Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 20 - 39)

WEDNESDAY 12 MAY 2004

DR LEA BORKENHAGEN, MR ANDREW JOWETT, DR CHRISTIE PEACOCK AND MR COLIN WILLIAMS OBE

  Q20  Chris McCafferty: What are the constraints?

  Mr Jowett: In Harvest Help's experience external inputs are important. You can raise productivity with just the right person assisting the farmer to try new things and improve the way they farm their small piece of land. For me it is this huge empty sea out there of hundreds of thousands of farmers with zero support, and with skilled workers (and it is a skilled job) you can achieve an awful lot. If I were to do one thing it would be to re-invent the training programme for field staff who work for whoever—the government, outgrow schemes, NGOs, whatever. We have got a real shortage of skilled people who can work with farmers to help them do better with what they have got. It is a major constraint.

  Dr Borkenhagen: One of the obstacles is that land is increasingly fragmented and that people have increasingly precarious access to it and therefore are unable to maintain consistent or increased productivity.

  Q21  Chris McCafferty: Why is that? Why is the land increasingly fragmented?

  Dr Borkenhagen: There are a number of different reasons. Some of them include massive changes in health. Some are environmental changes that really are quite exogenous and do not have any local drivers. Some of them are also to do with the privatisation that comes from large scale commercial investment in agriculture. Those are just three examples. To return to your main question, a second obstacle to agricultural productivity aside from fragmentation of land is food aid and food dumping which reduce the local market prices and therefore basically make moot any market activity that farmers would want to engage in. A third broader issue is that, whether you are talking about very local markets or large scale international ones, if poor people are not facilitated in attaining market access, market security and market fairness they would not be motivated to or have the ability to increase productivity.

  Q22  Mr Davies: I have a question for Dr Peacock who has not answered this question yet. I think FARM-Africa, while of course not excluding other important issues, has generally in answering this question put the emphasis on market access, a phrase that Dr Borkenhagen used a second ago. I wonder if you would like to tell us a bit more from FARM-Africa's perspective what you see as the major obstacles to market access and what you think the policy conclusions from that ought to be both for domestic governments and for foreign donors?

  Dr Peacock: To be honest, we have not done that much because we often work with very marginalised people who are trying to produce enough for home consumption. We are just starting to learn about it, for example, in our project in Kenya, the Meru goat project, where now we have managed to more than quadruple milk yields. There is now masses of milk at home, there is milk for local sale, and we are just starting to get into processing of milk and improved marketing. There is no doubt that the key to this is infrastructure. All of you I know have travelled in Africa and you know how lousy many of the roads are. Infrastructure has got to be improved. It is a physical thing for perishable goods in particular. Information as well has to be improved and the explosion of mobile telephones in many African countries, as I am sure you have all seen, is changing a lot of that very quickly. It is an area that we are just learning about ourselves because we are having sufficient success such that we are generating enough surplus.

  Mr Williams: If you are looking for particular solutions, a real improvement in short haul transport, moving goods from the farmer to the roadside, the first stage to market, would have a huge impact on incomes of small farmers as one technical solution. If we are looking for technical solutions we should be looking in those areas where there are real constraints.

  Q23  Mr Davies: Can I stop you there? You might think that that was an ideal opportunity for massive entrepreneurship because the capital threshold required to buy a truck and go round a few villages, collect the produce and take it to the nearest town is not impossibly high, one would think, even in the conditions of Africa, and the immediate improvement in the market price and therefore productivity would be quite substantial. Why is this not happening?

  Mr Williams: It is a question of the viability of motorised transport. I think there is a technical opportunity there that will make progress. I do not know what the solution is; otherwise it would have been found. Secondly, 90% of small farmers farm for one season in a year, whereas they could be farming the whole year. Water is not that bad in Africa. A lot more farmers could be irrigating and farming the whole year round. These are technical opportunities to assist and intervene on. I think that is a good one and we should be looking at it.

  Q24  Chris McCafferty: Dr Peacock, you mentioned earlier the need for effective agricultural plans and that you saw opportunities for DFID there. What are the implications for DFID's overall strategy in terms of raising productivity?

  Dr Peacock: I think there are huge opportunities for DFID to re-engage in agriculture and other donors, and I know the World Bank is also re-thinking their lending in this area. I would like to see a much more balanced aid programme. I and my colleagues are deeply concerned about the trend towards more and more resources going into direct budget support, leaving DFID itself with much less room to manoeuvre within particular sectors. That was why we welcomed the Country Assistance Plan that was recently developed in Kenya which seemed to have a much more balanced approach to development, supporting the government but also supporting other sectors, civil society and so on. In countries where there are weak democracies, growing democracies, that would be the sensible approach. There is the big question: is there a sector investment programme for agriculture? Is this what DFID should do as they do for health and education and others? There may be some resistance within DFID to this but I think it needs to be explored and each country is different, of course, but there are a lot of opportunities for DFID to explore new funding mechanisms. I very strongly believe that we all have to recognise that to have good quality aid costs money. It cannot be done on the cheap and it is better to do good development rather than lots and lots of bad development. I fear that with DFID's recent increase in their budget over the last few years, which is fantastic, there is a terrible tendency for shovelling money out the front door as fast as they can in big dollops because they have got so much of it. I would much prefer to see higher quality aid, well-managed, focused aid, and I think that could have a significant impact on agriculture productivity if it were targeted at the grass roots. To do this requires perhaps the exploration of new funding mechanisms and district level agricultural plans as one possible route.

  Q25  Chairman: The reality is that DFID are now moving much more towards budgetary support. What you are seeing is writing out cheques for central treasuries of other governments for health and education, HIV/AIDS programmes and that kind of thing, and so it is going to be more difficult to get money for agriculture. A few weeks ago you would have found me cast adrift on the Atlantic Ocean in a boat going to Bonthe, which is an island off Sierra Leone, because the outboard motor had broken down, so all we could do was sing hymns. Eventually we managed, after many attempts, to get the outboard motor going and it was a slightly worrying moment. Bonthe struck me as being an example of the problems that we all have in that this is a very fertile island that used to produce rice and palm oil, and where Wellsbourne helped them develop coconut trees which were shorter so that you did not have to climb so far to pick the coconuts, and piassava, which is a sort of rattan which was used to make the bristles in brushes for which they used to have quite a good market. However, during the years of conflict all of that collapsed so now in Sierra Leone they are importing rice. The price of rice in Freetown is now higher than it has ever been. They are not doing anything with palm oil. The piassava market has collapsed. I am not sure what has happened to the coconuts. What stopped anything happening was two things. One was a complete lack of leadership. Who was going to get a grip on this? Who was going to get the co-operatives going again? The other was a lack of finance. Little short of bringing in an African agricultural credit bank of some kind, I do not see the Government of Sierra Leone funding agricultural credit, I do not see DFID funding agricultural credit, so, other than NGOs coming in with money which is often not the right disciplines because it tends to be soft money or not the right market rates of interest so you do not have all the market disciplines; how do NGOs like FARM-Africa see this working out? Do you see the need for an African agricultural credit bank or somewhere where farmers could go and get credit to get themselves going? Otherwise I just do not see how you get the motor going to buy the seed to start the whole thing off.

  Dr Peacock: No. I am a very strong believer in the often vital role of credit and micro-finance. I would say that virtually every single success story of ours in Africa has pretty much involved some form of credit, whether it is in an informal way, such as goats given to a women's group, for example, and kids born and lent on to new families, so it is a very local level thing based often on traditional savings and credit systems (of which there are many in Africa) or in a more formal use of cash systems of revolving funds to support new enterprises. Certainly in the livestock field, which is my area of speciality, that is often the first step for a lot of people out of poverty, to acquire the ownership of livestock: small livestock and big livestock and more livestock eventually perhaps. That is a big economic driver in many parts of Africa which I think is very important to recognise. Historically there have been terrible failures of government credit programmes and as a result in many cases a very bad credit culture has developed because people have got away with not paying in many instances, with the exception of women, who are the most incredible repayers of credit generally and have the most remarkable repayment rates in my experience. They take credit extremely seriously but are often prevented from obtaining any form of credit because of the barriers and the collateral requirements and all these kinds of things. It is a really big constraint for a lot of women. I see credit as being very important. It probably needs to be along the lines of more non-profit type bank style things, and KREP in Kenya seems to be doing quite well from what I hear, and these kinds of models, even a role perhaps for a farmer organisation to provide credit eventually to its members as a service. I think credit is absolutely vital.

  Dr Borkenhagen: Oxfam over the past couple of years has been working with some more progressive banks, Etimos in Italy and Rabobank in The Netherlands to facilitate providing loans to establish co-operatives. This has not been an activity, as you were saying, that has been taken over by NGOs or has been done by requesting assistance from the development agencies. Rather, Oxfam has played a role in guaranteeing the loan on behalf of the farmers and the co-operative to the bank, so it has minimised the risk of that loan and has been effective.

  Mr Williams: Increasingly productivity sector organisations in the market are participating in and encouraging that and that will increase.

  Q26  Mr Davies: I just want to amplify the important issue of land tenure which is allied to what you have been saying. There is a perception if you take the long view you will not get farmers to invest anyway unless they are certain that they will continue to get the benefit of the investment. If you want investment to be provided you have to ensure that people have security of tenure. Then we have the most interesting de Soto hypothesis which says that unless people can be clear about their property rights less capital will be available because it will not be possible to provide secured lending. If one thinks about it, it is a challenging hypothesis. What do you think the importance is in the business of improving agricultural productivity of securing effective land tenure rights and what policy conclusions do you think we should be drawing from that?

  Dr Peacock: Certainly this is fundamental. When I first arrived in Ethiopia in the late eighties land was redistributed every year. Farmers did not know from one year to the next what land they would get which was an absurd situation. It depends on what sort of investment you are talking about, the length of time and so on, as to how secure your land has to be. Certainly in terms of long term soil improvement, soil conservation measures, you want very long term rights of use over the land. I would also look more broadly at the rights of pastoralists, for example, for grazing which have been eroded over many years in Africa and establishing those rights is equally important to food production and to livestock production. It is absolutely vital that we work within the land reform programme in South Africa, which is quite a radical change in redistributing the huge chunk of land and our role is to try and help people get some production out of the land they acquire. At the moment there is clearly a trend of land going out of production as part of this land reform process, which is undesirable but there have been strong political pressures driving this forward. Clearly, securing rights of access to land is critical to long term agricultural development.

  Q27  Mr Davies: You have to be very specific if we are going to draw the right policy conclusions. When you say you want rights to land what we are talking about surely is that if the rights are to have any real impact, any economic significance, they have to be property rights. It has to be possible to transfer them; otherwise they are not any good as collateral for loans. What you are saying is that this is an obstacle to development in these countries. People do not have property rights in that sense.

  Dr Peacock: There are very particular issues for places like Ethiopia. There have been state concerns within Ethiopia that if land was privatised there would be a massive landless class created after the next drought. That is the Ethiopian situation, and perhaps in Malawi there is the same difficulty in this area, but I think there are ways round that.

  Q28  Mr Davies: We have had some clear testimony from FARM-Africa and could I ask Dr Borkenhagen, because I sense from the Oxfam paper—which I have read, as always with interest—that you do not agree with that: in the paragraph on "Land rights and economic and social stability" you say, "We are concerned that DFID's approach supports a `willing-buyer, willing-seller' arrangement in land reform."[3] Surely a "willing-buyer, willing-seller approach" is what Dr Peacock and I have been talking about. You do not share that analysis?

  Dr Borkenhagen: A `willing buyer, willing seller' approach assumes equal power in a market exchange. We reject this because there are so many inequalities in land distribution and land rights. In our discussions earlier, before we came today, we did talk about land rights and rights of tenure issues. As I said earlier on, what is important and what we agreed among ourselves before, and what I think Dr Peacock was very much in agreement with, is that what we support is that people should have legitimate rights to access, use, own and control land. This may be enabled by written down titles so that the title owner can sell them, but it does not have to require the writing down of land ownership, and indeed does not have to imply land reform at an operational policy level—not necessarily formal land tenure. To ensure people invest in their production, it is necessary for them to have secure rights. This is important for DFID to consider for women because they unusually have less power in land rights.

  Q29  Mr Davies: When I say "property rights", my question is based on the suggestion that both men and women would be able to hold those rights. It would be scandalous and against Human Rights Act principles if it were otherwise. I think that is a red herring.

  Dr Borkenhagen: I was not making that point; I was making a different point. For there to be legal binding titles to land in order for people to sell them, there are certain classes of less powerful people that are going to lose out. Whether those classes are men or women will be context specific.

  Mr Davies: That is a different point. I want to establish whether the principle would be desirable, whether we should have property rights as we understand them in this country. It is a different issue what the pragmatic problems might be of achieving such a regime. You may have to look at the registration of rights. There is a bit about that in de Soto's book, as you probably know. The impression I get from your written submission was that you did not share the view that we have just heard from FARM-Africa which I have tried to summarise. It is important that we should know that. Maintaining solidarity between NGOs is less important than opening up the whole issue to public debate and getting the right policy response.

  Chairman: It seems to me there are whole areas like land reform, land rights, land tenure, where they clearly do have a shorthand for something substantial behind them. Perhaps Andrew would be kind enough to do an idiot's guide for MPs on the politics of land rights, land tenure and land reform, because there is obviously a whole politics of shorthand here and I think what we have been seeing is a bit of what Quentin said, you trying to reconcile these bits of shorthand into policy. If we could understand what the shorthand was about it would be more helpful for us. Does that make sense?

  Q30  Mr Davies: But, Chairman, I do want to make one point if I might, and that is that there are genuine differences of view. They should not be disguised or hidden and we want to know what the differences are.

  Mr Jowett: I am not going to try and answer that!

  Chairman: You have made that point. Andrew, you can now say something.

  Q31  Mr Davies: One side of A4 only.

  Mr Jowett: We will put something together for you.

  Q32  Mr Davies: You can make it a consensus document.

  Mr Jowett: No, we will not do that. We will put forward the arguments. We will send that in in writing[4]. Can I just make one point, because this discussion started after a discussion on access to credit and whether or not you needed land title for access to credit. You do not. There are dozens of locally managed credit programmes having a significant input that do not depend on land title serving as collateral. Usually there is a savings programme in place, or other assets maybe, or guarantors may be used or insurances, so it is a bit of a red herring, this argument over access to credit in terms of needing land title.


  Q33  Chris McCafferty: Can I turn to something completely different? The funding of NGOs has changed, as you are very well aware, quite dramatically over the last ten years. In times gone by there was access to general aid funding and now you are in a situation where for the most part you are being paid to provide a contracted service and those contracted services are generally speaking based on policies of donor governments or aid agencies. Does that cause a conflict of interest and how should NGOs interact with national governments and what is the appropriate role of an NGO in your view?

  Mr Williams: Are you talking about national governments like Malawi?

  Q34  Chris McCafferty: I am talking about donor governments because generally speaking the contracted service is through donor governments or aid agencies, although of course it can be through national governments, but I am interested in donor governments and aid agencies where you may have a contracted service, being a contracted service provider.

  Mr Williams: We receive money from DFID, from USAID, from the EU, and we have had to develop a whole new set of skills in each case to deal with that. The goalposts change quite frequently, which means another set of skills and that is reality. From our perspective all the time we are trying to pursue our own long term strategy through those changes. They are not always negative but I think it helps us also to be a bit more professionally accountable than we may have been in the past on the one hand. On the other hand sometimes there is a bit too much detail required that may not be relevant.

  Q35  Chris McCafferty: You said that sometimes you are able to deliver your own strategy. Is there not a conflict of interest?

  Mr Williams: Of course; yes, there is.

  Q36  Chris McCafferty: What is the nature of the conflict? Can you give me an example of one?

  Mr Williams: I can give you one example of wanting to concentrate on a certain technical area, such as market development, where the donor was far more interested in concentrating on hardware inputs on the production side and, more than that, where our interest was the position of the small farmer and getting the best deal and the lowest costs for the small farmer but the donor was particularly interested in developing local manufacture which we did not think was the priority interest of the small farmer.

  Dr Peacock: It is always very difficult to generalise about NGOs because they are so different, every single one of them, and the roles that they play and the roles that they want to play are very different. There are some that just earn their living, if you like, by doing contracts, providing services to people, and that is a legitimate thing. I think there is a danger in many African countries, partly driven by donors, of a blurring of NGOs with consulting companies, if you like, and private sector contracting service suppliers. A lot of NGOs, certainly FARM-Africa, see their role as being independent, trying to innovate and do new things and be independent of government but working with government, being able to pursue their own strategic objectives through accepting funding from a range of different donors and trying to spread their risks that way. It is extremely difficult therefore to generalise about NGOs in this way but I think we see an important role for NGOs as being part of this mix of suppliers of services to farmers, indeed suppliers of services to government. We have just got a contract to provide training to the Ethiopian Government in pastoral development, for example, which was a big breakthrough for us. We viewed that as a very big breakthrough, but it was very much in keeping with our own strategic objectives and supporting what we thought was a very good programme of work.

  Chairman: There is also going to be another important role for you, it seems to me, which is that if governments increasingly move into budgetary support NGOs increasingly are going to be the only people out in the field and we are going to be increasingly reliant upon you to tell us whether the budgetary support is working, because one is not necessarily going to know that in Addis or Nairobi.

  Mr Battle: Some NGOs are now getting the contract to monitor the budget support which puts them in quite difficult positions sometimes, I would suspect.

  Q37  Mr Khabra: DFID has issued a policy paper and the International Development Select Committee has decided to hold an inquiry into the effectiveness of the agriculture policy of the Department. DFID's policy paper highlights its commitment to trade reform, because that is important as far as agriculture is concerned, and identifies work to raise product standards as influencing the ability of farmers to participate in international markets. I know for a fact that agriculture is important for people in developing countries as well as in poor countries because the large population depends on their livelihood from agriculture. I can give the example of India where there are small farmers who depend on agriculture. So far in developing countries they have been pursuing agriculture policies which are to the disadvantage of developing and poor country farmers, so do you think raising product standards is a sensible thing to do and could the regional trade agreements deliver results in the short term?

  Mr Jowett: Can I just make a general point in responding to that and maybe pass the question on because we are not that involved in the big global trade agreements and their effects? The vast majority of farmers that we work with in southern Africa are on the margins of all this globalisation. They are interested in improving food production on their farm for their own consumption. Broadly speaking that is still what the game is about. I fear sometimes that debates move too far towards globalisation and big trade issues and we are missing what is the major point, which is how we are going to support those millions of farming families to reduce their vulnerability—whatever jargon you want to use—or increase their food security by producing more from the same piece of land on a sustainable basis. I accept your point is important but I do not want us to get too deflected from the core issue here.

  Dr Borkenhagen: There are three broad areas of farming. You have the large scale commercial farming, you have the medium sized land holders, and then you have people who are really mixing and matching, doing a bit of subsistence agriculture at some point during the year, perhaps working as a waged labourer in the town for some part of the year and perhaps also working on a farm as a labourer for another time. What you have are very different kinds of lives that can be led through agriculture. The point that was just made is that these last two categories are huge. The commercial sector right now is indeed expanding and, as you were saying, supermarkets—also retailers and manufacturers of products—are imposing particular standards on food production. What is happening is that the commercial sector is drawing from this quite often landless third group which is looking for wage labour and they come in and work in these factory fields. The question is, first of all, what is the impact of standards in that realm? Part of the impact is that right now the people who bear the cost for raising those standards are the farmers themselves. Quite often they are relatively wealthier farmers to start with but, for instance, Tesco impose standards on the farmers from whom they buy of about $120 per farm that the farmers themselves have to pay in order to meet the standards, such as having toilet facilities on the farm and having other sanitary measures put in. The point is: the costs and the risks of transforming their production systems to meet those standards are being borne by the farmers and the farm workers, not by the supermarkets or the manufacturing agri-business companies. Agri-business companies are in a far better position to do so, however. What we at Oxfam, and also with the Ethical Trading Initiative which DFID also funds, are trying to do is to get that risk to be borne by the larger companies who can afford to bear it more than the farmers can, whether it is the slightly wealthier farmers who own these farms that feed into these agricultural global supply chains or whether it is the workers themselves, quite often women, who are having to meet those standards themselves, for instance, in relation to not having children on the farm at the time of harvesting.

  Q38  Mr Khabra: Is it really essential to raise standards? There must be some reason for wanting to raise standards, in order to disqualify poor farmers' products so that they cannot be sold in the market at all. What are those reasons? Is it just to protect their own interests or for health reasons or what?

  Dr Borkenhagen: Primarily it is risk aversion strategies by the agricultural production or retailing companies. They do not want to be caught out. If they are saying they are selling something that is organic, if in fact it is found to have a particular amount of pesticide on it then consumers can take them to court or whatever are the proceedings that can follow after that the retailers are avoiding potential risk to reputation by saying, "We have met such-and-such standards". The standards are mostly to do with health and safety, and some of them are to do with labour practices. By meeting the standards in some areas of their supply chain, they minimise the possibility of being brought to book by consumers or consumer groups or investment groups.

  Mr Jowett: If I understood your original question correctly, I do not think the answer for African farmers in general is the big export of cauliflowers or sweet peas. That is not what we are trying to argue for.

  Mr Williams: And we stay clear of Tesco and the toilets as well.

  Q39  Chairman: Obviously with different commodities there are going to be different issues, for the cotton farmers of Burkina Faso or Bali or Benin or for the cocoa farmers of Ghana or Sierra Leone. We take the point. What one does not want to have is a situation whereby everyone is doing high politics in Cancün and forgetting that for the vast majority of farmers in Africa what they are really trying to do is get a living and sell their produce to local markets and regional markets.

  Mr Williams: I think the huge progress is to get in at the bottom end of the market for the vast majority of farmers. If we can be part of a process that makes that shift, that is where the big impact on poverty is going to be.

  Dr Borkenhagen: I also think that DFID is very well placed to understand exactly what you just said, that is, the relationship between these international trade regimes and the small scale farmers that we are discussing today. The impact of the trade regimes followed directly to those farmers is not that well understood. We want to have more direct linkages so that we can feed back to policy making. I think that, at least on the macroeconomic side, DFID is extremely well placed to do the macroeconomic analysis and we who are more in the field are well placed to do the analysis of the conditions of the rural poor.

  Mr Williams: We sometimes forget that DFID in one form or another and through several guises, through ODA and ODM and NRIN and TPI, has been working with small farmers for 60 or 70 years and the knowledge that they have built up is immense and we are slightly concerned that they are throwing it all away. They have a huge amount to offer, particularly in supporting research, the technical stuff, in local areas, much more than most other donors.

  Chairman: That is a huge message that we can finish on. Thank you very much for your papers, thank you very much for coming and giving your evidence, and thank you very much for the further paper that you are going to give us.





3   Ev 47 Back

4   Ev 50 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 15 September 2004