Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Professor Sir John Marsh (O4)

  1.  The sugar regime is designed to prevent competition relocating production within the European Union, in contradiction to one of the fundamental objectives of establishing a Common Market. By restricting supplies through quotas, import restrictions and exports it has ensured internal sugar prices that keep in production many producers, processors and possibly some refiners who would otherwise have disappeared. The costs of this policy have been borne by EU consumers and by third country exporters. The budgetary costs have been modest. Reform of the policy has been made difficult because of a Sugar Protocol agreed with some ACP countries, which allows them to export a fixed amount of sugar, 1.8 million tonnes to the Community paid for at the protected EU price.

2.  THE POLICY BACKGROUND

    (a)

    Sugar is produced as cane in the tropics, and as beet in temperate regions. In both cases the raw material has to be processed to extract sugar and then refined to produce a product for consumption. The processing and especially the refining activities involve large plants and considerable capital investments. In comparison with both producers and consumers, these relatively few businesses occupy a potentially monopolistic position.

    (b)

    Sugar faces competition from alternative sweeteners. Some of these have advantages for food processors. Others may provide sweetness without calories. In an age beset with problems of obesity, these offer an advantage as part of a calorie controlled diet. For poorer countries, however, demand for sugar rises rapidly with higher disposable income. It provides a valued source of energy as well as adding flavour and helping to preserve food.

    (c)

    Most sugar is produced in the countries in which it is consumed. Growers are protected from external competition by a variety of trade barriers. This means that the world market in sugar has the characteristics of a residual market. Although demand for sugar on a world scale is growing, in the short-term it is price inelastic. As a result small changes in the overall quantity placed on the market can have disproportionate effects. This has resulted in a very volatile world market upon which surpluses are dumped and from which domestic shortages are relieved.


    (d)

    The diagram shows world price movements in US cents per pound and individual countries in their local currencies. It indicates how much larger have been fluctuations in the world market than in the EU. Individual country prices reflect changes in exchange rates, thus the major fall in sugar prices in the UK from 1996 to 2000 is primarily the result of the appreciation of the pound sterling against the euro. Similarly the higher prices shown for Brazil and Barbados indicate their currencies weakness.

    (e)

    Supply is affected by season and weather so that although the area planted may be relatively static, the quantity reaching the market can vary substantially. Production in the EU despite its quota regime has varied since 1991 from 15.4 million tonnes (1995) to 17.7 million tonnes (1998).

Table 1

THE WORLD TOP 10 SUGAR PRODUCERS


Production 2001 Million Tonnes Share of World

Market %
Change

1991-2001 %
Brazil20.115 121
India20.015 54
European Union183.0 130
China8.66 2
United States of America7.4 610
Thailand6.04 42
Mexico5.14 50
Australia4.63 33
Cuba3.83 -50
Pakistan2.72 20
World134.0100 19




  Source: Sugar International Analysis—EU Commission September 2003

    (f)

    The EU is a major player in the world sugar market. During the 1990s production in both India and Brazil overtook that of the Community but EU policy remains a major issue in world trade debates. Tropical sugar exports find their markets limited by the policies of both the United States and the European Union. This affects not only the major suppliers but also a number of smaller countries, particularly in the Caribbean for whom sugar exports play a key role in their overall economies. For these countries there is seldom an easy alternative to sugar and so their economic fortunes are significantly affected by developed country sugar policies. For some of these countries, former dependencies of EU member countries, the Sugar Protocol provides a secure outlet for a limited quantity of sugar at the prices available to producers within the Union.

    (g)

    Sugar beet growing is an activity of larger farms within the EU. For most countries less than 10% of the farms are involved in sugar production, the exceptions being Belgium with 23% and the Netherlands, 17%. Table 2 shows that in most countries these farms are double the average size. On these farms the proportion of the cultivated area used for sugar exceeds 15% only in Finland.


    (h)

    The amount of sugar produced within the EU substantially exceeds the amount consumed. The UK is the only substantial net importer.


3.  THE UK SITUATION

    (a)

    Much of the sugar that is imported into the UK is produced from cane in the ACP countries and all of this is refined at the Thames (Silvertown) refinery owned by Tate and Lyle. It processes over one million tonnes per annum and is the largest cane sugar refiner in the world. Home produced beet sugar is processed and marketed by British Sugar plc who hold the entire UK sugar quota and command about 60% of the market.

    (b)

    The existing CAP sugar regime works to the disadvantage of the UK economy. It means that imported sugar, whether from EU or third country, costs consumers more. It also leads to a distortion in the use of resources within the UK as production is increased to a level greater than would be viable in a competitive market. The impact is to reduce UK GDP, although in the overall scale of the economy, this effect is so small as to be unlikely to attract notice.

    (c)

    The regime does benefit sugar growers, the beet sugar industry and, because the Sugar Protocol enables cane sugar still to be imported, Tate and Lyle and their parent company, Associated British Foods. EU analysis suggests that during the campaign, (the period during which beet sugar is processed) some 2,211 staff were employed in the UK. Defra indicate that their are some 7,200 sugar growers in the UK. A major reform of the CAP would put at risk many of these jobs and much of the capital invested in processing domestic sugar production.

4.  THE COMMISSION'S PROPOSALS

    (a)

    The Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament makes a powerful case for reform. It stresses three main issues:

      (i)

There is a need to bring the sugar regime into line with the policies for other commodities under the reformed CAP. Essentially support is no longer to be provided for production but for the producer and made subject to the requirements of cross compliance.

      (ii)

The EU has made commitments to allow imports from the Least Developed Countries, under the Everything But Arms initiative and to the Balkan countries. This raises the risk that there will be a serious increase in the oversupply of the EU sugar market by 2007. Such an oversupply would disrupt the market in many parts of the Union.

      (iii)

The Doha Development Round is likely to challenge the existing sugar regime. Progress in the WTO will inevitably require changes in the EU export regime, essentially a reduction or removal of export subsidies and greater market access for third country exporters.

    (b)

    To these reasons might be added a number of others that remain valid although they are not stated by the Commission.

      (i)

The income transfers achieved have no justification on social grounds. They raise the price of food, which figures heavily in the expenditure of poor people and confer income benefits to farmers who are in comparison relatively rich in terms of both income and wealth.

      (ii)

The level of production that results has no justification in terms of food security or comparative advantage. The EU constantly produces more sugar than it uses and can only dispose of this with what amount to subsidies on exports. The fact that exports are supported by a complex system of A, B and C sugar, cannot disguise the reality that although the budget may not finance exports, they are being funded by a policy that forces up consumer prices within the EU to levels not needed to supply demand.

      (iii)

The policy has damaging consequences for the third world. The subsidised export of approaching 6 million tonnes of sugar is not offset by imports of 1.8 million tonnes under the Sugar Protocol. Inevitably it depresses the world price and the fortunes of third country exporters. The fact that Brazil now sells more sugar on the world market than the EU cannot disguise the reality that the EU sugar regime plays a major role in depressing world prices.

      (iv)

The Sugar Protocol that is currently attached to the Cotonou Agreement maintains preferential access for ACP sugar. In the short run this benefits these countries but its longer run and global results are less reassuring. The gains can only be realised by the countries concerned if they continue to produce sugar. In terms of comparative advantage some of these exporters would not be competitive at world prices. Essentially the Protocol traps resources that should move to more productive and competitive uses. If the Community wishes to support these ACP countries a transfer of funds equivalent to the difference between a competitive world equilibrium price and the current EU price would offer a more flexible and effective way of helping them to develop.

      (v)

Countries that that do have a comparative advantage but are not included in the Protocol suffer as a result of the unloading of the sugar the EU imports as a result of lower world prices.

5.  THE OPTIONS FOR REFORM

    (a)

    The Commission does not make a specific proposal for reform; instead it invites consultation on three options.

      (i)

The status quo, in effect, continuing the existing regime and making adjustments to accommodate more imports. This would imply lower prices and production quotas.

      (ii)

Lowering EU prices and phasing out production quotas. The price mechanism acts as the instrument of adjustment of production levels, discouraging not only domestic production but also imports. This policy could allow for compensation to producers via the Single Farm Payment system agreed in the June 2003 reforms.

      (iii)

Liberalisation, the removal of price support mechanisms the end of quota restrictions on farmers and the elimination of barriers to imports. Again this could be combined with compensation to existing EU producers via the Single Farm Payment.

    (b)

    The first of these options is inconsistent with the Commission's own analysis of the need for reform. It does not bring coherence with the rest of the reformed CAP, it does not remove the problem of matching EU sugar policy to commitments made to other countries and it is unlikely to meet the demands for access by third countries that are expected to figure in any Doha Round settlement.

    (c)

    Options two and three represent a gradualist as opposed to a "cold bath" approach. Rationally they both ultimately lead to production levels determined by a market to which other countries would have access. Intellectually the "cold bath" approach has much to commend it. From the outset producers, processors and refiners know they have to adjust. Rather than mount a protracted political campaign to safeguard the existing use of their resources, they would have to evaluate them against the reality of what, in the future, they could earn in sugar production or other activities. This is essentially what other sectors have had to do and there is no economic benefit from delaying adjustment.

    (d)

    Politically the gradualist approach may be preferred. Market driven adjustments leave casualties. The process of moving to an efficient system is unlikely to be achieved in "one hop". As a result there may well be greater initial volatility and alarms could be raised about the security of supplies. The danger of a gradual approach is that markets may never be given a chance. Well-organised political lobbies will point to any disruption as evidence that liberalisation is a mistaken direction and seek to restore their comfortable world in the name of "what the consumer wants". It will take continued firmness of purpose by the Council of Ministers to deliver the ultimate goal of an efficient and non-distorted sugar market.

    (e)

    For both options reform will not be attainable without some measures to compensate farmers and to respond to the problems that will result for ACP countries. The Commission paper suggests that the Single Farm Payment should be the chosen instrument so far as EU sugar producers are concerned. This is a good starting point but it should be made clear at the outset that this is a compensation payment awarded to help farmers adjust, not to keep them in the lifestyle they have enjoyed for an indefinite or infinite period. Two steps would ensure this. First that the period is time limited so that recipients know they will have to adjust if they are to sustain their incomes levels in the future. Second that the right to payment should be attached to the producer, not to the land, and should be a saleable right, enabling the producer to realign his resources quickly and move on to new activities, having recovered much of the capital he has invested in sugar production. The suggestion that this would lead to land abandonment has no weight in the case of sugar production. This takes place on some of the best land within the EU and would rapidly be utilised for other agricultural activities.

    (f)

    An essentially similar approach should be applied to assist ACP countries cope with having to compete in an open world market. A basis for compensation exists in terms of the difference in value between the world price and the internal EU price these countries have received over a past time period. This not only provides a defined sum but also produces a distribution corresponding to the loss of benefit from losing protection. Again the compensation payment should be time limited, allowing the country concerned to use it in their own restructuring programme. Funding for this purpose would more appropriately come from the development budget rather than the CAP. It might reasonably be expected that other international agencies would join in support of adjustment programmes that enabled the countries concerned to move to a more secure, long-term future rather than be tied to continued dependence upon an EU commodity regime that has lost it legitimacy.

    (g)

    Both the second and third options imply opening EU markets to imports. It is important that the process of reform within the Community should promote progress within the framework of the World Trade Organisation. The opening up of markets, the removal of distorting policies in developed countries must be accompanied by an acceptance of international trade disciplines by all countries, including those of the developing world. Reform of the sugar regime makes sense in terms of the self-interest of the Community, even if others do not change. However, as countries such as China, India and Brazil grow in economic weight and potential, they too, must share in the responsibility of maintaining a trade system that creates wealth for the world as a whole. The EU needs to negotiate from a position of strength not one of guilt and reform of the sugar regime can contribute significantly to this.

    (h)

    The UK national interest favours a move to a liberalised market in the shortest feasible time and with compensation to farmers that is phased out once they have an opportunity to adjust. In terms of the three options offered, the third is most attractive. It would remove the added cost of the sugar regime to consumers, it would remove the loss of real income associated with paying more for imports than is necessary to ensure a secure supply and it would liberate resources within the UK to be used for more productive purposes. The key element is that payments of compensation should be linked to restructuring and not tied into a continuing commitment to farmers or captured to fund environmental or rural development policies. Such policies should be supported on their own merits, not on the grounds that, once upon a time, someone grew sugar beet on a particular farm.

    (i)

    The UK has an interest and an important responsibility towards many of the ACP countries. The suggestion outlined in paragraph 5f above would discharge this much more effectively than the continued survival of the sugar protocol. It would also provide an opportunity for development assistance to be directed towards developing new industries and markets higher-value-added products within the countries concerned and as exports.

17 March 2004[1]


1   COM (2003) 554 Final Brussels, 23.9.2003. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 12 July 2004