Memorandum submitted by Consumers International
AGRICULTURE AND EU ENLARGEMENT
PREAMBLE
1. Consumers International is pleased to
give evidence to the enquiry. It is based on research carried
out by ourselves and our members, especially the Association of
Polish Consumers, plus work commissioned by us, CI, and European
Research into Consumer Affairs (ERICA) from Professors John Marsh
(Emeritus Professor, University of Reading) and Secondo Tarditi
(Director, Interdepartmental Centre on Agri-food Environmental
Policy, University of Siena). Their research was published by
CI in 2003, Cultivating a Crisis: the global impact of the
Common Agricultural Policy.
2. Consumers International (CI) is a global
federation of consumer organisations dedicated to the protection
and promotion of consumers' interests worldwide through institution
building, education, research and lobbying. Our UK members, with
whom we work closely on trade issues, are Consumers Association
and the National Consumer Council. We also work closely on CAP
matters with our Brussels-based colleagues, the Bureau Européen
des Unions de Consommateurs. We have members in all the accession
countries where we have been very active during the accession
period, on food, agriculture, trade and other matters. The work
which forms the basis of this particular paper was carried out
in the programme Consumers in the Global Market with the
support of the European Commission.
3. We should make clear that we have not
been active on this issue in Cyprus and Malta. Our inability to
comment on the implications for them signifies no disrespect,
but simply lack of analysis in those countries.
INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY
IMPACT ON
CONSUMERS
4. Consumer organisations including Consumers
International (CI) and the Bureau Européen des Unions
de Consommateurs (BEUC), have long argued that the CAP is
disadvantageous to EU consumers, because of the prices set above
market levels. The impact on EU consumers is regressive because
food figures heavily in the budgets of poorer families. In the
EU countries with the lowest per capita incomes, Portugal and
Greece, more than a quarter of family expenditure goes on food.
The overall range, according to the EC (2000) is from about 13%
to about 35%, with an EU average of 17%[11]Central
Europeans in the eight accession countries spend between 21% (Slovenia)
and 39% (Lithuania) of their household expenditure on food. Any
boosting of food prices will inevitably penalise poorer households
disproportionately. Marsh & Tarditi calculate that in the
CEEC8, consumers will spend 12% more on food, equivalent on average
to 127 Euro per annum for a four person family[12].
Our advice to our Central European colleagues has therefore been
most definitely to argue against copying the CAP[13].
5. If the price of farm gate produce were
the only concern, our worries would be fewer, since the farm gate
prices only account for a minority of the final costs paid by
consumers (as little as 12% is calculated by Marsh & Tarditi
for the UK, probably an extreme example). But there are other
more subtle effects of the CAP which have longer-term consequences
for consumers, and are of particular concern to our colleagues
in the Eastern European countries not admitted to the EU and also
to developing countries. These relate in particular to the use
of export subsidies which in theory `compensate' EU exporters
for the fact that their products cost more than world prices due
to the arrangements made on their behalf to provide guaranteed
prices. Without these subsidies, the surplus would be unsellable
on world markets. It is the consumer in Europe that foots the
bill, both in the shopping basket through the high internal price
and as taxpayers to pay for the export subsidy. Yet, the effect
on food producers outside the EU is also considerable as the dumping
of subsidised exports from the EU reduces prices on their markets
to derisory levels; sometimes even negative prices have been offered
to importers by EU exporters.
CAP REFORM
6. Despite limited reforms during the 1990s,
the cost of the CAP has continued to rise. This increase came
in the form of direct income aids to farmers rather than price
support, including compensatory payments for price cuts that were
instigated after 1992 in some sectors (the MacSharry reforms).
In 1999, a further package of "reforms" was agreed in
the "Agenda 2000" programme, with further price cuts
and compensation. The EC did not (and does not) want to extend
Eastwards the payments that are being given to EU farmers to compensate
them for the price cuts. As the CEEC farmers are not having to
apply cuts in EU prices (because they are not members of the EU
yet), it is logical to exclude them from eligibility, especially
as the prices they receive will rise after accession. However,
the merits of this impeccable logic are lost on farmers in the
accession countries. This was a major issue not only in Poland,
the most vocal of the negotiators, but also in the Hungarian election
of 2002. Victor Orban, the then Prime Minister, warned of a two-tier
membership, with the CEEC farmers operating at a disadvantage
compared with the heavily subsidised farmers of the EU Fifteen[14].
President Palisas of Lithuania came to office in January 2003
with a pledge to renegotiate the terms of Lithuania's accession[15].
This proved to be impossible given that terms were agreed in the
preceding December, but it signifies the potential for the trouble
over this issue. This is especially clear when the EC argues that
too high a level of direct aid to CEEC farmers will discourage
restructuring. As Julie Wolf points out: "While this may
be true, the candidate countries are justified in wondering why
direct payments are good for EU farmers but bad for those in Central
and Eastern Europe[16]."
7. A programme for reform was put forward
by the EU's Consumer Committee with the active participation of
many members of the Bureau Européen des Unions de Consommateurs
(BEUC) between 1998 and 2000[17].
Such a policy could have helped CEEC economies to develop and
accession to take place without excessive disruption. EU price
cuts would bring prices closer to CEEC levels. EU production subsidy
cuts would reduce surpluses and restrict dumping in third countries.
Diminishing EU border protection would provide markets for CEEC
producers. Compensation at national level would enable EU Member
States to help their own farmers at a level commensurate with
income levels in the respective Member States. CEEC countries
would be free to do the same in theory, though they would not
have to compensate farmers for price cuts if prices are not raised
in the first place. And that is why such a programme would be
in the interest of CEEC consumers too. Simply importing the CAP
to Central Europe will see price rises, ultimately penalising
poorer families.
ACCESSION
8. This is what we feared would happen when
agriculture took centre stage in the December 2002 Copenhagen
summit at which the terms of accession for the 10 new entrants
were announced. All efforts were concentrated on the subsidy share
out. The outcome was that the EU's basic negotiating position
was adopted. Accession countries will receive 25% of direct payments
going to EU farmers in 2004, 30% in 2005, 35% in 2006 and a gradual
increase to 100% in 2013[18].
Any extra amounts to be paid in 2004 to 2006 will have to come
from national finances. On the face of it this deal seems unfair
to the CEECs. But the injustices are not evident simply along
East versus West fault lines, as was presented to the CEECs' publics.
They are also consumer versus producer. As ever in the CAP, things
are not quite what they seem. We need to take a step back, to
set the historical context in the region.
9. Farm subsidies can be broadly divided
between those that are intended to benefit consumers (usually
through keeping prices down) and those that are intended to benefit
farmers (through guaranteeing prices or through direct income
aids). The traditional point of contrast between East and West
was that the EU kept food prices up and the socialist countries
kept food prices down. In fact, traditionally, the socialist countries
subsidised both producers and consumers, a policy which proved
to be unsustainable. For the accession countries, then, moving
to an unchanged CAP in the EU means a huge shift in agricultural
policy.
10. Following the seismic changes of 1989
to 1991, the effect of EU policies on agriculture throughout the
CEEC region was profound because of subsidised exports. In 1990,
exports from Poland, Hungary, Czechoslovakia, Romania and Bulgaria
gave these countries, taken together, a positive trade balance
of 960 million ECU with the EU. By 1993 this had shifted to a
negative balance of 424 million ECU, with only Hungary retaining
a positive balance of trade in agriculture[19].
This was still the case eight years later in 2001[20].
THE EXAMPLE
OF POLAND
11. At the same time as the EU subsidies
reached a plateau around 1986-88, the economies to the East were
collapsing. Thus Poland, the largest of the candidate countries,
witnessed a forced change of policy which made it one of the least
subsidised agricultural sectors in the Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development (OECD). In 1988, just before the
transition, Poland's direct and indirect agricultural support
amounted to 24% of total farm revenue compared with 46% in the
EU. That is, its farmers were subsidised, but only half as much
as those in the EU as a proportion of output. By 1993, while the
EU's level had risen to 48%, that of Poland had dropped to 16%.
Even more dramatically, consumer support in Poland was 52.9% in
1989 (ie the subsidy in relation to expenditure), but by 1991,
only two years later, it had dropped to 0.2%[21].
In other words, price subsidies to consumers had virtually disappeared
in only two years from a level at which half of food prices had
been discounted by subsidy.
12. There is an argument that EU export
subsidies provide cheap imports to Central Europe and therefore
could benefit consumers there in such circumstances. This did
not happen in Poland. The flood of cheap imports did not translate
into low prices to consumers, rather it appears that some traders
bought cheap and sold dear. In this they were aided and abetted
by the policy of the Polish government which witnessed a shift
to price support rather than direct payment to farmers. Hence,
by the end of the 1990s, 76% of farm support was borne directly
by consumers through such mechanisms as intervention buying[22].
These mechanisms were also applied to sectors which were relatively
unsubsidised in the EU, such as pork, for which the intervention
price was some 50% higher than the market (or border) price[23].
13. The Polish Central Statistical Office,
using 1990 as the baseline date with an index of 100, calculates
that food prices were 439.6 by 1995 and 635.4 by 1999. Yet, by
the end of the 1990s, food prices were scarcely rising at all,
indeed they declined in some years. Thus, in recent years, both
food prices and agricultural incomes have been extremely volatile,
prices fluctuating between hyperinflation and stagnation, and
agricultural earnings going from growth to collapse to stagnation,
with continued decline in the late 1990s (30% decline of farm
income over the four years 1996-99)[24].
14. Of course, as Polish agriculture lost
its subsidies and Polish consumers suddenly had to pay higher
prices, it was very easy for the subsidised EU exporters to enter
the Polish market and undermine Polish agriculture still further.
Faced with this intense competition from EU agriculture, Poland
failed to take up its full quota of agricultural export opportunities
to the EU, as allowed for in the Europe Agreements which followed
on from the transition. It never exceeded 80% of its permitted
quotas despite the fears expressed by Western European farmers
that they faced competition from the CEECs because of their lower
labour costs[25].
15. Faced with this volatility, it is not
surprising that the Polish public saw the EU as a beacon of hope.
Tarditi has calculated what would happen if, as of 2001, the CAP
were extended directly to the 2004 entrants, for just 11 principal
commodities. He concluded that direct payments to farmers would
rise from 10% to 36% of current farm receipts and market price
support from 14% to 35%[26].
16. However, as in the EU, subsidising producers
does not mean that consumers pay less, as common sense might suggest.
Polish farm gate prices for the 11 products would rise by some
11%. Tarditi further calculates that the CEEC Eight would see
a 12% rise in prices on average, deviating from 28% in Estonia
to 1% in Slovenia (confirming reports by our Slovene colleagues
that prices there tend already to be at EU levels)[27].
It is important to note that increases in farm gate prices do
not necessarily translate into commensurate increases in retail
food prices. But they certainly lead to increased price pressure
on an already hard-pressed population, while some pro-EU campaigners
are unwisely suggesting that prices will fall. Tarditi and Marsh
conclude that: "The implication of applying the CAP is
a substantial transfer of real income from consumers and taxpayers
to producers." Furthermore, they point out that: "As
farmers receipts increase and they seek to expand, much of the
added revenue is absorbed in higher input prices, particularly
for land. Thus the remaining benefit to farmers' incomes is substantially
less than the amount paid by consumers and taxpayers. . . . it
is clear that the beneficiary is not actually the hired farm worker
but the owner of the farm business . . . on large scale enterprises
there is no guarantee that the benefits of farm support will be
passed on to the worker[28]."
17. It would be some consolation to consumers
if they could see their higher prices going to a useful social
goal. Yet, this would appear not to be the case, or at least only
to a limited extent, as has also happened inside the EU.
A PARADOX
18. So there is a paradox in that the erstwhile
command economies of the Central and Eastern European Countries
(CEECs) are meant to be moving towards a market economy through
EU accession, while the CAP, with its quota systems and price
guarantees, represents a Western version of precisely the kind
of command economy, highly bureaucratic and centralised, from
which the CEECs are supposed to be escaping. A further paradox
is that the kind of policy which EU consumer bodies have advocated
is not unlike that which Poland and Hungary adopted during the
course of the 1990s, only to abandon during the process of EU
accession. For example, within the CEECs, there was only modest
reliance on price setting, usually at prices below world markets,
unlike the CAP.
19. Hungary was particularly active in defending
this policy. It was the only European member of the "Cairns
group" of agricultural exporters during the Uruguay Round
of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade Agreement (GATT)
negotiations, and the CEECs comfortably met the terms of the WTO
Agreement on Agriculture because they had cut their subsidies
so severely. Hungary has since left the Cairns group, doubtless
in view of EU accession. So, perversely, our praise for the Hungarian
position during the 1990s, was not welcome to the Hungarian government.
20. The advice of consumer organisations
has been overridden, with consequences that stretch beyond the
borders of the CEEC accession countries. After accession, the
new members will be able to apply export subsidies. The WTO 2000
Trade Policy Review on Poland concludes the following:"Although
Poland will not have to contend with subsidised EU exports following
accession, its agricultural sector will be subject to greater
competition from EU producers. . . On the other hand, following
EU accession, Poland's agricultural production may be eligible
for increased EU export subsidies. This could transfer the burden
onto third country markets and world exporters through the depressing
effects of such policies on world commodity prices[29]."
21. In other words, any increase in export
subsidies will probably be at the expense of other non-EU CEEC
countries, such as Ukraine and neighbouring accession candidates,
such as Romania and Bulgaria. Thus, Moldova, Europe's poorest
country, finds that not only is its internal market undermined
by subsidised exports from the EU, but it cannot export to the
EU and finds its traditional Russian market undermined by cheaper
EU exports. We will be working with our Russian colleagues on
these matters during the coming years.
22. So now that the CEEC8 are about to join
the EU, they become absorbed into a system which underwrites over
production. So from being part of the solution as we had hoped,
(because they had hit upon better policies than the CAP during
the 1990s) they are becoming part of the problem from the point
of view of other Eastern European countries
PUBLIC OPINION
23. Westerners should take note that the
challenges facing the CEEC region are unprecedented, and that
EU experience, while useful as a "pointer", may have
limited applicability. The region is having fundamentally to restructure
its system of governance for the third time in less than a century.
Louis Emmerij from the Inter American Development Bank points
out: "What is unprecedented is that (trade) liberalisation
took place in economies with rapidly shrinking GDP and domestic
demand accompanied by the loss of their Eastern markets. . . The
argument (used by the EU during recession) that the 1 or 2% economic
decline justifies protectionism can hardly be sold in Central
and Eastern Europe[30]."
24. Yet, despite this, the Western negotiators
have appeared apprehensive at the prospect of greater integration,
indeed more so than the general public, since opinion in the EU
is in favour of accession, according to a Eurobarometer survey
(October 2002)[31].
In the EU Fifteen, 51% supported accession and 30% were against.
These majorities could be fragile and vulnerable to change in
economic or political circumstances. But the fears of EU citizens
would be misdirected if they singled out the accession process
as a threat. The weight of the GDPs of the 10 new members is a
mere 6% of the EU's GDP, and the EU had a 17 billion Euro trade
surplus in 2000. Moreover, the budgetary cost of enlargement is
a mere one thousandth of EU GDP[32].
What kind of threat is this?
THE LAST
WORD
25. The haggling over subsidy has brought
out the worst in Europeans on all sides. The Southern Europeans
worry that they will lose regional aid to the poorer newcomers,
the Irish and the French worry about low-cost competition, the
Germans worry about the cost, and the British hang on to their
rebate. Laszlo Csaba of the Central European University calls
for a more broad-minded approach: He dates what he calls an "obsession
with transfers" to Mrs Thatcher's strident (and successful)
demands for a "British rebate" on its contributions
during the 1980s, justified on the grounds that the UK gained
little from the CAP. He points out that: "Being a net
contributor surely has not hurt German interests, and conversely,
being a net recipient has not been of much help to Greece in its
first decade of EU membership[33]."
26. In their eagerness to demonstrate their
negotiating prowess to their electorates, political leaders in
the accession countries are rushing to reproduce in the CEECs
the errors of the CAP against which we have long campaigned. An
opportunity has been lost for us to learn from our Central European
neighbours.
Consumers International
January 2004
11 Secondo Tarditi and John Marsh, Cultivating a
Crisis, Consumers International 2003. Back
12
Secondo Tarditi and John Marsh, Cultivating a Crisis, Consumers
International 2003. Back
13
Robin Simpson, Bureau European des Unions de Consommateurs,
The CAP and the Accession of the CEECs, Seminar of the National
Association for Consumer Protection, Budapest 1997. Back
14
Financial Times, 31 January 2002. Back
15
European Voice, 6-12 February 2003. Back
16
Julie Wolf, The future of European Agriculture, Centre
for European Reform 2002. Back
17
European Commission, Report of the CC on reform of the CAP, adopted
8 December 1998. Back
18
Heather Grabbe, The Copenhagen Deal for Enlargement, Centre
for European Reform briefing note 2002. Back
19
The Agricultural Situation and Prospects in the CEECs,
EC DG6 (Agriculture) 1995. Back
20
Business Central Europe, July/August 2001. Back
21
The Agricultural Situation and Prospects in Poland, EC DG6 1995. Back
22
World Trade Organisation, Trade Policy Review, Poland,
2000, Chart iv.2. Back
23
Polityka, 2389/08/2003. Back
24
Association of Polish Consumers, The impact of trade liberalisation
on Polish consumers, 2002. Back
25
National Consumers Council, Agricultural Policy in the EU,
1995. Back
26
Secondo Tarditi, Impact of the CAP on CEECs, Presentation
to the Royal Institute of International Affairs, Chatham House,
December 2002. Back
27
Ibid. Back
28
Secondo Tarditi and John Marsh, Cultivating a Crisis, Consumers
International 2003. Back
29
World Trade Organisation, Trade Policy Review, Poland,
2000. Back
30
L. Emmerij, Eastern Europe in a Development Perspective
in The aftermath of real existing socialism in Eastern Europe,
eds J. Hersh and J. Schmidt, Volume I, Macmillan 1996. Back
31
European Commission, Eurobarometer, October 2002. Back
32
http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/arguments/index.htm Back
33
Laszlo Csaba, Inter-economics, Review of European Economic
Policy, Volume 36 No.5, September/October 2001 Double talk,
the political economy of Eastbound enlargement of the EU,
Hamburg Institute of International Economies. Back
|