Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 20-39)

9 FEBRUARY 2004

MR TIM BRIGSTOCKE, MR ANDREW CHADWICK, MR ROBERT CLARKE AND MR JOHN SUMNER

  Q20 Chairman: You have the benefit of my earlier remarks, so I hope you understand we will try to keep to the same track record, but I think it would be very useful if you would just introduce who is giving evidence, and also, because we do not necessarily take as much evidence from yourselves as we do from the NFU and others, say a couple of things about the organisation.

  Mr Brigstocke: I am Tim Brigstocke, and I am Chairman of the Royal Association of British Dairy Farmers, which for ease we will call RABDF. On my far left is John Sumner, who is our Policy Advisor. On my immediate left is Andrew Chadwick, who is a dairy farmer with 200 cows in Cheshire, and on my right is Robert Clarke, who runs a family unit of 120 cows near Preston. Both Andrew and John, as well as myself, are directors of RABDF, and Robert is also a director of Dairy Farmers of Britain. Our main activity as far as RABDF is concerned is running the Dairy Event, which is the major technology transfer event held each year at Stoneleigh, where we have about 14,000 attending a two-day event, with about 400 trade stands. So we are very much involved as an organisation in technology transfer as well as responding to consultations. We have an annual conference, which is well known and is perceived as the Oxford farming equivalent for the dairy sector, and we have also recently done two things which may be of interest: first, we have received funding under the Agricultural Development Scheme from Defra to do director training in the milk group sector, so that not just existing directors but aspiring directors are properly trained in how to run farmer-controlled businesses, and secondly, we have done quite a detailed evaluation of the costs of milk production, which has received a number of plaudits from the industry.

  Chairman: Thank you for that. That is very clear. We are going to stay in the same vein of looking at the efficiency of the industry, perhaps with some international comparisons in mind. I will ask Colin to take up the questions.

  Q21 Mr Breed: In your evidence, you claim that milk production in the UK compares very favourably with other leading dairying countries, but how efficient really is our milk production, particularly when you compare it to producers outside the European Union?

  Mr Sumner: Chairman, if you look at any set of parameters, the structure of the UK dairy farming business is strong. We have a higher than average herd size compared to Europe. We have the same average as in America, not that that says too much really. Whatever parameters you might like to take, including genetic improvement and feeding technology, then I think we compare pretty favourably with the rest of Europe.

  Q22 Mr Breed: What about outside Europe?

  Mr Sumner: If you look outside Europe at the main dairying countries, we look at New Zealand as a main competitor. If you wish to talk about Japan, I do not think the comparison is too important.

  Q23 Mr Breed: Perhaps America and New Zealand.

  Mr Sumner: If you look at America, we have the same sort of herd size and the same sort of structure as they have in America. New Zealand obviously has a larger herd size, but they have quite a different set of circumstances in terms of production and, I think in terms of technical efficiency, we can probably hold our heads up and say we are as good as they are.

  Q24 Mr Breed: I know it is very difficult to make strict comparisons because of the different ways that they look at butter fat and everything else, and therefore there will be some slight variations, but when you look at our prices and what farm gate prices are here compared to New Zealand, there is an enormous difference, yet their dairy farmers are clearly making at least adequate profits. How might you explain that?

  Mr Sumner: There is a big fundamental difference between the countries you have just described. If you look at New Zealand, most of their milk is produced from grass production; they do not have to provide winter housing conditions for their cows. They also have an industry that is geared up to exporting most of their product. Eighty-five per cent of milk produced in New Zealand is exported elsewhere, so there is quite a different culture in terms of milk production to the one that we have in the UK.

  Mr Chadwick: I do not think we are ever going to compete on price with the New Zealanders. Partly because of climate, partly because dairying in New Zealand is a very important industry, but they cannot supply the whole of the world market, however hard they try. We cannot compete either with parts of Australia. We are much more competitive with the United States, but the United States is changing. To over-generalise, it is moving from east to west dramatically. If you go to California, there are several herds of 4,000 cows, all milked in a factory system, with entirely Mexican labour, except for the owner, who is normally a first, second, or third generation Dutchman. We do not have the ability to have those very large units, and they would not be socially acceptable here. It is going to be more difficult to compete with the States.

  Mr Brigstocke: To add to that, Mr Chairman, I think the welfare standards that we have to operate in the UK are quite different to what happens in New Zealand, and particularly North America. It is interesting that Dick Sibley, who has recently, last week, won the Princess Royal Award for his outstanding contribution to the dairy farming sector as a vet, has recently been to North America to look specifically at cattle health plans, and was horrified at how bad the North American situation was.

  Q25 Mr Wiggin: Can you tell us how bad it is in New Zealand? We hear this a lot, but there is never much evidence.

  Mr Brigstocke: Really, as Mr Chadwick has just said, there are practices that are acceptable over there that would not be acceptable over here, such as tail-docking, for example. The very extensive conditions that operate over there, that animals do not have to be housed, over here just would not be acceptable.

  Q26 Mr Breed: As you may be aware, the Committee went there not so very long ago and we did look at that. They use a very low-cost system, in almost every respect.

  Mr Brigstocke: They do. It would not be acceptable.

  Q27 Mr Breed: They have hardly any labour, low concentrate, and it is a totally different system. Nevertheless, I think we are wrong sometimes to try and emphasize the animal welfare aspect, which may be slightly different, but I think it is the fact that they have a low-cost system and their yields are much lower, but at the end of the day they produce more profit. Can we look at the quota system in terms of the way in which it might distort the market for milk in the EU, such that it may in effect protect the more inefficient producers in other EU states, which are perhaps kept in business, which may disadvantage UK dairy farmers? Do you have any comment on that?

  Mr Clarke: I think it is important to remember that the UK market is one of the highest in percentage terms of domestic fresh and liquid products, and that gives a slightly different relationship between the producers and their ultimate market, or should do. From the point of view of the quota implications and the way this Government and previous governments have implemented quota regulations, we have discrepancies across the various European states as to how they have been implemented. I think we have to concentrate really on protecting the UK market for the British consumer. I am sure the British Government will want to ensure that their electorate has a constant supply of cost-effective, safe product. Issues like food security are going to come more into play. There is a great danger if some of the implications that previous contributors have indicated to you could happen in terms of the total supply of milk in the UK declining and actually threatening the UK's ability to even feed its own people with the healthy, nutritious food that milk is.

  Q28 Mr Breed: Are you entirely happy with the current quota?

  Mr Clarke: I think the way that the quota system has been implemented gives a false restriction in the marketplace. Supply and demand at the end of the day should regulate the market. When you have one issue like quota, and the perception that you should produce to the country's quota, it stifles many of the innovative and forward-thinking developments that can go on, particularly in products and in terms of product development. We have to educate—and producers have to be educated as well—to understand that "market" is not necessarily "quota", and we should be producing to the market and not to quota.

  Q29 Mr Breed: I think you mean by that you would be quite happy if quotas went?

  Mr Clarke: On a personal level, yes. As an organisation, yes.

  Mr Chadwick: Personally, I think, if the MTR comes in, and milk prices fall, as most economists expect, to about 15 pence a litre, quota, although formally there, will be irrelevant; we will not be producing to quota. That is my guess.

  Chairman: Obviously you heard us ask a number of questions, understandably, on market structure, which is key to this whole area. I am going to ask Bill to follow those up.

  Q30 Mr Wiggin: To what extent would the problems of low farm gate milk price be addressed through vertical integration and breaking what you call, I believe the price taken mould?

  Mr Clarke: The important thing to remember is that the implementation of the trust that you have heard previous speakers talk about and the level of cooperation that we need to achieve is not going to come about by any political solutions; it is going to come about through commercial solutions. It is important that we do not have any blockages in the way of that. We need to look carefully at how competition legislation is implemented and how that is applied throughout the food chain, because if we are going to see producers being able to change their fortunes by investing in processing, in forming relationships with both retailers and with established processors, to actually take more part in the chain, there has to be a level of stability, and the current pricing level does not really give them the ability or the confidence to go forward.

  Mr Sumner: Chairman, if I can support that, if we look back over the history of the dairy business since deregulation, since 1994 the industry has been severely constrained by competition law. If we are looking forward as to how the industry might develop, then we would ask the Government to look again at the way it applies competition law to the dairy industry, in that it does not present any unnecessary boulders in the way of development of the structures that we need within our business.

  Q31 Mr Wiggin: Have you talked to the Competition Commission about this? Do you think that they would stand in the way of that sort of integration?

  Mr Sumner: We have not talked direct to the Competition Commission about this particular issue, but we did give evidence as an organisation when Milk Marque had its inquiry. We had a slight concern that the competition authorities do not always carry over one message to another. Another competition inquiry that we gave evidence to did not know the outcome of the Milk Marque inquiry, which gave us a little bit of concern. But no, we have not given evidence to them, but we would welcome the opportunity to do so.

  Mr Brigstocke: From some informal discussions, we have been led to believe that they appreciate that the dairy industry has changed quite appreciably since the demise of Milk Marque, and therefore it might be a fair time to re-look at the whole situation.

  Q32 Mr Jack: Just refresh my memory. I thought that one of the main reasons why we got the changes that occurred second time round was that the Competition Commission, in their report, made adverse comments on the way that Milk Marque abused its market position, and it jumped, if you like, before it was pushed, and we ended up with the three co-op solution. Perhaps you could refresh my memory as to where there are words from the competition authorities to say "Thou shalt not vertically integrate."

  Mr Brigstocke: Mr Sumner's point was that when we were giving evidence on a different inquiry, the people asking the questions had been involved in the Milk Marque decision and wanted to know our opinion as an organisation about what had actually happened once Milk Marque had disappeared. That was the point he was trying to make.

  Mr Chadwick: I think you are right. Milk Marque was found to have abused the thing. By the time the Competition Commission came to that finding, it had already lost its power and influence anyway, but I think what came out of it was two things: one, the Competition Commission makes a decision, largely on legal grounds as far as I understand it, and it never returns and looks at the effect of its decision; there does not seem to be any mechanism, from our discussions with them, by which five years on they can look at their decisions and see what has happened commercially, however justified legally. The second point is I think they have certainly put the wind up the directors of the co-ops—and I am not one—and certainly, rightly or wrongly, it stopped them co-operating together.

  Q33 Mr Jack: I come back to the question I actually asked, which was that I do not recall having read anything that said "Thou shalt not vertically integrate" in terms of looking for this value chain. We will be taking evidence later on from Milk Link, who have to a degree climbed out of the bargain basement producer and are stretching up to do some production, but what I do not see is a lot of evidence from the producer side of moving rapidly beyond the basic commodity-type market into value added. Is it feasible to do that?

  Mr Brigstocke: I am going to ask Mr Clarke, as a director of Dairy Farmers of Britain, to answer that.

  Mr Clarke: Firstly, I am here as a producer, not as a director of Dairy Farmers of Britain, but with the benefit of some of that experience, you are right that the implication of the report was not to stop vertical integration. The point I was making earlier was that, in the interpretation of the legislation, which sets percentages for market share, in the interpretation of what constitutes the market when you are measuring market share, that is where we need to have a clearer understanding. If you take a very narrow understanding of what market share is, that precludes a lot of the collaborative work that many producers want to see happen. If there is a will to have the widest possible understanding of what is market share, then the market structure in the country would develop in terms of getting producer organisations and selling organisations down, from many teams of different organisations not only to single figures but down to two or three, to be more effective in terms of their equal status relationship with the rest of the chain.

  Q34 Mr Jack: We got into this inquiry because there was a perception that farmers were not getting a fair deal out of the existing supply chain, and you can either fix that by getting more of somebody else's share, or by being much more price setters for products than price takers. That is why I am exploring what can be done, and I have to say I have not had a clear indication, structurally speaking, as to why, from the producer point of view, we can go further up the chain. It may well be that there are capital constraints, but we will come back to that. Let us talk about the question of profit. Dairy farmers are very open people. The cost of producing milk is a never-ending topic of conversation, but the margin, for example, that other people make, either on the producer side or on the retailer side, seems to be a hidden secret. We did actually get some evidence from Robert Wiseman, who claim that their take is relatively moderate; they are talking about a net margin of 2.2 pence per litre; Arla Foods quoted us a figure of 1.2 pence per litre. Are those fair returns for those people, or are they being greedy at the expense of the primary producer?

  Mr Clarke: I do not think it is a case of being greedy. I think people need to have a fair share. I am not here to represent the two companies you mention, but that would not be excessive, and it would certainly be our view that producers, being at the bottom of the chain, take basically what is left. If processors are in such a position that they are only able to take that sort of margin from the retailer, it obviously indicates where the remainder of the margin already is.

  Q35 Mr Jack: Let us explore in a little more detail. When I go into a supermarket and pick up a carton of milk, I am sometimes quite shocked at how low the price is. I can buy four pints in my local newsagent for 89 pence. How much profit is my newsagent making out of that, and how much eventually comes back to you?

  Mr Clarke: I do not know what the newsagent is making out of it. What comes back to me, as a producer, not quite on the Fylde where many of your constituents are but close to it, is as follows. We currently operate on a margin, before management time, of 0.1 of a penny. That is what is left after my milk price. That has not paid for my management time, and it has not paid for my partner's labour in the business. In terms of what is coming back to the farm gate price, with me currently receiving 18.89 pence, it is not sufficient for my business to make confident investments for the future.

  Q36 Mr Jack: A moment ago when I quoted the figures for Arla and Robert Wiseman you did not balk at it; you did not say "My God, that is outrageous!" You said that was supposedly fair.

  Mr Clarke: If I could have a margin of a penny, or a penny and a half, on top of my own management income, I would say that was a fair margin as well.

  Q37 Mr Jack: That is another 0.9 pence a litre, if I have followed your mathematics.

  Mr Clarke: I said the figure we are at at the moment was before I paid for myself. I require another 1.5 pence to pay for my management time, so we are looking at 3.5 pence.

  Q38 Mr Jack: Where should that 1.5 pence come from?

  Mr Clarke: That margin, I believe, can be gained by the processor and the producer working together in some sort of relationship to come from the retail sector. There are certain cases where some differentiation, some better marketing, can grow the various sectors of the dairy industry, and everybody in the chain can have a fairer share. But in certain very competitive areas—and I am sure Robert Wiseman will give evidence of the fact that he sees liquid milk as a commodity area, as he has said it before in public—there should be more margin coming out of the supermarkets.

  Q39 Mr Jack: What dialogue do you as an organisation have with retailers and processors? Do they have open discussions with you about what they are making out of your products? You have been very open with us in telling us the numbers that make sense to your enterprise. What dialogue do you have with processors and retailers?

  Mr Sumner: Chairman, I am not going to answer your question directly but I would like to make a comment. You were talking about price takers. Dairy farmers are price takers. You made the point very clearly, and Robert Clarke has given his example as a dairy farmer. The price of milk is set by those that put milk on the shelves, and that seems to bear no relationship at all to the costs that might be incurred in the chain. There are, of course, three layers in the chain that you have described: the producers, the processors and the retailers. The farmer at the end of the day has to take the price. We do talk to retailers, but we do not have any power because as an organisation we do not sell any milk; we just represent the interests of dairy farmers. We do talk to processors and to retailers, and we try to explain to them the mechanics of the dairy business, but at the end of the day, the five big supermarkets drive the price of milk, and they impose on the industry, if you like—and they will obviously have very strong reasons for doing so—the price at which they will sell milk. You have described the price of 89 pence in your local newsagents. Dairy farmers have no contribution to that price at all, and maybe that is part of the reason why we are all here.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 8 June 2004