Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (1-19)

2 DECEMBER 2003  

MR MASOOD AHMED AND MS SHARON WHITE


Witnesses: Mr Masood Ahmed, Director General for Policy and International, and Ms Sharon White, Director, Policy Division, Department for International Development, examined.

  Q1 Chairman: Thank you very much for coming this afternoon. I have just a couple of general points. Firstly, the acoustics in this room are not brilliant, so if you could speak up. I was wondering if, before we start to take evidence, you could just tell us a bit about what is the role of Director General for Policy and International. Presumably that is what I still think of as a Deputy Secretary post, is it?

Mr Ahmed: Yes.

  Q2 Chairman: And also what does the Policy Division do. I am not quite sure that if I was on Who Wants to be a Millionaire and I was asked this question I could give the answer. Perhaps you can tell us a bit about what you do in DFID and we are genuinely interested in what your division does.

Mr Ahmed: Thank you very much. I am happy to tell you a little bit about what it is that this role is about and what I do. To give you a sense of the structure of DFID, there is a Permanent Secretary and then there are three Directors General. One of them deals with our bilateral programmes, so that is all of the bilateral aid. Another one deals with corporate services and knowledge, so essentially finance, HR, IT. Then the third one, which is my job, deals with international and policy and that essentially has two parts. One is I oversee all the engagement of the UK as a member or a shareholder of international agencies, whether it is the World Bank, the regional banks, the UN, the EU and the Commonwealth and, to the extent that DFID has a contribution, also WTO as well as the IMF. That is one part, the international agencies. The other part of what I look at is to think about what should be the policy that we take on any particular development issue, whether it relates to the policy that we promote in the international system or the policy that applies to our own programmes. In a sense we do not make a distinction between what we promote as good policies for our own programmes or for international agencies, but essentially what should be our view on specific development policy questions, whether it is a question like user fees or whether it is a question of migration and how we understand that. Within that structure I have two divisions that report to me. One of them is an International Division that brings together all the international work and the other is the Policy Division which Sharon White heads. I also have a number of chief advisers who act as a sort of internal challenge function, internal expertise, looking at economics, governance, social development, human development and sustainable development. That is the range of issues that we look at.

  Q3 Chairman: I think probably we have not seen enough of you so we shall have to try and rectify that. It may well be the way in which the topics are selected. The UK's largest bilateral aid programme is to India and I just wonder what kind of work we have done on the contribution that the NRI community, the diaspora, have made to welfare and enterprise, wealth creation in India? Is any work done on what the generations of migrants who come to the UK make in terms of development contributions to countries we are particularly supporting?

Mr Ahmed: If I could ask Sharon to give you a sense of what we are doing. I would just make a general point. A lot of the work that we have begun to do on migration has (a) been relatively recent in origin because, unlike some of the other areas, it is an area which DFID and other agencies have come to somewhat late in the day, and (b), given our primary focus on the poor and development, the initial focus of a lot of this work is looking at conditions in developing countries themselves and looking at the impact of the migrant communities in industrial countries, the diaspora, and how they feed back is something that we are only beginning to get into. Sharon can give you more specific information.

Ms White: Thank you very much. As Masood has mentioned, it is quite early days for us on the migration front. India is one of a number of countries in Asia where we have begun to do some more analysis of how migration is impacting on development. We had a conference a bit earlier this year bringing together India, Indonesia, China, Vietnam and the Philippines as a first discussion to raise awareness of migration. This year DFID is developing a new country assistance plan for India and one of the groups that we consulted was the Indian diaspora within the UK. We have begun the dialogue but there is still a bit further for us to go. There is some work that DFID supports within India in terms of trying to protect the human rights legal status of seasonal migrants within India. There is some work that we have in hand but we are hoping to do more work and to use the networks much more effectively in the future, particularly in thinking through our strategies.

Chairman: There is a broad issue here and this Committee is going to try and be reasonably disciplined in this inquiry otherwise we go off on all sorts of tangents. There is a broad point here, firstly to what extent is migration of benefit to the countries to which people migrate, and it seems to me with falling birth rates in most developed countries that is obviously an issue of some importance, but also one of the things we need to get a handle on is the contribution that diasporas make to the countries of which they are part of the diaspora. Maybe one of the things that you could possibly share with us, not now but perhaps in writing[1], is an indication of the research work that DFID has been doing on this and we can compare that with the work that those at Sussex University and others have been doing and so on, so we can see what is the totality of the information that is around us in this area. I think we are all putting our minds to this anew.

  Q4 Mr Davies: You say, Mr Ahmed, you have done some work on migration. I was wondering if you could tell us at least what your preliminary conclusions are? I know it is a very broad question but, just to try and narrow it and make it a bit more specific to our interests, can you distinguish between the extent to which migration is driven by extreme poverty; the extent to which it is driven by something quite different, which is improved economic circumstances and education giving people the feeling that they actually do even better by crossing the frontier and changing their job; to what extent it is driven by environmental factors; to what extent it is driven by a conflict; to what extent by persecution, by totalitarian tyrannical regimes? These are some of the broad categories. Is it possible to give some indication as to the relative weighting in the data that you have examined?

Mr Ahmed: I would be happy to do that. First of all, there are all these phenomena that co-exist in different parts of the world. At the same time, we need to try to get an aggregate picture of them. The first point, and in some ways it is quite striking when you start looking at migration numbers from a development perspective, is how important internal migration is within developing countries. In some ways we tend to focus very much on migration across boundaries, national boundaries, but in terms of simple numbers, even though the numbers on internal migration are quite bad, if you take a couple of countries—India and China—the numbers of people that migrate seasonally, either from rural areas to urban areas or that have migrated on a more permanent basis from rural to urban areas, are probably in the neighbourhood of 200 million a piece, so those are quite large numbers and that is just for two countries. For the poor in developing countries, in some ways this kind of migration is the one that is more direct, that is what most of them are engaged in. It is also the one that for them is part of the livelihood strategy, part of how they earn their livelihoods over their lifetime, maybe one family member may migrate to the city and others may be seasonal workers. As a first point I simply want to emphasise internal migration. The second point that comes through from the numbers is international migration. Again, a fair amount of is south-south. In the case of Asia, for example, if you exclude China, probably something like 80% of the migrants out of Asian countries stay within the continent. It is not necessarily a south-north phenomenon, so we can just put that aside. Let us talk a bit about the numbers and structure of international migration between developing and industrialised countries. Again, if you look at the numbers:- a fair amount of caution is needed about how robust the numbers are, but the one that most people use as a benchmark is about 170 million international migrants. That is about 3% of the world population.

  Q5 Mr Davies: That is the number currently living as international migrants?

Mr Ahmed: Yes.

  Q6 Mr Davies: What is the annual flow figure?

Mr Ahmed: I will come to the flow figures in a minute, if I might. If you look at the structure, in industrial countries the vast majority of people coming in from developing countries as migrants are actually skilled workers, so you change the nature of the profile of migrants who are coming in as skilled workers. Skilled workers coming into industrial countries raise a different set of issues in terms of their impact on development and it becomes a bit more difficult to say categorically whether this is good or bad for development. On the one hand, there are some quite positive factors, the most visible one in some ways being the effect of remittances. They are quite large numbers, again subject to a certain amount of uncertainty, but probably in the neighbourhood of $70 billion or $80 billion a year official and probably twice as much, maybe more, unofficial remittances. You can make quite good arguments about how remittances are counter-cyclical, so they continue even when countries go through a bad patch and they tend to go directly to households so there is less of a loss in the transfer, which you worry about with development assistance in terms of whether it actually reaches the poor. On the other hand, there are some questions about how they are spent, whether they might promote consumption rather than investment, some questions about them promoting inequality, but nevertheless it is a very big factor in terms of general equality. The second set of things that are positive also are increasing the kinds of links that are not financial alone but in terms of the contributions that diasporas make in fostering technology markets, enterprise, going back to re-establish businesses. Of course, particularly the Indian diaspora involved in information technology has been a prime example of people who have gone back and helped to make the connections that have helped establish exports in that area. That is on the plus side. On the negative side, I think it is worth mentioning that there is a very legitimate worry about whether the recruitment of skilled workers, particularly in shallow markets from countries where there is a very limited number of these workers, particularly in healthcare, say, may be exacerbating the difficulties of promoting healthcare in those countries. When you look at the data I think there is a certain amount of legitimate worry that in some countries that might be exacerbating the situation. It is obvious that the answer is not to stop the possibility of migrating which may not be feasible because people tend to find ways around that route. Also, the answer may be to try and strengthen the supply of skilled workers in that country rather than to stop recruiting them. There is a debate and discussion around the negative side of that. There are other social negative effects as well in terms of whether the separation of families causes problems. The last thing I should say is if you look at the numbers that come through, we have been talking mainly about migration as a voluntary phenomenon, much of it is voluntary, some of it is illegal but it is still voluntary, people moving because they feel they would be better off whether by moving within a country or moving across boundaries, and those numbers are quite large, but there is an involuntary dimension to migration which is either internally displaced people, and the numbers of internally displaced people are quite significant, in the neighbourhood of about 20-25 million internally displaced people who have been displaced because of conflict or environmental problems or other reasons, sometimes associated with development projects, problems have been associated with that. There is also international trafficking of vulnerable people. Frequently these are people who are genuinely very poor coming from a poor background and obviously they are subject to all kinds of exploitation and there is a worrying dimension of involuntary transfers associated with that. For refugees, which is one manifestation of that involuntary movement in some ways of people who are trying to flee, the numbers are about 10 million or so. It is important to recognise that refugees largely take refuge in neighbouring developing countries, so of that number of about 10 million probably three-quarters are in developing countries. Similarly, internally displaced people by and large are concentrated in a few developing countries. The manifestation of involuntary migration, the forced migration that we see in industrial countries, either takes place in the form of asylum seekers who make it here, who are generally better off, better educated than the ones who stay in developing countries, or they are people who come through in the form of trafficking, people who are trafficked into Western Europe. I must say to you that I was struck when I started looking at the numbers—again the estimates are very dicey—by the fact that probably 400,000 people a year are being trafficked into Western Europe, many of them women and children, and probably about 200,000 of them come in from Eastern European countries. That is part of the dilemma, how does one then manage the risks associated with the voluntary migration and maximise the benefits and how does one control some of the factors that affect the involuntary.

  Q7 Mr Davies: Thank you. For the purposes of making progress in the discussion, let us distinguish between three types of migration. The first category would be the internal voluntary migration, which is surely inescapable from economic change if one thinks of what happened here during the Industrial Revolution, for example, in England, the United States, Germany and elsewhere, that is one category. The second category would be forcible displacement either as a result of conflict or being driven out, and that is obviously highly undesirable as a problem. I would be grateful if you would focus on the third category, which is voluntary movement across frontiers, voluntary and international. You set out some of the factors which can operate on both sides of the equation, positive and negative. A positive aspect could be the generation of local consumption and demand as a result of remittances, generation of investment flows as a result of remittances, formation of human capital through the development of new skills while the immigrants are abroad if they then come back to their own country with that higher level of human capital. Those are obviously plus factors. A negative factor would be the one you have mentioned, which is the removal of human capital which does not come back and which could have been very valuable for development. Can we get from you, Mr Ahmed, if we can, a sense of the balance of advantage here. It is very important. On a net basis, do you think that this voluntary international migration at the present time is an advantage to the human race, is positive, is part of the solution, or do you think that on balance it is problematic?

Mr Ahmed: I can give you my own assessment.

  Q8 Mr Davies: It is a one word answer.

Mr Ahmed: I will give you my answer to it. My answer to it would be unambiguously that (a) overall it is positive and (b) it is an inescapable dimension of globalisation. The issue is not should one have it, should one not have it, but how does one manage the risks and maximise the benefits. Yes, it is positive and one could probably make it more positive if one managed it more effectively.

  Q9 Mr Davies: My final question on this particular subject is in relation to women. Can you say anything specific about female migration in this context or do the same considerations apply equally to both halves of the human race?

Mr Ahmed: The only thing that one might want to add in terms of female migration is that for obvious reasons, (a), they are more likely to be subject to exploitation during trafficking of various kinds and they figure disproportionately in that, along with children, although numbers are pretty weak on trafficking. I think one needs to worry about that dimension of it. On the positive side, (b), a lot of women migrants who are not migrating as part of families but migrating as the primary migrants themselves in search of employment, particularly from countries like the Philippines, have been very important sources not only of providing income for their families but in some ways you can see evidence in some cases where it has raised their empowerment and their ability to make decisions and so on. It can actually be quite a positive empowering phenomenon but, on the other side, there is the worry about trafficking.

  Q10 Chairman: The Holy Grail for this Committee is the Millennium Development Targets. Can I just put to you a contrary thought, and it is this: when one goes around Africa one is continually seeing skilled people being stripped out, nurses and doctors. I think it is said that there are more doctors of Ghanaian origin in New York State alone than in the whole of Ghana. When we went to Malawi I saw a nurse training school where the whole of those who were qualified, with the exception of one, were coming to the UK. I think there is a genuine concern that the NHS is hoovering up qualified nurses from developing countries. Is this something that DFID is doing work on? Is anyone monitoring how we in the North/West are hoovering up the best skilled from developing countries? Going back to your point, it may not be possible to prevent that, and indeed I think the UN Charter gives people the right to leave their own countries, if I remember rightly, but in those countries where we are particularly taking people—South Africa, Ghana, Nigeria and others—should we not be seeking to help replicate those skills by providing extra training for nurses, extra training for doctors in those countries? It may be more cost-effective for us in terms of policy rather than training nurses here to be training nurses in South Africa or Ghana knowing that we are going to recruit them in the UK as part of their development and our needs.

Ms White: I think it is an issue of big concern to DFID. I think the impact on the country depends, as Masood said earlier, on how shallow the skill base is. We find in some developing countries, like Ghana as you say, a very high proportion, 60/70%, of health professionals are migrating to countries like the UK. In others we find that one of the reasons why professional staff are migrating is because they are unable to get a job in their chosen profession at home, so the circumstances may be more grave than in others. We are trying to do a number of things. DFID has become more active with other government departments, particularly the Department of Health, in drawing up an ethical recruitment list, so as not to target those countries where the depletion of skilled professionals is going to be particularly problematic. We are also trying to work with other donors to make sure that the practices of recruitment agencies more generally internationally are rather better. A lot of our mainstream development assistance is targeted to try and strengthen the capacity within countries: reform to civil service pay structures, trying to improve service delivery so that there are better jobs and people are going to have less need, in a sense, to migrate overseas for the good employment to raise their living standards.

  Q11 Mr Colman: Are you talking, in a sense, about compensation being paid to the developing countries for the fact that we are taking their skilled labour and employing it in the UK? Do you think that there is a straight aid component in this in terms of what you should be paying, say, Ghana or the Philippines?

Ms White: Not compensation. What we are trying to do is make sure that the economic opportunities for people domestically are strong enough so that the incentive to migrate to the UK is less strong, so the wage rates of teachers, of nurses, of doctors, are rather higher, the prospects are better, higher education systems are able to domestically train workers. It is not providing a wage substitute but trying, through various forms of assistance, to improve the labour market prospects for professional workers.

  Q12 Mr Colman: Clearly the wage rates that could be paid in Ghana, say, to a nurse or a doctor are significantly less than could be paid under the NHS in the UK. Is there still not a requirement that we should pay compensation to the Ghanaian economy in some way to deal with this otherwise unbridgeable gap?

Ms White: We do not feel that compensation is the most appropriate response because it would be very difficult for us across all countries to try to level up to global wage rates. Do you think about paying US wage rates to professional workers across the world? That is why our focus is really on trying to improve the local capacity, improve the local prospects for people in countries in our mainstream development assistance.

  Q13 Chairman: Before we move on to remittances I would like to ask one other question. You mentioned trafficking. On this Committee we are not very good at Eastern Europe because they tend not to get much UK development aid or EU development aid, but trafficking to me suggests involuntary migration, it suggests slavery, it suggests forcible migration. The figures you were quoting were quite significant. I just wondered who is compiling those statistics? Where does HMG get those figures from? Who, within the machine of government, takes the lead on pursuing issues in relation to trafficking? Other than occasional stories in the newspapers one does not get a sense of this being an issue in the UK. Is it a bigger issue elsewhere in the European Union or in other Member States? What is your feel on trafficking?

Mr Ahmed: We rely on a lot of sources to get data. The one that we rely on particularly in the area of trafficking data is the International Organisation for Migration, the IOM. They provide data. It is not an area where DFID has a lead because lots of these issues about trafficking into the UK are areas where the Home Office would have a lead on it.

  Q14 Chairman: We are talking about forcible migration, almost slavery here.

Mr Ahmed: It is forcible.

  Q15 Chairman: Involuntary migration.

Mr Ahmed: It is certainly involuntary and people who are either deceived into believing where they are going to or in one form or another subsequently exploited. Yes, it is involuntary. It is different from what one would call smuggling of people, which in some sense is voluntary, complicit, where the person being smuggled wants to come in but to go around legal barriers. We rely on that data. I cannot say to you how the numbers for the UK relate to numbers overall, except to say that numbers for Western Europe as a whole are about half a million, 400,000. Exactly what the breakdown is, of that I do not have to hand, but I would be happy to try to find that out[2]

Mr Colman: The Home Office has been doing major work on this in the last two years, so if Mr Ahmed can get that note to cover the Home Office as well I think that would be very interesting.

  Q16 Hugh Bayley: How significant economically are remittances to developing countries? Which countries in absolute terms receive most remittances and which receive most as a proportion of their national income? What sorts of factors determine the levels of remittances that expatriates make to countries?

Mr Ahmed: The overall number of remittances was something in the order of $80 billion a year for 2002.

  Q17 Hugh Bayley: Globally or from the UK?

Mr Ahmed: These are all global numbers. Which countries are the primary recipients of this? Let me give you the first five: the largest numbers are going into India and that is in the order of about $14 billion a year, then (and I would be happy to send you a table with the specific numbers[3]) Mexico, Philippines, Morocco and Egypt. However, these are not the countries for which remittances are the largest share of their economy. As you might expect, a number of small countries and low income countries feature more prominently in that list. Just to give you the first three: 14% of Tonga's GDP is now remittances, Lesotho 30% and Jordan about a quarter. A couple of points about the nature of these remittances, what drives them, what can we say about what works? The first point is one that I mentioned in response to an earlier question which is that they tend to be a more stable form of flow, which is obviously good from the recipient country's point of view because they do not tend to mirror movements and other things—they tend to be counter-cyclical. The second thing that is important about the remittances is that in a number of countries they tend to reach quite a broad range of the population, a large number of households are actually getting it. In El Salvador it is estimated that something like three-quarters of households get an income from remittances. Similarly, in the Philippines it is quite broad based and in Senegal. Some studies show they have a direct effect on reducing poverty. The World Bank and others have done studies which have shown that if you have a ten per cent increase in a country's share of remittances, that is generally associated across countries with about a 1.5 per cent increase in poverty reduction. These cross-country numbers are useful as a benchmark but I would not personally say there is a precise relationship that applies in every case. The broad case suggests that they will have an impact on poverty. What is also interesting is that in terms of the migrants and who is sending them now, their own contribution, there are some factors that appear to affect whether or not they send more of their income as remittances or less. One interesting point is generally women appear to send a larger percentage of their income as remittances than men do. Secondly, generally the low skilled migrants tend to send a larger proportion of their income as remittances. Migrants who are there on a temporary basis and whose families are at home predictably send a larger share of their income in remittances. The longer people stay the more the remittances decline. It is interesting to watch intergenerational differences. South Asian migrants are generally dropping off after the first generation. For other migrants coming in from other parts of Asia it is the second or third generation where they stop sending remittances back. One of the problems about sending remittances has been that the cost of transfers has been quite high. In some cases 15 or 20% is used up as the simple cost of transferring remittances from the UK to Latin America for example. As the cost of transferring money has come down people have started sending more remittances through the efficient channels. What we do not know is whether this means more remittances are being sent back or more are being sent back through the efficient channels which were previously sent through unofficial channels about which we have less data. Also, on the one hand, there is this desire to make it easier to transfer money, reduce the cost and there are things that governments have done quite effectively in terms of making it easier to open bank accounts and the like, but, on the other hand, there is a worry about how this relates to concerns about money laundering and the financing of terrorism. Governments have also been making it harder to transfer money through informal channels and trying to track better the money that flows through official channels. DFID has been working on this issue of migration and along with the World Bank we organised a conference here in October. This was actually the first time we had brought together about 100 people from various countries and agencies to look at different elements of the links between remittances and their impact on migration. There is now a proposal which the World Bank will need to follow up by setting up a website to disseminate good practice on experiences across countries in terms of facilitating the process of remittances and reducing their costs and making it easier for migrants to participate.

  Q18 Hugh Bayley: Are there things that governments in developed countries, the UK Government in particular, could do to reduce the cost of remittances by changing fiscal rules for currency dealing? Where does the ten or 15% get absorbed? If you go to Thomas Cook, you can normally change your money for one or two per cent. What are the points of the system that you would need to target to reduce the transmission costs? What more could be done either by the financial services companies or by the Government? Have you looked at the taxation arrangements of remittances? We have taxation treaties with a lot of developed countries which stops double taxation. I know you have a slightly different issue when you give money from one person to another, but it does seem to me that it would be beneficial, if you want to encourage remittances, if you could either get agreement from developed countries that they will not further tax income that has been taxed or we would give a tax exemption for resources which are passed into a different tax regime and taxed within that regime. Is that something your Department has looked at? Once the money gets there, particularly in these smaller countries, remittances can have a big economic impact for the country concerned that may or may not help poverty alleviation depending on how the money is used and who it goes to. What are remittances spent on and what, in policy terms, could we do or developing country governments do to ensure that a greater proportion of remittances go to help the poorest people?

Mr Ahmed: I will tell you about some elements of it because it is a field where people are still trying to figure out what the best solutions are. Here are some thoughts about what countries have done. I think one thing one could do is make it easier for migrants to open bank accounts. If they can open bank accounts, they can use formal channels at lower costs than they can if they go through informal channels. Several commercial banks have made it easier for migrants to open bank accounts and that has had a noticeable effect on reducing the cost. A very simple thing is when they installed cash machines linked to US banks in Mexico they found it made it much easier for migrants from Mexico sending money back to be able to withdraw money from their account than if they had to go through the formal channels. The second thing is perhaps joining up with Post Office savings banks as well as with micro- finance institutions in developing countries because part of that 15% is used up by the fact that the reach of the financial sector in developing countries is frequently much more concentrated in urban areas, it does not reach the poor, but the bigger problem is that the financial sector is not servicing the needs of the smaller communities, which also manifests itself in terms of raising the costs of remittances. Thirdly, there is already evidence of greater competition. Once banks have started coming into this business and they have recognised how big the flows are it is beginning to have an effect and because of the increasing difficulty using informal channels, the Hawala system, that has given banks a greater opportunity because they see their market share increasing because of the flow being transferred over from informal to formal channels. Some host countries have also had tax rebate schemes on remittances like special bonds. India, in particular, has a special bond for non-resident Indians which provides them with a greater break. What could be done to ensure that the money that actually goes to developing countries is used more for investment than for consumption? Frequently what we think of as consumption may actually be one form of investment in the sense that, if you are looking at people investing in healthcare or meeting a health budget, it is actually quite a high priority from the point of view of people who are spending it. One needs to be a little bit careful about how one defines consumption and investment and also how one defines priority because in one way a lot of the country-based approaches to develop support now are to put the money in the hands of the recipients and let them make the choices. So in some ways with remittances that is what they are doing. Those choices do reflect how they see the return on investment and on saving and the environment within which those investments are being made. So it is very difficult to set up a sustainable scheme whereby remittance income will consistently have a higher return on savings than the rest of the population in that same country is able to get on its savings because what you are setting up is a mechanism for arbitrage whereby a lot of the local people will then try and get onto the scheme. In any event, it is obvious the best way to deal with the problem is to fix the environment within which those savings are being done more broadly, not only for the remittance scheme. Your question about whether we have looked at fiscal incentives in the UK or other industrial countries could raise some of the same worries about arbitrage, whether in a sense you can run sustainably a scheme for remittances which you could contain in terms of not having other flows also taking advantage of that tax break, but it is not something we have looked at in our work yet, perhaps other people have but I am not aware of it.

  Q19 Hugh Bayley: Perhaps it is something you could take back to your Department and talk about with other branches of government because although I understand your immediate reaction that you could create incentives for tax avoidance in this country if one were to introduce a scheme, there are quite a number of perfectly proper ways in which the government encourages either personal investment decisions or personal giving decisions in terms of tax relief for charitable donations and it might be possible to look at those as parallels. Finally, has your Department considered using aid monies as an incentive, perhaps matching individual remittances with government resources? If you want to encourage remittances, if you think it is a good way of getting a bit of global re-distribution, if you think it gets money into the hands of those who need it most, is that something you could do, rather than giving a tax incentive you give a government expenditure incentive either to the individual or to the state?

Mr Ahmed: The simple answer is we have not considered it. It is something we can take back and look at. There are two questions we would want to look at in this case. One is whether and how much you think providing that kind of incentive would lead to an increase in the flow of remittances, a net increase not simply a re-allocation from one channel to the other and secondly, what else you could have done with that aid financing, in a sense would you be better off supporting country poverty strategies, would you be better off supporting other kinds of objectives rather than tying it to this particular pattern? Both of those are empirical questions which it would be worth looking at to see what the answers are.



1   Ev Back

2   Further information to follow. Back

3   Ev. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 5 January 2004