Select Committee on International Development Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Nigel Harris, Professor Emeritus, Development Planning Unit, University College London

I.  MIGRATION

  1.  It is now generally agreed that the European labour force is set to decline over the next three decades- to different degrees in different countries and at different times. Efforts are underway to increase the employment of adults currently not working, to raise retirement ages, and increase intra-European migration, but, even if these measures are successful, the deficits in labour supply will still be economically deleterious. Much public attention has been devoted to the problems of scarcity of skilled and highly skilled workers, but the educational systems of Europe are continually upgrading the native-born workforce so that there are steadily fewer workers willing to undertake low-skilled jobs—and the shortage of complementary low- skilled workers can severely reduce the capacity of the skilled to attain optimal levels of productivity.

  2.  The present system of migration controls, put in place in the 1970s, is no longer capable of accommodating both the dynamic but unpredictable domestic demands for workers of different skills, and the global demand for work in Europe, an incapacity illustrated in the perpetual changes in statute and regulation. The system is increasingly costly, bureaucratic, opaque and arbitrary. Intensifying controls only increases the criminalisation, brutalisation and militarisation of the process of entering Fortress Europe.

  3.  In sum, the workers are needed and developing countries have available a ready supply of willing and literate workers. Furthermore, there is evidence of major potential gains to the world economy from lowering migration controls.[86] The reluctance of Europeans to avail themselves of this obvious remedy arises from fears that the workers would want to settle and would impose burdens on systems of social security, housing etc. However, in terms of long-term settlement, contrary to popular opinion, many migrants, possibly a majority and particularly the low-skilled, do not want to go into permanent exile,[87] but only to secure access to work, to earn in order to support families left at home or meet other major expenses (to marry, purchase a house, pay for hospital treatment or education etc). This is particularly important where purchasing power values are markedly different between source and destination countries—a poorly paid worker in Europe has a middle income at home, provided he or she is able to spend the incomes earned abroad at home. Most migrants would seem to prefer to circulate rather than settle (of course, this generalisation is powerfully affected by conditions at home).[88] Circulation is the most ancient form of worker migration, and there are many schemes which have worked with great reliability in this field (not least, employer-run contract labour schemes).[89]

  4.  However, the effect of immigration controls is, perversely, to force migrants to settle, to accept exile until such time as they can secure citizenship and thus the freedom to circulate.[90] It has been commonly noted that Spanish, Portuguese and Greek migrant workers settled permanently in Germany until their countries entered the European Union and they won the right to return home without jeopardising their freedom to circulate and return to Germany if they wished. Thus, preserving the freedom to circulate is a condition of workers being willing to return home (as a number of European governments have found in the disappointing results of schemes to encourage return). However, the modern nation-State is ill-equipped to accommodate circulation. Governments assume and seek to preserve a sharp distinction between a clearly defined body of citizens, the basis for the exercise of democratic franchise and the privileges of nationality, and those who are foreigners and should leave. The instinct of government is to enforce either departure or "integration", incorporation into the historic nation.

  5.  However, despite the problems attached to the idea of migratory circulation, it provides a way both of spreading the benefits of migration over much larger numbers of people and meeting the fears of Europe's native-born population. Furthermore, the decline in international transport costs—and in ordinary communication—makes feasible the keeping of family and other social relationships intact while a worker is working abroad, and thus the social basis for return.

II.  DEVELOPMENT

  6.  In the 1990s, the dynamic of Europe's labour market attracted much larger numbers of regular and irregular workers from outside Europe—globalisation has, as it were, become inescapable on the streets of Europe's big cities. The by-product of this change has been an extraordinary increase in the flow of worker remittances to their home countries (increasing rapidly and now—including estimates of unofficial transfers in cash and kind—worldwide, possibly between two and four times the levels of official development aid). In development terms, this is a remarkable and unexpected increase in the revenues of developing countries. In addition, remittances are, in contrast to other revenue and investment flows, counter-cyclical (they increase in a recession), do not generate counter-flows (payments for imports, profits on foreign investment), and go directly to those in need in some of the poorer localities (Suro, 2003).

  7.  Governments in developing countries, after some reluctance, have become eager to harness this new source of revenues for development.[91] The four hundred or so home-town clubs of the Mexican diaspora in the United States have mobilised to finance development projects in their home localities—to pave a road, build a health clinic, primary school etc. Mexican local, State and Federal governments have, in some States offered three dollars to match each dollar remitted by a worker abroad, and re-aligned domestic anti-poverty, health and educational programmes (Progresa, now Opportunidades) to magnify the effect of remittance flows (Escobar et al, 2003; O'Neil, April 2003). The Mexican government after long years of shame at the scale of emigration of its citizens, has moved to track their destinations, keep in touch, supply Mexican identity cards (for irregular migrants), facilitate cash transfers and offer advice. Other countries have developed schemes to utilise the scarce skills of their most highly skilled citizens abroad to upgrade universities and the professions, and to start industries of high technology (Lindsay Lowell, Dec. 2001; Findlay, 2001).

  8.  However, migration can remove from the labour force of a developing country the most skilled, energetic and enterprising workers, making very much more difficult the task of conquering poverty. It would be quite wrong for Europe to purchase the welfare of its inhabitants at the cost of developing countries. However, there are means, discussed below, to turn circulatory migration into a positive reinforcement for development efforts.

III.  AID

  9.  Official aid programmes to developing countries play a great variety of roles, from supporting macro economic balance and reforms, financing responses to emergencies, and projects. Project aid has a mixed record of achievement and can, in certain circumstances, lead to the subordination of the perception of the developing country's requirements to the interests of the donor. This does not happen with remittances which carry no political strings. Furthermore, the lack of local development agents can jeopardise the outcome of aid projects. Donors employ governments in developing counties, consultants and, increasingly NGOs to play the role of local implementing agents. However, with circulatory migration, there could be an immense number of development agents in returnees. Aid programmes could then be employed to reinforce the efforts of returnees, of remittance flows and, as now, the efforts of developing country governments and NGOs.[92]

  10.  Enhancing human capital is widely seen as one of the most important issues in economic development and circulatory migration can contribute to this aim. On the one hand, temporary migration includes a large number of students who come to Europe to study. In many cases, they are also allowed to work. On the other, if we were to think of all circulatory migrants on the model of students (including in study, work-experience, on the job training, and enhancement of professional skills), then migration could simultaneously meet Europe's requirements for workers and enhance the human capital of developing countries through returnees. In addition, treating all migrants on the same basis would militate against the current tendency to create a two class system in which the highly skilled are able to move fairly freely, work and settle, but the low skilled are expected to be tied to the soil of their native place. Aid programmes in conjunction with host country educational institutions, could be enlisted to organise the training, education and professional development programmes of migrants, track returnees, and offer follow up programmes in the student's country of origin, of aid and support for development projects.[93]

IV.  LESSONS FOR EUROPE

  11.  There are many issues not resolved here—for example, how far families can migrate with temporary workers, how far extensions in the period of work are permitted, how people who wish to stay on a more permanent basis are to be permitted to make the transition from migrant to settler, how conditions of work and pay are to be regulated, monitored and policed, how migrants are to be accorded health protection during their work period (whether within or without existing social security arrangements). Ideally, employers should be obliged to bear the risks and costs of recruitment and repatriation, but this may not satisfy European electorates. Partnerships between home and host country governments, relevant trade unions and NGOs may be a formula for establishing a fair, well-regulated and well-policed system of circular migration.

  12.  However the central principle remains—to turn migration from a problem for both Europe and for developing countries into an opportunity for the reduction of world poverty.

V.  MIGRATION AND ANTI-GLOBALISATION

  13.  Between about 1970 and 2050, Europe is undergoing wrenching processes of social and economic change involved in the emergence of a single integrated world economy. European electorates have accepted much of this process already in terms of deindustrialisation (and the relocation of part of manufacturing capacity to Asia), in trade and capital movements, and now the "out-sourcing" of services. Major reforms in Europe's social security and pension schemes can also add to a generalised sense of insecurity Still to come are the full effects of declining population and ageing. In retrospect, the 1990s may be seen as witnessing the beginning of a major transition in terms of people, particularly in Europe's large cities. After 200 years or so of creating national States and the appropriate national identities, it is hardly surprising if the combination of these processes did not threaten to destabilise to the psyche. The economics of labour migration could become disastrously intertwined in the politics of personal identity. In fact, the process may be less destabilising for the majority of Europeans who belonged to countries than to those Europeans to whom those same countries belonged, or rather to the intelligentsia whose role it has been to articulate and sustain the national idea—a respectable xenophobia, may be more dangerous today than popular resentments. This would be enhanced for the population at large by the real or invented association of border crossing with terrorism. The danger of terrorism is less with the threat of particular acts of violence and rather more with the maintenance of a continual state of popular panic in electorates to which political leaders are obliged to react with "tough measures" if they are to survive politically.

  Not dealing with migration in a timely and publicly transparent way thus has the potential for disaster, pulling down the temple on our heads. On the other hand, converting the issue into an opportunity for a sustained attack on world poverty can mobilise the idealism of Europeans for this task.

February 2004

REFERENCES

  Baines, D E (1991): Emigration from Europe, 1815-1930, Basingstoke: Macmillan.

  Constant, Amelie and Douglas S Massey (2002): Return Migration by German Guestworkers: neoclassical versus new economics, International Migration, 40/4, 2002: 5-39.

  Constant, Amelie and Klaus F Zimmermann (2003): Circular movements and Time Away from the Host Country, IZA DP 960, Forschung Institut zur Zukunft der Arbeit (IZA), Bonn, December.

  Cornelius, Wayne (2001): Death at the Border: efficacy and unintended consequences of US immigration control policy, Population and Development Review, 27/4, December: 661-685.

  DFID-World Bank (2003): Report and Conclusions, International Conference on Migrant Remittances: Development Impact, opportunities for the financial sector and future prospects, October 9-10, London.

  Dustmann, Christian (1996): Return Migration: the European experience, Economic Policy: A European Forum 22 April 1996: 215-250.

  Eichengreen, Barry (1994): Thinking about migration: European migration pressures at the dawn of the next millennium, in H Siebout (Ed), Migration: a Challenge for Europe, Mohr, Tübingen.

  Escobar, Agustin, Philip Martin, Peter Schalzer, Susan Martin (2003): Migration: moving the agenda forward, International Migration, IOM, 41(2), 2003).

  Findlay, Alan (2001): From brain exchange to brain gain: policy implications for the UK of recent trends in skilled migration from developing countries, International Migration Programme 43, ILO, Geneva, December.

  Hamilton, C, and J Whalley (1984): Efficiency and distributional implications of global restrictions on labor mobility: calculations and political implications, Journal of Development Economics, 14 (1-2): 61-75.

  Iregui, Ana Martes (2002): Efficiency gains from the elimination of global restrictions on labour mobility: an analysis using a multiregional CGE model, World Institute of Development Economic Research conference, Poverty, International Migration and Asylum, Helsinki, 27-28 September.

  Lowell, B Lindsey (2001): (a) Some development effects of the international migration of highly skilled persons, International Migration Programme 46, ILO, Geneva, Dec. (b) Policy responses to the international mobility of skilled labour, International Migration Programme 45, ILO, Geneva, December.

  Massey, Douglas, Jorge Durand, Nolan J Malone (2002): Beyond Smoke and Mirrors: Mexican immigration in an era of economic integration, Russell Sage Foundation, New York.

  Moses, Jonathan W and Björn Letnes (2002): The economic costs of international labor restrictions, paper for WIDER conference (see Iregui above).

  O'Neil, Kevin (2003): (a) Using remittances and circular migration as drivers of development, Center for Contemporary Immigration Studies, University of California: San Diego, 11-12 April. (b) Migration and Development, Migration Policy Institute, Washington, December.

  Suro, Roberto (2003): Remittance senders and receivers: tracking the transnational channels, Pew Hispanic Center and Multilateral Investment Fund, Washington DC, 24 November.

  UNDP (1992): The Human Development Report 1992, UNDP: New York.

  Werner, Heinz (2002): From the German "Guestworker" programmes of the Sixties to the current "Green Card" initiative for IT specialists, International Migration Programme11, ILO, Geneva.

  Walmsley, Terrie L and L Alan Winters (2002): Relaxing restrictions on the temporary movement of natural persons: a simulation analysis, unpublished paper, University of Sheffield.

  Winters, L Alan, Terrie L Walmsley, Zhen Kun Wang, Roman Grynberg (2003): Liberalising labour mobility under GATS, Economic Paper 53, Commonwealth Secretariat, London.





86   The theory of international trade turns on the proposition that where there are differences in factor endowment (raw materials, labour, capital, entrepreneurship etc), between countries or localities, disproportionate economic gains result from exchanging factors. This is the rationale for liberalising world trade and the mobility of capital. A number of studies have endeavoured to put figures on the gains arising from the liberalisation of labour migration. Hamilton and Whalley (1984), using 1977 data and a set of strict assumptions, estimate gains to gross world product (then US$ 7.8 trillion) arising from lifting all migration controls at between $4.7 trillion and $16 trillion. Recent reworking of more up-to-date data confirm these broad magnitudes (Moses and Letnes, 2002; Iregui, 2002). UNDP, in the Human Development Report 1992 (pp 57-58), present a different calculation of more limited changes. Walmsley and Winters (2001) present a model in which worker migration to employment in services in developed countries equal to 3% of the developed countries labour force would yield benefits of $156 billion, shared between developed and developing countries, compared to the estimated $104 billion generated by a successful outcome of the Doha trade round (and the roughly $55 billion granted in aid to developing countries by the OECD group). The precise figures are no better than the assumptions made, but the direction of change, and the magnitudes, is important. Back

87   Without controls, it is commonly observed that migrant workers circulate. Thus, with the decline in trans-Atlantic transport costs of the 1890s, 40-50% of Italian migrants to the United States up to 1914 returned to Europe; and 30-40% of Portuguese, Croatians, Serbs, Hungarians and Poles (Baines, 1991). Constant and Zimmerman (2003) estimate that 60% of contemporary guest-workers in Germany are repeat migrants. See also Eichengreen (1994) and Dustmann (1996). Back

88   However, steady progress in many developing countries-in the provision of basic infrastructure, telecommunications etc, is narrowing the gap with developed countries. The availability of cheap support workers-maids, nannies, gardeners, cooks-may already mean that standards of livings for software programmers in Bangalore-at lower levels of remuneration-are higher than in Silicon Valley. Back

89   The German guestworker case is often cited to support the proposition that "there is nothing so permanent as a temporary worker". However this is a misjudgement since (i) employers pressed the government to keep workers because the suspension of the programme meant that there could be no replacements; (ii) workers tried to stay because they recognised that, if they left, there would be no repeat opportunity to work in Germany; (iii) in any case, a significant proportion of guestworkers did leave Germany-see Werner (2001); Constant and Massey (2002). There are many other schemes of circular migration that have worked effectively-for example, the US-Mexico Braceros scheme, contract labour schemes in the Persian Gulf etc. In the case of the Mexico-Canada agricultural labour programme, in the 28 years of its operation (with 12,500 workers involved in 2002), no Mexicans overstayed their visas, and 5% returned to Mexico before their visas expired-O'Neil (2003). Back

90   In the American case, Mexicans are estimated to have stayed in the US on average three years in the early 1980s, but in the late 1990s after major steps to tighten border controls, nine years-and as a result, bring spouses, put children into schools and seek US citizenship. On the general case, see Cornelius (2001) and Massey et al (2002): "Immigration policies should . . . recognise that most international migrants are not initially motivated to settle in developed nations, and that hardening the borders through police actions only undermines the inclination to return, ultimately reducing the flow of people and migradollars back to sending regions to choke off their development. A smarter strategy would be to counter the natural inclination to remain abroad by facilitating return migration and the repatriation of fund" (Massey et al, 2002: 157). Back

91   As also have financial institutions, development banks and aid donors-see the DFID-World Bank conference in London, October 2003. Back

92   The EU has made efforts to relate aid programme to migration, but these have usually been directed at preventing emigration rather than reinforcing development. Back

93   There have already been schemes here-see, for example, the Belgian Migration for Development programme; Working holiday maker schemes in Belgium, UK etc. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 8 July 2004