Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Global Alliance for Sugar Trade Reform and Liberalisation (Brisbane, Australia) (O32)

SUMMARY

  1.  The EU sugar regime is import averse, discriminates between developing countries, prevents competition between domestic suppliers, penalises its own industrial sugar users, has escaped all domestic reforms, and damages the incomes of other sugar producing countries.

  2.  The Global Sugar Alliance seeks an integrated approach to the reform of policies affecting sugar trade—market access, domestic support and export subsidies.

  2.1  Substantial and meaningful increases in market access.

  2.2  The elimination of the special agricultural safeguard for sugar.

  2.3  Substantial reductions in the sugar tariff.

  2.4  The elimination of all forms of trade-distorting domestic support.

  2.5  The elimination of export subsidies.

  3.  The Global Sugar Alliance believes it is important that the special and differential needs of all developing and least developed countries are taken into account as a new EU sugar regime is developed.

THE EU SUGAR REGIME IS IMPORT AVERSE

  4.  Imports are tightly controlled by prohibitive tariffs:

  4.1  Quota access is less than 2 million tonnes.

  4.1.1  EU sugar imports account for around 4% of developing country sugar exports.

  4.1.2  Developing countries accounted for 65% of global sugar exports in 2001[15]

  4.1.3  In the Uruguay Round the EU refused to provide WTO tariff quota bindings to ACP sugar exporters at the levels they were actually exporting in 1995.

  4.2  Imports are subject to special safeguards and the effective tariff level is 339% for raw sugar and 419% for white sugar[16]

  4.3  Following domestic lobbying, sugar imports from least developed countries under the "Everything But Arms" (EBA) initiative will not be liberalised until at least 2009 and may be subject to special safeguards.

  4.4  The EU is possibly the only WTO Member which reserves to itself the right to subsidise the export of the equivalent quantities of sugar that it imports[17]

THE EU SUGAR REGIME DISCRIMINATES BETWEEN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

  5.  ACP sugar quota holders are allocated a total quantity of 1.295 million tonnes and India 10kt under a WTO duty free tariff quota.

  6.  The EC allocates quotas to some, but not all, ACP sugar producers.

  6.1  Kenya, a major sugar producer, has only recently been allocated a quota.

  6.2  Other developing countries must compete for a WTO tariff quota of 85kt.

  6.3  Least developed countries are subject to very tight quota controls under EBA arrangements.

  6.3.1  EBA sugar has displaced some ACP imports under EC preferential access arrangements relating to the maximum supply needs of refineries.

THE EU SUGAR REGIME PREVENTS COMPETITION BETWEEN DOMESTIC SUPPLIERS

  7.  Quotas are allocated at Member State level and there is little or no internal trade in sugar.

  7.1  national quotas are predicated on self-sufficiency in each Member State and special subsidies are given to encourage production in marginal sugar producing regions.

  8.  The regime is in direct contradiction to the Community's Single Market and Competition policies.

  8.1  It is a common regime only in the sense that it maintains a single high wall against imports and guarantees common support price and export subsidies.

  9.  To quote from a 1991 Court of Auditors Report:

  9.1  "[It is] a market organisation which has become so self-contained that it has practically closed itself off from any movement in the direction of the main initial objective, ie to create a common market, with all its economic advantages.

  10.  The regime requires that non-quota sugar be exported.

THE EU SUGAR REGIME PENALISES EU INDUSTRIAL SUGAR USERS

  11.  Industrial sugar accounts for over 70% of EU domestic sugar consumption, yet EU food and other sugar-using industries are forced to purchase domestic EU sugar at more than three times the world price.

  11.1  with adverse effects for employment and investment in the processed foods sector[18]

  11.2  access to imported sugar under inward processing arrangements is tightly controlled.

  12.  EU sugar processing is one of the few EU manufacturing operations to receive subsidies[19]—the mechanism is effectively a local content subsidy to manufacturers, of a type which the EU has challenged when maintained by developing countries.

THE EU SUGAR REGIME HAS ESCAPED ALL DOMESTIC AGRICULTURE REFORMS

  13.  Sugar is known as the "white gold" of European agriculture.

  14.  Effective levels of support for sugar are far in excess of support for cereals.

  14.1  EU expenditure on price support for white sugar is nearly

6 billion[20]

  15.  The intervention price is currently more than three times the world price and because of the closed nature of the regime, producers typically command prices some 10-20% above the world price.

  15.1  no-one can explain the basis for establishing the intervention price level and the court of Auditors has been highly critical of EU accounting methods in this regard[21]

  16.  The regime is virtually unchanged since its inception over 30 years ago.

  16.1  it was excised from the most recent review of the Common Agricultural Policy.

  17.  The regime is not self-financing.

  17.1  in terms of direct budgetary outlays—the EU spends

1.6 billion on export subsidies, but recovers only around half that amount from producer levies.

  17.2  the EU has avoided intervention buying-in over the last 15 years through export subsidies on quota sugar and by forcing the disposal of surplus to quota production on world markets.

  17.3.  effectively, the world market is used by the EU to dump its sugar surpluses.

THE EU SUGAR REGIME DAMAGES THE INCOMES OF OTHER SUGAR PRODUCING COUNTRIES

  18.  EU sugar legislation makes the objectives of the sugar regime clear. They are internally focussed, reflecting the objectives detailed in Article 39 of the Treaty of Rome for the Common Agricultural Policy, and include:

  18.1  the promotion of improved incomes;

  18.2  the promotion increased technical and economic efficiency;

  18.3  the stabilisation of markets;

  18.4  guaranteed regular supplies to consumers at reasonable prices.

  19.  The regime's objectives do not purport to be an instrument of development policy.

  19.1  It is predicated on controlling import access through quotas.

  19.2  The EU Commissioner for development—and many others—question whether the sugar access arrangements for a select number of ACP members constitute good development policy[22]

  20.  Developing countries in Africa and Asia account for the bulk of EU sugar exports (around 13% of French exports go to Africa).

  20.1  With benefit of export subsidies, France even exports to Jamaica and other ACP sugar producing countries.

  20.2  The self-sufficiency of developing countries in sugar has declined substantially, from 80.9% in 1992 to 60.18% in 2001[23]

  20.3  The EU provides a guaranteed price to ACP sugar quota holders, with an estimated total value of

450 million, but provides export subsidies of

1.6 billion to its own producers, including around

8-900 million to export the so-called equivalent of its imports from ACP sugar exporters.

  20.4  The EU is a self-acknowledged high cost producer, yet is exporting at record levels (around 6 million tonnes[24]) at a time of record low world sugar prices, in a period when far more efficient producers are having difficulty in covering production costs.

  20.4.1  Over half of EU exports are surplus to quota sugar, which the EU claims is not subsidised, but which are clearly exported at well below production costs.

THE EU SUGAR REGIME AFFECTS ALL SWEETENERS

  21.  Iso-glucose and high fructose corns syrups, alternative sweeteners to sugar, have developed market niches in heavily regulated and high priced sugar markets such as the US and Japan. In the EU the cost of isoglucose production[25] is less than sugar. In Europe the market penetration of these alternative sweeteners is constrained by quota.

  22.  The Commission[26] has concluded, in the absence of quotas on iso-glucose production:

  22.1  if the price of sugar were set at

450/tonne, the drinks sector would be totally absorbed by isoglucose, reducing the sugar market by a third;

  22.2  The price of sugar would have to be reduce to

370/tonne to act as a disincentive to investment in isoglucose production.

REFORM OF THE EU SUGAR REGIME IS A PRIORITY

  23.  The Global Sugar Alliance seeks an integrated approach to the reform of policies affecting sugar trade—market access, domestic support and export subsidies.

  23.1  Substantial and meaningful increases in market access.

  23.2  The elimination of the special agricultural safeguard for sugar.

  23.3  Substantial reductions in the sugar tariff.

  23.4  The elimination of all forms of trade-distorting domestic support.

  23.5  The elimination of export subsidies.

  24.  The Global Sugar Alliance believes it is important that the special and differential needs of all developing and least developed countries are taken into account as a new EU sugar regime is developed.

29 March 2004

350/tonne (

150 for raw material and

200 for processing costs) while the production cost of isoglucose 55, which has the same sweetness as sugar, is approximately

380/tonne (average EU cost). In general, the production cost of isoglucose varies from

330 to 460/tonne depending on the circumstances (cost varies according to the country and the cost of the raw materials used), while the average cost in the acceding States is less than

300/tonne. EC Report (6547/04) from Working Party on Sugar and Isoglucose to: Special Committee on Agriculture, 18 February 2004.


15   FAOSTAT database. Back

16   Source: About ACP sugar, European sugar statistics www.acpsugar.org.stats. Exclusive of the SSG, The WTO bound rate is 228%. Back

17   A footnote to the EU's WTO schedule provides that the EU will not observe its WTO export subsidy reduction commitments in respect of quantities equivalent to those imported from the ACP and India. Back

18   In a letter to the Financial Times of 12 June 2003, the Director-General of the UK Biscuit, Cake, Chocolate and Confectionery Alliance advised that, for the first time in living memory, the UK imported more biscuits and confectionery than it exported, due to high EU sugar prices. Back

19   40% of the intervention price is delivered as a subsidy to sugar processors, on condition that they purchase raw sugar or sugar beet harvested in the EU. That subsidy cannot be characterised as a "measure in favour of agricultural producers" as provide in the WTO Agreement on Agriculture. Back

20   EC Notification to the WTO: G/AG/N/EEC/38, Supporting Table DS:5. Back

21   ECA Special Report 20/2000 (C50 of 15/02/01). Back

22   See ABARE studies. Back

23   Source ISO: Self-sufficiency in sugar-trends and prospects. Back

24   Latest figures are around 4 million tonnes; EU average is 5 million tonnes. The EU exports around three times as much as it imports. Back

25   The production cost of isoglucose 42 is around Back

26   EC Report (6547/04) from Working Party on Sugar and Isoglucose to: Special Committee on Agriculture, 18 February 2004. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 12 July 2004