it is in a particular production supplied to a local market there has to be a point at which the price starts to rise and compensate.

  Q198 Chairman: Can I ask our two bankers what are your initial thoughts about how a farmer should actually view these payments? Should they tuck them away in the back pocket and say, "Well, that is money I can use to do something else on the enterprise known as my farm" or should I devise some accounting method to effectively cross-subsidise activities, going back to the point Dr Jones was making a second ago, do not in themselves pay. What is your financial advice going to be to farmers who may seek an indication as to how to treat these monies by whatever mechanism they get to them?

  Mr Lole: We have been trying to work with our customers to help them understand that they do not need to continue an existing enterprise if it is not profitable in its own right and also to view the payments as a means of making a change and possibly a transitional payment as something they should try to grasp earlier rather than later along with the change so that their end position improves.

  Q199 Chairman: Because we have talked about the payment and the attitude to it. The money going to farming is going to be top-sliced in various ways. There is going to be a net leaching of cash out of farming in addition to a different view to it that will be taken as a payment as opposed to a subsidy which is directly related to production. In terms of the general health of agricultural finance—and perhaps Mr Ellwood would like to comment on this—is farming going to be able to cope, say, over the next five years with the movement of some money out of direct payment to farmers and this very focused, market-based decision-making process to which Mr Lole referred?

  Mr Ellwood: I think the answer is we do not know.


1   Ev 45 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 6 May 2004