Supplementary memorandum submitted by
Dr James V.H. Jones
IMPLICATIONS OF THE CAP REFORM DECISIONS
FOR ENGLAND ANNOUNCED ON 12 FEBRUARY 2004
SUMMARY
The Single Payment is to be delivered
to farmers in England by way of a "dynamic hybrid" system
that phases out the individual historic claims element by 2012.
A flat rate payment will be calculated
separately in the Specially Disadvantaged Area.
Ignoring the effect of payment cuts
for modulation etc. the payment should be around £65-85/ha
(£26-34/acre) in the SDA and £210-230/ha (£93-85/acre)
elsewhere.
The exact level of payments over
time is complicated by changes in the overall ceiling on payments
on the one hand and cuts due to modulation and financial discipline
on the other.
The modulation cuts are now likely
to be greater than those envisaged by the Curry Commission because
the UK government match funding contribution will be lower and
because some of the EU compulsory modulation funds will not be
refunded.
Together financial discipline and
modulation cuts alone are likely to reduce payments by between
19 and 25% by 2012.
The reform of the sugar sector might
create require some rearrangement in the UK ceiling to compensate
sugar producers who are exclusively in England.
Set aside rates are likely to be
reduced by being applied over a larger areapossibly from
10% down to 7%.
In the SDA sheep farmers are likely
to benefit from the change to flat rate average payment but beef
farmers will loose out unless they are very lightly stocked.
Farmers in the Disadvantaged Area
are likely to benefit but more in the case of sheep farmers than
for those with beef suckler cows.
Dairy farmers are likely to loose
out unless they average less than 7,750 litres per hectare (3,135
litres per acre). Intensive units with flying herds, maize forage
and high yields are most likely to be worse off and extensive
grass based dairies with lower yields and rearing their own replacements
will fare better.
Lowland sheep producers are likely
to be better off and suckler beef producers worse off than they
would have been under an historic entitlement system.
Tradability of the Single Payment
is likely to be restricted and at low values.
This will adversely affect the balance
sheets of farmers with existing quotas.
Tenants will fare markedly worse
and landlords better than under an historic system.
Land prices will be distorted by
what is effectively a flat rate subsidy attachment.
Scotland and Wales are to adopt an
historic basis and the Northern Irish hybrid is "static"the
main potential implication of the use of alternative methods is
the potential migration of milk quota out of England in 2005.
INTRODUCTION
1. The Secretary of State Margaret Beckett
announced decisions on what is intended for CAP reform implementation
in England in the House of Commons on 12 February. It was preceded
by announcements from Edinburgh, Belfast and Cardiff earlier in
the week. The most important element in all these announcements
has been on the delivery of the new single payment. Scotland and
Wales have opted for an historic basis of entitlement. Northern
Ireland and England have opted for "hybrids" between
historic basis and flat rate payments but of a very different
nature.
Northern Ireland
2. In Northern Ireland the hybrid proposed
is of a type referred to as "vertical" because it treats
current subsidy regimes differently. So some will contribute wholly
or partially to historic payment entitlement whereas others contribute
more to a flat rate average payment which all farmers receive.
There are no proposals to change the percentages over time. So
it is a "static" hybrid.
England
3. In England however there is no differentiation
based on subsidy regimes from which the money was, in effect,
derived. But across the board there will be an element based on
past receipts and an element that is a flat rate based on averaging
all payments. This will not stay the same but will alter over
time so that the flat rate element will increase and the historic
element will be phased out. In order to try and avoid some of
the extremes of redistribution two separate areas are identified
within which the subsidy redistribution will occur. These are
the Specially Disadvantaged Area (the most extreme conditions
within the Less Favoured Area) and all other land. Payment rates
will be markedly different in these two areas. It will certainly
not eliminate redistribution of subsidy. It will redistribute
subsidy within the SDA possibly to quite a significant extent.
It will leave part of the Less Favoured Areathe Disadvantaged
Area with the much higher lowland rate of payment. and it will
also leave those with the highest potential payments per hectare
in the non-SDA area (such as dairy farmers and intensive beef
units) with less subsidy than they might have had on a historic
basis. Details of this are available from the Ministerial statement
and a question and answer brief on the DEFRA website. It is not
intended to go over these in this brief.
4. What we aim to do in this brief is to
give a preliminary assessment of a number of the potential implications
of the proposed Single Payment Scheme for England. What might
appear at first sight to be a simple and possibly an uncontroversial
proposal actually throws up quite a number of important issues
that need to be clarified in the coming weeks and months. It is
also important to stress at this stage that these proposals will
have to fit the detailed implementing regulations for the CAP
reform in general and these have yet to be confirmed by Brussels.
DEFRA have been in close contact with the EU Commission to achieve
conformity with proposed EU regulations as far as this is possibleas
confirmed by Lord Whitty in his evidence to the House of Commons
Environment Food and Rural Affairs Committee (EFRA) only the day
before the announcement. But it was admitted by Lord Whitty to
the EFRA Committee (last Wednesday) that not even Commissioner
Fischler knew every detail of what those regulations would be.
THE VALUE
ATTACHED TO
THE HISTORIC
ELEMENT IN
THE SINGLE
PAYMENT
5. The proposals alter the balance between
the historic and the flat rate elements as shown in Figure 1 below.
This shows that before 2008 the historic element will make up
the majority of the payment but after that time it will be the
smaller element and will be quickly eroded so that by 2012 it
will have disappeared altogether.
Figure 1 Historic and flat rate elements
in the Single Payment Scheme for England

6. The situation is complicated by the fact
that the total amount of money available to redistribute gets
larger during the early years until 2007 (see Table 1 below).
After 2007 the amount is expected to remain the same for the UK
although reform of the sugar sector might make it necessary to
readjust the allocation of the UK ceiling giving a larger share
to England (the cost of sugar reform is discussed later).
Table 1
THE UK CEILING ON ALL PAYMENTS
| Ceiling | Dairy payments
| Non-dairy payments |
| Euro millions |
Euro millions | Euro millions
|
| | |
|
2005 | 3,350 | 167
| 3,183 |
2006 | 3,350 | 334
| 3,016 |
2007 and onwards | 3,868 |
503 | 3,365 |
7. So not only does the flat rate element get bigger
over time the overall amount of money that can be spread gets
bigger. The allocation of the ceiling within the UK will presumably
depend on the distribution of subsidy under present regimes and
new ones. Table 2 below attempts to assess the breakdown. It shows
that the allocation to England should increase as both the dairy
and eventually the sugar sectors generate direct payments that
are decoupled and converted into Single Payment.
Table 2
DISTRIBUTION OF HISTORIC SUBSIDY RECEIPTS AND PRODUCTION
IN THE UNREFORMED SECTORS AS AN INDICATION OF POSSIBLE BASIS FOR
SINGLE PAYMENT SUBSIDY ALLOCATION IN THE REGIONS OF THE UK
| England | Wales
| Scotland | Northern
Ireland
| UK |
Historic receipt of subsidy | £ million
| £ million | £ million
| £ million | £ million
|
Subsidy payments in 2002
Crop subsidies and set aside
| 902.2 | 11.5 | 118.9
| 8.7 | 1,041.3 |
Livestock subsidies | 432.8 |
123.8 | 243.0 | 166.5
| 966.1 |
Total | 1,335.0 | 135.3
| 361.9 | 175.2 | 2,007.4
|
Proportion | 66.50 % | 6.74 %
| 18.03 % | 8.73 % |
|
Subsidy basis in unreformed sectors
Dairy
| mil. litres | mil. litres |
mil. litres | mil. litres | mil. litres
|
Milk quota in 2001-02 | 9,934.4
| 1,425.8 | 1,160.9 | 1,651.7
| 14,172.8 |
Proportion | 70.09 % | 10.06 %
| 8.19 % | 11.65 % |
|
Sugar | 000's has | 000's has
| 000's has | 000's has | 000's has
|
Sugar beet area | 169.0 | 0.0
| 0.0 | 0.0 | 169.0
|
Proprtion | 100.00 % | 0.00 %
| 0.00 % | 0.00 % |
|
| | |
| | |
THE AMOUNT
OF SUBSIDY
PAYMENT ON
THE FLAT
RATE BASIS
8. The flat rate subsidy will depend on the allocation
of the total amount of money available within the UK and how it
is spread between the SDA area and the non-SDA area. The NFU have
put an estimated value of between £65 and £85 per hectare
(£25 and £34/acre) in the SDA and £210 and £230
per hectare (£85 and £93/acre) in the non-SDA area.The
exact figures do depend on:
the subsidy allocation between SDA and non-SDA
(and this can change as dairy and sugar are largely in the non-SDA);
the SDA areathis sounds easier to determine
than it is because it is eligible agricultural area we need to
determine and not just an area on a map; and
the exchange ratewhich is by no means stable.
But we have produced an estimate of the SDA eligible area
based on figures used by Drew Associates and Exeter University
in an Economic Evaluation of HLCA payments undertaken in 1997
(page 98) which identified just over a million hectares of SDA
land farmed in conjunction with a further 230,000 hectares of
SDA common land.
Table 3 below compares this with the NFU estimates to see
how the total matches up to the maximum amount of money available
set by the payments ceiling (post 2007). The ceiling at an exchange
rate of 68 pence to the euro lies between the NFU upper and lower
limits assuming the ceiling is allocated according to the basis
in Table 2 but ignoring a potential sugar payment.
Table 3
COMPARING ESTIMATES OF THE FLAT RATE PAYMENT RATES WITH
THE UPPER LIMIT ON PAYMENTS SET BY THE CEILING
SDA area estimate | hectares
| | |
Land in the SDA in England | 1,106,084
| | |
Common land farmed with SDA | 230,000
| | |
Total | 1,246,084 |
| |
SDA as a % of the eligible area? | 14.11%
| | |
Total eligible area (2002) | 8,833,900
| | |
Non-SDA eligible area | 7,587,816
| | |
NFU estimates of payments |
| | |
Payment rates | Rates
| Total amount | |
| £ per ha |
£ millions | % of total
|
SDA high | £85 | £106
| 5.7% |
SDA low | £65 | £81
| 4.8% |
Non-SDA high | £230 |
£1,745 | |
Non SDA low | £210 |
£1,593 | |
Combined SDA and non-SDA |
| | |
Highs | | £1,851
| |
Lows | | £1,674
| |
RICS estimate of ceiling
UK ceiling post 2007 | 3,868
| million euros |
English share | 67.0% |
|
English ceiling | 2,591 |
million euros |
Value of ceiling at 680/$ | 1,762
| |
| | |
What these figures do not allow for is any cuts in payment.
These are important because before we can establish anything about
the redistribution of subsidy, the influence on land prices and
rents, etc. during the time that the dynamic hybrid is going to
adjust them we have to establish how much the payments are going
to be over time.
PAYMENTS CUTS
OVER TIME
9. Points about these cuts have been reworked several
times already and appeared in earlier briefing notes. The main
charges are that we know a national reserve will be required at
least initially because
National reservewill be required
because at least initially 90% of payments are based on historic
entitlement and hence the special cases against a history subsidy
not having been paid in the past for a variety of reasons is pertinent.
National envelopeswill not be used
so what could have been a cut of up to 10% in payments will not
apply
Scalebacks may be required against historic
based allocations if these exceed the ceiling on payments (see
the Update brief part 2 of 23 January Table 6) which suggests
a scaleback of up to 5% might need to be applied)
Financial discipline cutsare likely
to be required as the Accession States that join the EU on 1st
May 2004 become entitled to an increasing proportion of the full
rate of their Single Payment.
Modulationboth by the EU and the
UK.
It is the last two of these that represent the greatest overall
cut and they will apply regardless of whether payments are made
on a flat rate or an historic basis. So we examine these in more
depth to try and forecast a possible level of cut.
Financial discipline
10. Financial discipline cuts are likely to be subject
to a
5,000 "franchise". This means that the first
5,000 of Single payment will escape the cut regardless of the
level. This not only means that some farmers will suffer more
than others but also it redistributes the burden throughout the
EU dependent really on the number of small farmers each country
has. It makes it harder to forecast cut levels.
Figure 2 Proportion of direct payments that would ecape
cust by falling into a
5,000 franchise

The graph above shows that the UK has 15.4% of direct payments
that fall into the below
5,000 bracket. In the EU 15 the average is 33.2% and some countries
have up to 70% of direct subsidy falling into the cut free bracket.
Deeper cuts have to be made on the two thirds of payment that
is affected in order to compensate for the third that escapes
it.
11. The Commission originally set out financial discipline
cuts on fixed percentages when they took the form of a degressive
cut. They had to allow not only for the phasing in of Accession
State subsidies but also any additional reform. We can see that
some of this additional reform is now confirmed. But figures have
not yet been revised. Table 4 below shows rates of cut that would
have been dictated just by maintaining a status quo and without
any contingency. Assuming that 33.2% escapes a cut (a percentage
that will have to be revised as it only applies to the EU-15)
then we can anticipate cuts starting in 2008 and increasing to
over 4% by 2012. In reality this is probably a minimum rather
than a likely figure. But one imponderable is what happens to
the budget for the remaining market support. This is affected
by such factors as the deal with the WTO, international commodity
prices, exchange rates etc and it cannot be easily predicted.
Table 4
LIKELY MINIMUM RATES OF FINANCIAL DISCIPLINE CUT BASED
ON DEFICITS PROJECTED IN JANUARY 2003 BASED ON "STATUS QUO"
SUPPORT REQUIREMENTS
| Pillar 1a |
| Exposed | |
| ceiling | Deficit
| to cuts | Percentage
|
| mil euro | mil euro
| mil euro | cut
|
| | |
| |
2008 | 46,271 | -517
| 30,873 | -1.67% |
2009 | 46,679 | -788
| 31,182 | -2.53% |
2010 | 47,146 | -1,111
| 31,494 | -3.53% |
2011 | 47,617 | -1,253
| 31,808 | -3.88% |
2012 | 48,093 | -1,355
| 32,126 | -4.22% |
2013 | 48,574 | -1,470
| 32,447 | -4.53% |
Modulation
12. The government has been very coy about providing
any forecast on the likely level of any additional modulation
above that provided for as compulsory by the EU. The reason for
this may be that the level may have to be greater than might otherwise
have been the case because the contribution by the UK government
under new "co-financing" arrangements is likely to be
less than had previously been anticipated. So in effect what might
previously have been required as a 10% flat rate modulation to
raise the equivalent of 20% of pillar 1 funding now becomes 5%
of EU compulsory modulation plus 9.2% of flat rate modulation.
This is because the EU modulation is subject to a
5,000 cut free franchise which cuts payments by 15.4% and the
UK is likely to only get back 80% of the funds contributed (the
minimum). Both EU and UK modulation are assumed to be co-financed
at 40% and not 50% as was previously the case.
These effects are summarised in Table 5 below.
Table 5
THE EFFECT ON NEW MODULATION ARRANGEMENTS COMPARED WITH
THE FUNDS GENERATED BY UK FLAT RATE MODULATION
Pre-MTR raising Pillar 2 finance by just using UK (flat rate) modulation
Modulation amount
| Cofinancing at 50% | Total
| |
10% | 10% | 20%
| |
Post MTR raising Pillar 2 finance by EU compulsory and UK flat rate modulation
EU modulation gets reduced:
Compulsory headline rate
| Franchise loss of 15.4% | 20% retained by EU
| Net |
5% | -0.77% | 0.85%
| 3.38% |
| Rate | Co-financing at 40%
| Total |
EU compulsory | 3.38% | 1.35%
| 4.73% |
UK modulation | 9.16% | 6.11%
| 15.27% |
Total | |
| 20.00% |
| | |
|
13. So whilst the generation of EU compulsory modulated
funds was expected to replace the need for higher rates of UK
modulation in practice it looks like merely adding to it. The
additional modulation is required to fund the Entry Level Agri-environment
scheme which is an addition to the requirements already earmarked
in the England Rural Development Plan. That plan already envisaged
modulation at 4.5% by 2006. That would now have to be 5.4% to
produce the same amount of money.
Table 6 below shows the amount of money required to fund
the Entry Level Scheme at the rates used in the pilot schemewhich
are £30/ha in the lowland and £15/ha in the Less Favoured
Area. The Curry Commission suggested that 10% modulation would
be required to fund the ELS along with other agri-environment
schemes. It looks as though this might now be needed in addition
to the 5% EU compulsory modulation. The Entry Level Scheme will
not be the only additional demand on Pillar 2 funding. There will
also be an expanded menu of funds available to meet cross-compliance
conditions on areas such as food quality assurance, traceability,
animal welfare and environmental protection.
Table 6
ESTIMATES OF THE BASIC COST OF THE ENTRY LEVEL AGRI-ENVIRONMENT
SCHEME AND THE IMPACT ON MODULATION REQUIREMENTS
| Lowland | LFA
| Total | Modulation rate
on pillar 1 ceiling
required
|
Payment rate in £ per ha | £30
| £15 | |
|
Area in total in millions of hectares | 7.5
| 1.5 | 9.1 |
|
Cost of 10% coverage in £ million |
£22.6 | £2.3 | £24.9
| 0.85% |
Cost of 20% coverage in £ million |
£45.2 | £4.6 | £49.8
| 1.70% |
Cost of 30% coverage in £ million |
£67.8 | £6.9 | £74.7
| 2.54% |
Cost of 40% coverage in £ million |
£90.3 | £9.3 | £99.6
| 3.39% |
Cost of 50% coverage in £ million |
£112.9 | £11.6 | £124.5
| 4.24% |
Cost of 60% coverage in £ million |
£135.5 | £13.9 | £149.4
| 5.09% |
Cost of 70% coverage in £ million |
£158.1 | £16.2 | £174.3
| 5.94% |
Assumptions:
Ceiling is £1,762 million at an exchange rate of 68 pence per euro
No franchise is applied i.e. the cut is flat rate
Co-financing is at 40%
| | | |
|
Combined effect of cuts on the flat rate payment
14. It is difficult to estimate the overall result of
all these factors. But the modulation and financial discipline
alone are likely to result in cuts of between 18 and 23% by the
end of the decade (as shown in Table 7 below). A national reserve
of up to 3% will be needed at least until the historic element
of the subsidy has been phased out.
Table 7
ESTIMATES OF THE COMBINED EFFECT OF MODULATION AND FINANCIAL
DISCIPLINE
| Modulation
| Financial discipline |
Total effect |
| |
| |
| EU | UK
| Minimum required | Based on degression
| | on SP over
5,000
|
| |
| | | min
| max |
2005 | 3% | 4.5%
| 0% | 0% | 7.5%
| 7.5% |
2006 | 4% | 6.0%
| 0% | 0% | 10.0%
| 10.0% |
2007 | 5% | 8.0%
| 0% | 1.5% | 13.0%
| 14.5% |
2008 | 5% | 10.0%
| 1.7% | 4.8% | 16.7%
| 19.8% |
2009 | 5% | 10.0%
| 2.5% | 7.7% | 17.5%
| 22.7% |
2010 | 5% | 10.0%
| 3.5% | 8.3% | 18.5%
| 23.3% |
2011 | 5% | 10.0%
| 3.9% | 9.0% | 18.9%
| 24.0% |
2012 | 5% | 10.0%
| 4.2% | 9.8% | 19.2%
| 24.8% |
| |
| | |
| |
If we assume a 23% cut by the end of the decade. Flat rate
payments would be cut back from say £220/ha to £170/ha
(£89/acre to £69/acre) in the non-SDA and say from £75/ha
to £58/ha (£30/acre to £23/acre) in the SDA.
THE EFFECT
OF REFORM
OF THE
SUGAR SECTOR
15. Another imponderable is the effect of sugar reform.
This is being examined seriously at both EU and UK level at present.
But the EU have pledged to remove tariffs on "everything
but arms" by 2009 to countries which include the low cost
sugar cane producers of the Caribbean. If this follows the pattern
of previous reforms a lowering of tariffs and the intervention
price would be accompanied by the creation of an area payment.
This would almost certainly be decoupled and included in the Single
Payment. The ceiling set by Brussels cannot be increased. We can
see that it will in any event already need to be cut after 2008
as a result of the need for Financial Discipline. So a sugar area
payment would have to be accommodated within the ceiling.
The intervention price for refined white sugar stood in 2002
at about
646 per tonne well above the world price of
264/tonne. The world price is only 41% of the intervention price
level. If farm gate prices came down to world prices beet would
fall to about £13.50/tonne from the present A quota price
of about £33/tonne. The three-year average yield of beet
2000 to 2002 in the UK was 51.75 tonnes per hectare. If fully
compensated a £19.50 price drop would be worth just over
£1,000/hectare in area aid payment.The sugar beet area is
about 169,000 hectares and it is all in England. Based on full
compensation an area payment would add about £169 million
to direct payments relative to an estimated English ceiling of
about £1,762 million before any adjustments of the apportionment
of the ceiling with other regions of the UK. In reality the compensation
is likely to be much less and full compensation is not always
made for price cuts.
SET ASIDE
16. The spreading of payments under the hybrid will also
require a spreading of the set aside requirement. It is not clear
how this will be done. But one approach would be to spread it
out across the whole area registered as eligible for Arable Area
Aid payments. This is an area of 5.3 million hectares in the UK
relative to an actual area for crops and set aside (the base area)
of 3.8 million hectares. Assuming it was scaled back in proportion
a set aside rate on the base area of 10% would become a rate of
about 7% on the whole AAAP area.
WINNERS AND
LOSERS IN
THE UPLANDS
17. If we compare present subsidy rates with the NFU
estimate of flat rate before any overall cuts in payment (which
apply whether the Single Payment is paid on a historic or a flat
rate basis) then we can establish the kind of stocking densities
that mark the threshold between the winners and the losers. Table
8 below shows the effects.
Table 8
THRESHOLD STOCKING RATES FOR WINNERS AND LOSERS IN THE
SDA
SDA flat rate payment (before any cuts) £75.00 per hectare
Sheep annual premium per ewe £13.54 per ewe
Suckler cow premium with extensification £214.99 per
cow
Plus £75/cow indirect from fattening subsidies £289.99
per cow
Threshold stocking rate for sheep 5.54 per hectare 2.24
per acre
Threshold stocking rate for suckler cows based on SCP 0.35
per hectare 0.14 per acre
Threshold stocking rate for suckler cows plus indirect 0.26
per hectare 0.10 per acre
The lower level of support for sheep relative to that for
suckler cows means that beef farmers are more likely to lose out
by the conversion to flat rate than sheep farmers in the uplands.
This seems to be born out by survey figures. Although the figures
in Table 9 below are for the UK rather than for just England they
show the much higher rates of subsidy for sheep farms in the SDA
relative to cattle farms. The sheep farms might find that they
receive more subsidy on the flat rate basis the beef farms will
almost certainly receive less.
Table 9
DIRECT SUBSIDIES THAT ARE TO BE DECOUPLED (ie excluding
the HFA payments) ON FARMS IN THE SPECIALLY DISADVANTAGED AREA
SDA mixed sheep and cattle in the UK
| | |
| Payments per farm | £ per ha
|
Direct livestock subsidies | £19,248
| £90.33 |
Direct crop subsidies | £158
| £0.74 |
| £19,406 | £91.1
|
SDA specialist sheep in the UK |
| |
| Payments per farm | £ per ha
|
Direct livestock subsidies | £13,578
| £46.09 |
Direct crop subsidies | £20
| £0.07 |
| £13,598 | £46.2
|
SDA specialist beef in the UK |
| |
| Payments per farm | £ per ha
|
Direct livestock subsidies | £18,678
| £168.64 |
Direct crop subsidies | £805
| £7.27 |
| £19,483 |
£175.9 |
| | |
There is very little cropping receiving arable area payment
in the SDA area. But there is a little in Northumberland and the
border with Wales. This will be hit very hard, as payment levels
would fall from around £245/ha on the historic basis to only
around £75/ha at a flat rate.
WINNERS AND
LOSERS IN
THE NON-SDA
AREA
18. One group of likely winners are the farmers in the
Disadvantaged Area because they have the lower stocking rates
associated with hill farming but are not in the SDA. Table 10
below shows average results for the UK and indicates that they
may not be major winners overall. But as with the SDA sheep farmers
are likely to be winners and cattle farmers may gain little if
anything from a conversion to flat rate.
Table 10
DIRECT PAYMENTS (excluding HFA) ON DISADVANTAGED AREA
FARMS IN THE UK
| Payments per farm
| £ per ha |
Direct livestock subsidies | £13,379
| £201.81 |
Direct crop subsidies | £267
| £4.03 |
| £13,646 |
£205.8 |
| | |
Table 11 below shows the thresholds for stocking rates and
milk production (based on quota holding for Dairy Premiums). Some
of these subsidies overlap and to a varying extent. So there is
no fixed relationship between Dairy Premiums based on quota holding
and Slaughter Premiums based on replacement of cull cows. Every
fattening beef animal would get a Slaughter Premium but only male
animals can get a Beef Special Premium and they can get this twice
although claims are limited to 90 per farm. So it is impossible
to be precise. But the figures in the table give an indication.
Dairy farms are likely to lose out. The higher the output
per hectarea function of yield and stocking rate the more
likely they are to lose. If they are maize or whole crop cereal
growers then they will be more likely to lose out because they
also receive arable area aid payments. Those who rear their own
replacements lose out less than those with flying herds. Beef
farmers are likely to have stocking rates above the threshold
that makes them losers. Sheep farmers are likely to be winners
as their stocking rates are almost certainly below the threshold.
The more extensive their production the more likely they are to
gain by a move to flat rate.
Table 11
THRESHOLD STOCKING RATES AND DAIRY PRODUCTION FOR WINNERS
AND LOSERS BY MOVING TO FLAT RATE PAYMENT IN THE NON-SDA
Non-SDA flat rate payment (before any cuts)
| £220.00 per hectare |
|
Milk Dairy Premium and Additional Amount after 2007
| 2.49 pence per litre | |
Dairy payments threshold on an area basis |
8,835 litres per ha | 3,576 per acre
|
Slaughter premium on cull cows | £54.17 per head
| £27.09 per ha |
Dairy payments threshold with slaughter premium
| 7,748 litres per ha | 3,135 per acre
|
Sheep annual premium per ewe | £13.54 per ewe
| |
Threshold stocking rate for sheep | 16.25 per hectare
| 6.58 per acre |
Slaughter Premium plus Beef Special Premium
| 150.66 per head | |
Slaughter Premium on an area basis | 1.46 per hectare
| 0.59 per acre |
Suckler cow premium without extensification
| £160.82 per cow | |
Plus £75/cow indirect from fattening subsidies
| £235.82 per cow | |
Threshold stocking rate for suckler cows based on SCP
| 1.37 per hectare | 0.55 per acre
|
Threshold stocking rate for suckler cows plus indirect
| 0.93 per hectare | 0.38 per acre
|
| | |
THE TRADABILITY
OF SINGLE
PAYMENT ENTITLEMENT
19. In order for the entitlement to Single Payment to
be worth trading it must have a value over and above the flat
rate level of payment. The historic basis represents 90% of the
value of payment at the outset. So one might assume that this
would be enough to create at least in the short term a basis for
trading. However there are a number of reasons why this is not
likely to be significant enough to create either much value or
much trade. These are:
1. There will not be any land that is totally without
Single Payment (the so called "naked acres") even though
at first the amount will be smaller it will increase quite rapidly.
2. Trade cannot start until 2006 because in order to trade
entitlement you must exercise it first. So trading cannot effectively
begin until 2006 by which time the historic element has already
been reduced.
3. After 2006 the influence of the historic element reduces
rapidly so that after 2008 it comprises a minority element in
the entitlement.
4. The payments that might have been the highest per hectare
on the historic basis were those from dairy farms. However dairy
payments do not reach their full amount until 2007 and as after
2008 the historic element is less than half the entitlement the
impact will be very much diluted and short lived.
5. Arable derived payments will be only slightly above
the rate under a flat rate system.
6. The overall level of payments and therefore any advantage
to higher payment levels generated from historic claims will be
cut back by modulation, the national envelope, possibly scalebacks
and eventually also by financial discipline. Even in the early
years when the historic element is worth more it will be reduced
by EU and UK modulation of at least 8 or 9% and a national reserve
requirement of say 3%.
The net result is that without going into detailed calculations
it is unlikely that there will be much trading and that if this
does take place at all values will be low.
IMPACT ON
RENTAL VALUES
AND LANDLORD
AND TENANT
RELATIONS
20. It was predicted in earlier briefing papers that
if a historic claims based system were adopted then landlords
would be very vulnerable because tenants could sell their payments
entitlement or move to another farm leaving the farm without any
subsidy entitlement.
If a Regional Average ie flat rate system were adopted then
tenants would be vulnerable. This is because entitlement would
in effect be all but attached to the land. All farmers would receive
it and all the tenant could do would be to refuse to transfer
it to the landlord. They could not sell it or exercise it on land
that currently did not have any entitlement.
So it follows that if there is little value attached to the
entitlement and little trade in it then even at the start of the
conversion period the effect will be similar to that of a flat
rate basis as far as landlords and tenants are concerned.
21. On Farm Business Tenancies with little security of
tenure or short duration then it can be anticipated that rents
will have to reflect the fact that landlords have a fairly comfortable
option of receiving flat rate payment without having to actively
farm the land. They would have to respect cross compliance conditions
and under go maintenance. But it is bound to create a floor price.
This is little different from the current situation on arable
land where rents are certainly influenced if not actually pegged
by the arable area aid and set aside payment levels. But on livestock
farms where rents are lower due to the fact that landlords would
have to keep stock and possibly have a quota for entitlement to
headage payments to receive subsidy one can anticipate rent rises
as the flat rate element starts to deliver subsidies without any
such obligations attached.
On Agricultural Holdings Act tenancies the security of tenure
and statutory rental arbitration formula offers less chance of
landlords taking advantage of the situation. But it is going to
be more difficult to decide what an appropriate level of income
will be and it may be that arbitrators will have to take into
account whether tenants have taken advantage of the Single Payment
whilst opting to do very little farming as opposed to those that
are still actively engaged in production. This certainly merits
some careful thinking perhaps by the cross-industry group set
up to look at tenancy issues (TRIG).
POTENTIAL IMPACT
ON LAND
PRICES
22. Land prices are clearly influenced by many more factors
than just subsidy income or even for that matter farming income.
But in as much as this does have a bearing on price the Single
Payment moving to a flat rate payment basis is likely to have
the following effects:
1. Subsidy entitlement will attach to the land and not
be a separate item detachable from itas would have been
the case with the historic tradable Single Farm Payment.
2. Land that now has subsidy attached to it and/or has
subsidy that is greater that it would otherwise have been will
be worth more eg the winners and losers in both the SDA and the
non-SDA including land in the Disadvantaged Area.
3. There is at present a price differential between AAAP
registered land and land withoutthis distinction in as
much as it relates to subsidy potential alone will disappear.
4. Non farming purchasers may be more attracted to buying
land which comes with a subsidy entitlement regardless of production
as opposed to only being able to access the subsidy through farming
activities.
But it is worth pointing out that the land market is small
and is increasingly influenced by non-farming purchasers. This
might have been exaggerated by the uncertainties created by the
MTR but the market has been getting smaller and more influenced
by 'lifestyle buyers' in any case. The Savills Agricultural Research
Briefing No. 23, which has only recently been released, makes
this point convincingly.
IMPLICATIONS OF
ADOPTION OF
DIFFERENT SYSTEMS
IN OTHER
PARTS OF
THE UK
23. The implications of running different systems of
entitlement in other parts of the UK are largely ones of allocation
of the initial entitlement. Farmers who have land in both England
and Wales or Scotland will stand to gain more by their historic
claims in those countries than on the part of their farming that
relates to England. The set aside rate is likely to be lower in
England.
But there is a particular worry with dairying. That is that
English dairy farmers will not now eventually stand to gain much
by holding quota other than giving them a right to sell milk whereas
in other parts of the UK it will create a permanent entitlement
to receive subsidy based on their quota holding in 2005. That
might well prompt those who were holding off from quitting dairying
in England with a reason to leave and there will be an added incentive
for dairy farmers in other parts of the UK to acquire their quota
even if they subsequently decide to quit. So we could see a very
distorted market which according to quota broker Ian Potter has
already begun to develop in quota disappearing from England to
other parts of the UK. This clearly could have long term implications
should it develop into a large-scale movement.
BALANCE SHEET
ISSUES
24. Another aspect of the lack of value attached to the
Single Payment entitlement is the impact on balance sheetsespecially
of tenant farmers. The value attached to beef and sheep quota
will have disappeared. The value attached to milk quota after
decoupling takes place (ie after 2005) will be very small because
it relates to production only and in a market which will see substantial
reductions in the support price.
So value to quota entitlements will be taken away but is
now unlikely to be replaced by much value to be attached to the
Single Payment entitlement.
Dr James Jones Head of Farm Management at the Royal Agricultural
College, Cirencester and an RICS Countryside Policy Panel member
and stakeholder representative.
February 2004
|