Select Committee on International Development Uncorrected Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Priya Deshingkar, Laxman Rao and John Farrington, Livelihood Options Project, Overseas Development Institute

THE SEASONAL MIGRATION OF RURAL LABOURERS IN ANDHRA PRADESH, INDIA

  This evidence is based on the results of the Livelihood Options project, a three year DFID-funded policy study, that aims to identify how policies can be changed to support positive exits via diversification, and how negative impacts can be reduced. The research was conducted by the Overseas Development Institute (ODI). Brief descriptions of ODI and the staff members involved in the research are presented below.

DESCRIPTION OF ODI AND STAFF

  ODI is Britain's leading independent think-tank on international development and humanitarian issues. Its mission is to inspire and inform policy and practice which lead to the reduction of poverty, the alleviation of suffering and the achievement of sustainable livelihoods in developing countries. This is done by locking together high-quality applied research, practical policy advice, and policy-focused dissemination and debate. ODI works with partners in the public and private sectors, in both developing and developed countries.

  The Rural Policy and Environment Group (RPEG) seeks to support positive changes in livelihoods through focused policy research and through its networks for information dissemination and exchange. RPEG specialists from social and natural science backgrounds examine a range of issues bearing on policies that influence rural livelihoods. RPEG works closely with governments, non-governmental organisations and international organisations to identify how natural resources can contribute to sustainable improvements in livelihoods. It aims to generate new knowledge and methodologies at the local level, and policy and institutional advice at national and international levels.

  The results of RPEG's research are intended for policy-makers, those implementing projects in developing countries, international and local NGOs, and of course rural people and their organisations. The Group also undertakes research-based policy advisory work and has an extensive programme of publications and information exchange; the Group aims to increase the effectiveness, efficiency and accountability of natural resource management and rural service delivery in the context of poverty reduction.

  Priya Deshingkar directed the Andhra Pradesh studies for the Livelihood Options project and is a Research Associate of the ODI. She has a PhD from the Institute of Development Studies, UK, and was formerly on the staff of the Stockholm Environment Institute. She has worked and published extensively on questions of poverty, environment and livelihoods in India.

  Laxman Rao is a Research Officer on the project and has a PhD in Political Science. He was posted in two of the study villages for a year and was responsible for quantitative and qualitative data collection.

  John Farrington is a Research Fellow at the London-based Overseas Development Institute and led the Livelihood Options study. He is also Visiting Professor at the University of Reading, UK, where he obtained a PhD in Agricultural Economics. He has worked and published extensively on India.

INTRODUCTION

  Seasonal and other forms of circular migration have long been part of the livelihood portfolio of poor people across India. It is now recognised that migration is a part of the normal livelihood strategy of the poor and does not occur only during times of emergency or distress.

  The National Commission on Rural Labour (NCRL) puts the number of circular migrants in rural areas alone at around 10 million (including roughly 4.5 million inter-State migrants and 6 million intra-State migrants). But government departments such as rural development, agriculture or labour are not geared to dealing with migrants and regard them as "external" to the systems that they work with. According to the NCRL, the majority of seasonal migrants are employed in cultivation and plantations, brick-kilns, quarries, construction sites and fish processing. Further, large numbers work in urban informal manufacturing, construction, services or transport sectors, employed as casual labourers, head-loaders, rickshaw pullers and hawkers (Dev, 2002).

  However, official awareness of the magnitude of seasonal migration or the importance of it in the lives of the poor is abysmally low. Policy-makers have tended to perceive migration largely as a problem, posing a threat to social and economic stability and have therefore tried to control it, rather than viewing it as an important livelihood option for the poor. There is little by way of organised accessible support for poor migrants who face insecurity in their source location as well as destination.

  This paper focuses on seasonal and circular migration for employment from rural areas in AP. We do not discuss seasonal migration by livestock-keepers for grazing or seasonal migration of fishers from coastal areas but much of the generic argument will apply to them too. Neither have we dealt with permanent and semi-permanent migration for employment, which has different determinants and impacts and is therefore beyond the scope of this paper.

  This work synthesises 12 months of primary data collected across the Livelihood Options study's six villages in AP. Each of the six villages provided labour for different migration options or streams.[84] The remainder of this paper presents a broad picture of who migrates, by income, class, caste and gender, then examines specific migration streams in more detail and finally explores how migrants may best be supported by policy.

    —  Migration is a routine livelihood strategy and not simply a response to shocks—corroborated by case studies from all over India.

    —  Migration can lead to the accumulation of wealth, particularly where there are marketable skills or established employment relationships.

    —  Processes of social exclusion prevent people from moving from low-return and insecure migration to more rewarding types (segmented labour market).

    —  Accumulative outmigration can occur from poor areas and distress/short term coping migration can occur from well-endowed areas.

A DESCRIPTION OF THE STUDY AREAS

  Andhra Pradesh (AP) has an area of roughly 275,000 sq km and a population of 75.7 million in 2001, almost 8% of India's total population. Three quarters of its population, or 55.2 million people, live in the rural areas, while nearly one third of its GDP is derived from agriculture. It receives a southwest monsoon from June to September, and the southern parts of the state also receive short winter rains. The rest of the year is dry with the hottest season being April-May. There are 23 districts in the state, each of which is divided into mandals, with each mandal covering 20-30 villages.

  Field work was conducted in three districts of AP, one from each of the state's three main regions, Telangana, Rayalaseema and Coastal Andhra. Each region differs in their historical, political and agro-ecological conditions, and display distinct patterns of livelihood evolution and diversification. Telangana is a semi-arid region, with relatively poor levels of infrastructure development, educational facilities, and advancement of women. It contains the state capital Hyderabad, which provides urban employment to many rural migrants, but is still home to some of the poorest people in AP. Rayalaseema has some of the harshest environmental conditions in the state, and perhaps even the country. Average rainfall is 700 mm, and the proportion of total area which is cultivated is only 38%. Once a prosperous farming centre, this region is now severely affected by drought: in some parts of the region, 2001 was the fifth consecutive year of drought. Coastal Andhra includes the coastal delta areas of AP which are similar to "green revolution" parts of Punjab, Western UP, Gujarat and Maharashtra. The region has developed more rapidly than other parts of AP in recent decades, with significant improvements in female literacy, incomes, infrastructure development, and infant mortality rates. Agriculture is based on the intensive cultivation of paddy and sugarcane on canal-irrigated lands, and draws in large inflows of seasonal migrant labour.

  The three districts chosen, after discussion with key informants, were Medak, Chittoor and Krishna. Within each district, two contrasting villages were selected for detailed household level study. The selection of villages was guided by various criteria, including proximity to urban areas, roads and markets as well as social and economic indicators of development.

  The two villages studied in Medak district, in the Telangana region, are Madhwar (MD) and Gummadidala (GU). MD is a remote village in the dry, backward, north-western part of the district. Income levels are low, and a large proportion of the working population migrate on a seasonal basis to high agricultural productivity zones, and to Hyderabad. However, land ownership is relatively equitable, with only 20% of all households owning no land at all. GU, by contrast, lies within an industrial belt in the south of Medak district, and is situated only 40 km from Hyderabad. A significant proportion of total income in this village is derived from industrial labour, and there are many more landless households than in MD. Partly as a result, GU has the largest gaps between the living standards of the rich and poor of all the six villages studied. Poorer households in the village use the nearby reserved forest to collect firewood, tendu leaves (used for making country cigars), leaf plates and broom straw.

  The two villages studied in Krishna district, in the Coastal Andhra region, are Kosuru (KO) and Kamalapuram (KA). KO is a large, well-connected village with canal irrigation, typical of the better-off villages of the delta zone. The average household per capita income is higher here than in any of the other surveyed villages, although landholdings are highly skewed (65% of households are landless), which explains why KO is also more unequal than the other villages, with the exception of GU (as measured by the ratio of the 90th to the 10th percentile of household per capita income). Assured irrigation enables farmers to harvest two paddy crops each year, and the village is the destination for seasonal immigrant labourers who come for up to three to four months in a year to transplant and harvest the paddy. KA is another prosperous village with assured canal irrigation, but is smaller and more remote than KO, with lower average incomes. There has been a considerable degree of permanent outmigration from KA over the years especially after a major cyclone in 1991 so that population growth in the village has been slow.

  The two villages studied in Chittoor district of Rayalseema are Voolapadu (VP) and Oteripalli (OP). VP is in the particularly dry, western part of the district, and has suffered from drought conditions for the last four years. However, it is less remote than OP in terms of labour market linkages: roughly one quarter of working adults spend part of the year outside the village in seasonal migration, particularly on construction sites in nearby urban centres. Sericulture is a major occupation in the village, which expanded rapidly during the 1990s, but is now under threat from cheap Chinese silk imports. OP village lies in the eastern part of Chittoor district, close to the border with Tamil Nadu. It has also been affected by serious drought during the past five years, and is now officially classified as drought-prone. Many farmers, particularly those traditionally involved in groundnut cultivation, now leave their lands fallow rather than taking the risk of farming with uncertain outcomes. Several poor households have diversified into service sector jobs, catering to establishments in the nearby town of Chittoor. Collecting and selling of non-timber forest products (NTFPs) is a significant source of income for poorer households, particularly during the lean work season.

  Information was collected from every household in each of the six villages on the ownership of assets, membership of local associations and credit groups, receipt of government assistance, extent of debts, receipt of migrant remittances, and caste group. Information was also collected from every individual in each household in each village on age, gender, martial status, education level, their primary and secondary occupations (if working), the income obtained from each of those occupations, and whether or not they spent part of the year outside the village through seasonal migration.




2.  CONCEPTS[85]

  Migration can be classified according to its temporal dimensions (seasonal, other short-term, long-term, permanent), its returns (coping or accumulative), distance (local, long-distance or international) or its cycle (one-off or repeated). Some have also distinguished migration "push" created by poverty and a lack of work and the "pull" created by better wages in the destination (Lee, 1966). Here, we are concerned primarily with seasonal, local or long-distant and (usually) repeated migration which may be either for accumulative or coping purposes, and may be either "push" or "pull". Our focus is also on the poorer segments of the population, and almost by definition, those usually excluded from favourable aspects of the local economy, though, as Skeldon (2002) has noted, it is generally not the poorest who have the contacts needed for migration, or can take the risk.

  In what follows, four inter-related questions are examined:

    —  What broad patterns of access to migration, either as a coping or accumulative strategy, do we observe across different social groups?

    —  How might we explain these patterns of access with respect to economic and social factors?

    —  How does migration seem to affect people's ability to move out of poverty, or remain trapped within it?

    —  What implications might this have for policy-makers?

  The following sections first provide an overview of the magnitude and structure of migration in the study areas and present an analysis of how migration patterns vary by caste[86], gender and landholding. They then examine the factors influencing accumulative and coping types of migration in the study area and finally address the question of how best policy can support migrants and reduce their vulnerability.

3.  THE MAGNITUDE OF MIGRATION

  Census data[87] collected from 4,647 households in AP show that migration occurred from all six villages but to varying degrees. On average 25% of the households had at least one member migrating. Key informant interviews suggested that the magnitude of migration has grown over time both in terms of the absolute numbers of people migrating and its importance as a source of household income. But in the absence of baseline data, it is difficult to quantify this increase.

  As expected, migration rates were extremely high from villages which were remote and located in dry areas without assured irrigation and prolonged drought conditions. But much of this migration from drought-prone areas was along old and established routes, which although precipitated due to a "push" of some kind (such as drought and crop failure) have now become regular and accumulative paths to engaging in high-return labour markets. Examples of this are the migrants from MD in Medak who have migrated for many decades to more prosperous areas.

Table 1

INCIDENCE OF MIGRATION IN AP SAMPLE VILLAGES
AP villagesTotal number of
households
Proportion of households
with at least one member
migrating (%)
MD427 78
VP553 33
KO1,429 10
GU1,560 4
KA464 15
OP214 9
Total4647 25
Source: Household Census


  The highest rates of migration were seen in the case of MD in Medak district where 78% of households had at least one member migrating. This village is located in a very dry and very backward part of the State contiguous with similar areas in Karnataka and Maharashtra. It is nestled in a cluster of villages, all of which are known for their high rates of out-migration to the capital city of Hyderabad, neighbouring States and the sugarcane fields of Medak and Nizamabad districts. Dryland agriculture is the mainstay of the economy in MD and there are few opportunities outside casual labouring. The average number of days of work available for an agricultural labourer is a mere 35 in the Kharif season. MD also had the highest number of persons migrating from each household at 2.87, suggesting that there are households where nearly everyone migrates. Next was VP, also located in a low potential area, but with good trade links to Bangalore, where the average number of people migrating per household was 0.72.

  The exceptions in the State were dry villages where migration rates appeared very low (OP near Chittoor town, and GU near Hyderabad) but this could be because several households were commuting on a daily basis to nearby urban locations and this was not captured by the definition of migration used.

  Contrary to dominant perceptions on migration, there was outmigration from the well-endowed villages in Andhra Pradesh; KA and KO showed migration rates of 15% and 10% respectively. These villages have very high levels of land polarisation and mechanisation, and while there is strong labour demand throughout the year for high value, labour-intensive crops, only a certain proportion the substantial landless population gain access to this work. For the rest, migration forms an important coping strategy for at least part of the year.

4.  THE RETURNS FROM MIGRATION

  Income from farm and non-farm work inside and outside the village

  Seasonal migration generated on average a sixth of household income across all villages. Labourers within the villages worked overwhelmingly in agriculture, but outside the village mainly in other occupations. Labourers' earnings inside the village were highest in the case of KO and KA, both prosperous "green revolution" villages, with a large landless class and a predominance of modern, irrigated green revolution technology amongst the landed. KO is also highly diversified, with several non-farm activities and occupations within the village. The lowest earnings were in MD, where there are limited opportunities available locally both in the farm and non-farm sector. This village is drought-prone and backward with hardly any diversification at all. It had the highest average earnings from outside sources, indicating that migration was the main source of earning through both farm and non-farm work. A large proportion of these returns were through high-return sugarcane cutting work, which we treat in detail below.

  Next in rank was VP village in Chittoor, a drought-prone village with active trade links with Bangalore city. Several households in that village engaged in high-return earthwork, a subject that we also cover in detail below.

  Although the earnings from work outside the village were lower in the highly productive coastal villages of KO and KA, there was some low-paid outmigration for farm work by lower caste households that were excluded from local work opportunities. This type of coping migration is also covered below.

Table 2

AVERAGE RETURNS PER HOUSEHOLD PER ANNUM IN AP (RS)


AP villages
    Inside the village     Outside the village
FarmNon-farm TotalFarm Non-farmTotal


OP
3,303 1,0834,386111 339450
VP3,6372,156 5,7933091,396 1,705
KO6,7751,897 8,67214579 224
KA6,352340 6,6920525 525
GU2,6822,877 5,5590731 731
MD3,001504 3,5053,0461,280 4,326
Total4,5381,678 6,216445692 1,137


Source: Household Census, AP


  Since employment through agriculture is the most important source of livelihoods for poor labourers, we analyse the data on agricultural income in some detail below.

The returns from agricultural labouring work inside and outside the village

  Households earn roughly twice the agricultural labouring income within the village compared to outside. Of the in-village component, Kharif earnings are 1.5 times more than Rabi earnings. This could be due to the high labour requirements of paddy, which is the main Kharif crop. This trend is seen in most of the villages, with the exception of VP, where the returns are higher in Rabi and this is most likely because labour-intensive vegetable crops are grown during Rabi and these need even more labour than paddy.

Table 3

AGRICULTURAL LABOUR INCOME INSIDE AND OUTSIDE THE VILLAGE IN AP (RS)


Village
Kharif RabiInside total KharifRabi Outside totalTotal income


OP
1,348 1,2292,577 1,36901,369 3,945
0613 813000 3,188
VP1,3802,078 3,4581,934 2842,2185,676
01,150 2,77500 04,775
KO4,8851,783 6,6682,243 1332,3759,043
2,1500 3,30000 04,925
KA3,2453,037 6,2822,268 02,2688,550
2,4502,200 5,05000 06,575
GU1,943836 2,779892 08923,671
2500 675000 763
MD1,6241,370 2,9942,385 2,5744,9587,952
1,225400 2,2751,4100 2,2755,335
Total2,6181,723 4,3411,814 3632,1776,518
91388 1,97500 03,700


Source: Household Census. Note: Means are in bold and medians in regular font


  Outside the village, the earnings from agricultural labour are nearly five times higher in Kharif compared to Rabi across all villages. But there are sharp variations here: the most backward and dry village, MD, shows high and nearly equal earnings for both Rabi and Kharif, showing that migration is important throughout the year. In other villages, there is little or no earning from agricultural labour outside the village during Rabi, making Kharif the main outmigration season as well as being the main season for in-village employment.

  In-village per household agricultural labouring incomes are highest in the villages with the highest agricultural productivity and output. These are KO, KA and GU. Figures from the most backward and dry village, MD, show high returns from migration during both Kharif and Rabi. But the returns from outmigration were higher in green revolution villages of KO and KA. This shows that despite the many locally-generated work opportunities, those that are excluded from local work still outmigrate for agricultural work.

Table 4

AGRICULTURAL LABOUR INCOME INSIDE AND OUTSIDE THE VILLAGE BY LAND CATEGORY IN AP (RS)


Land Category
Kharif RabiInside total KharifRabi Outside totalTotal income


Landless
4,162 2,0956,257 2,4812472,727 8,985
2,450725 4,5508750 8756,450
Sub-marginal2,413 2,3244,7382,720 2072,927 7,664
1,5001,065 3,7101250 1256,450
Semi-marginal1,445 1,7623,2071,630 8522,483 5,689
1,2001,000 2,7001,2000 1,2004,000
Marginal2,2571,704 3,9611,545 6132,1586,119
1,500650 2,65000 04,000
Small1,8771,775 3,6521,355 3601,7155,367
00913 000 1,900
Semi-medium596 6671,263706 4001,106 2,369
000 000 0
Medium3660 36600 0366
000 000 0
Large00 000 00
000 000
Total2,6181,723 4,3411,814 3632,1776,518
91388 1,97500 03,700


Source: Household Census, AP. Note: Means are in bold and medians in regular font


  The landless derive the highest income from agricultural labour inside the village compared to other classes. The earnings for the landless from in-village sources are nearly three times as much as outside the village. The picture changes as we examine incomes from outside the village, with submarginal farmers earning slightly more than the landless. Medium and large farmers clearly do not migrate out for agricultural work.




5.  WHO MIGRATES AND WHY

  We investigated the determinants of the likelihood of migrating using regression analysis. Our dependent variable is given the value 1 if at least one member of the household migrates during the year, and 0 otherwise. Our explanatory variables are the (log) value of land assets, the (log) value of livestock assets, the (log) value of agricultural assets, three dummy variables corresponding to the different caste groups Scheduled Tribe, Scheduled Caste and Backward Caste (the reference caste group is Other Castes), size of the household and lastly the "inverse dependency ratio" of the household (ratio of working members to non-working members). We estimated the regression using the logit method. We expected that households with more land and assets would be less likely to migrate, and that larger households with a higher inverse dependency ratio would be more likely to migrate. The results were as follows.

Table 5

FACTORS CORRELATED WITH MIGRATION: REGRESSION ANALYSIS RESULTS


Explanatory variable
Effect on likelihood
of migration


Significance level
Land1.070 .359
Livestock0.973 .009
Agricultural assets 1.033.014
ST5.958 .000
SC5.373 .000
BC3.899 .000
Household size1.174 .000
Dependency ratio1.754 .001
Constant0.023 .000
Source: Household Census, AP


  Note: The first column shows the estimated amount by which each explanatory variable affects (in multiplicative terms) the "odds ratio": the likelihood that a household migrates as a ratio of the likelihood it does not. The second column shows the level of statistical significance of each estimated effect. For instance, an increase in (log) agricultural assets by one unit increases the probability that a household has at least one migrating member, relative to the probability it does not, by a factor of 1.033, or 3.3%. This result is significant at the 5% level, but not the 1%.

Do those with land, livestock and agricultural assets stay at home?

  The regression analysis shows that there is a positive relationship between land owned and migration, ie the more the land owned the more the household is likely to migrate. But the results are not significant.

  With regards to livestock, the results show a significant negative relationship, ie those with more animals are less likely to migrate. But as we will see from the case studies, livestock is essential for one kind of migration, namely sugarcane cutting. The results for agricultural assets show that more assets increase the chance of migration but significance levels are not high.

The poorest rarely migrate

  The findings from the regression analysis need to be unpacked further. Cross-tabulation between land class and numbers of households migrating shows that migration among sub-marginal farmers is slightly lower than semi-marginal or marginal farmers. As we shall see from the case studies on migration, a minimum level of material assets is required to make the investment for migration; for travel, purchasing supplies to take to the destination and leaving some money behind for running the household.

Labour-scarce households do not migrate

  The regression analysis shows that the availability of labour within the household is a strong determinant of the likelihood to migrate. Having one extra member in the household increases the relative likelihood of that household migrating by 17%. And an increase in the ratio of working to non-working members in the household also increases the relative likelihood of migration by nearly 75%. Focus group discussions and participatory wealth ranking of migrating households corroborate these findings: labour-scarce households do not migrate.

Higher migration among the STs and SCs

  The regression analysis shows that the Scheduled Tribes are several times more likely to migrate compared to upper castes, followed closely by the SCs who are roughly five and a half times more likely to migrate than OCs, and then by Backward Castes (BCs) who are four to four and a half times more likely to migrate.

  Caste characteristics of migration streams are closely associated with village characteristics and the two reinforce each other, leading to a higher incidence of migration amongst certain castes.

  The regression analysis shows that certain caste categories are more likely to migrate. Taking the Forward Castes (FCs) as the basis for comparison it is seen that STs are nearly six times more likely to migrate; SCs roughly five and a half times more likely to migrate and BCs roughly three and a half times more likely to migrate.

  Further disaggregation of the four broad caste categories is shown in Table 6 below indicates that the castes that had the largest numbers of migrants were the Lambada (ST) at 62%, followed by the BC Artisans with 33.2% households migrating. Next were the two main SCs and the BC cultivators. There was comparatively little migration from upper caste households.

Table 6

MIGRATION RATES BY CASTE


Castes
Number of
HHs
Number of
migrating HHs
% of caste group
migrating
FC-Brahmins53 47.5
FC-Reddy370 205.4
FC-Kapu389 389.8
FC-Kamma250 72.8
FC-Non Brahmin380 205.3
BC-Cultivator1,248 25720.6
BC-Artisan500 16633.2
BC-Service471 35 7.4
SC-Mala457 10422.8
SC-Madiga380 11129.2
ST-Lambada60 3761.7
ST-Others89 77.9
Totals4,647 80617.3
Source: Household Census


  The case studies presented later demonstrate that those castes that are endowed with traditional skills that can be adapted to modern requirements stand the best chance of obtaining high-return work. If skills are acquired over time by working under a skilled person, then this too leads to well-paid and regular work, as is seen in the case of some SC construction workers who have been in the trade for several years. But several lower caste groups, particularly the erstwhile untouchables, are routinely excluded from higher return work because of prejudices held by contractors and employers who may often belong to a different caste. Lower caste people may also lack the assets that are needed for some kinds of high-return work.

  Much of the literature on migration suggests that it is predominantly men who migrate. But in the study villages, household members were found to migrate in various combinations—men only, women only, men and women, men, women and children. In the study villages the majority of migrants were male. Even within villages, some streams had more men migrating whereas others had more women.

  The reasons for this are complex and related to whether or not the skills are gendered, cultural norms to do with women's work and restrictions on women migrating. For example in the case of OP which is near a town, most of the migration is by single people within households, mainly men, for employment in the non-farm sector.

  The gender possibilities for migration are also determined by caste. For higher caste families it was traditionally often shameful for the woman to work outside her home. Lower castes have much less social pressure. Those with spare labour capacity are able to take advantage of these opportunities to create the extra income that can move a household from a deficit to a surplus trajectory.

  As a rule, men-only migration occurred where men possess the required skills or in the early years when the activity is relatively new for the community and the destination areas/work are perceived to be too risky to take women and children along. As the migration stream becomes more established and the working arrangements more predictable, women accompany their husbands or may even start going without them.

Table 7

GENDER PROFILE OF MIGRATING HOUSEHOLDS



Village


Male


Female


Total
% of males in total
migrating individuals
% of females in total
migrating individuals

OP
207 2774.0725.93
VP236164 40059.0041.00
KO146126 27253.6846.32
KA8446 13064.6235.38
GD7557 13256.8243.18
MD683535 1,21856.0843.92

Total
1,244935 2,17957.0942.91



  Source: Household Census

Table 8

AGE AND GENDER OF MIGRANTS WORKING IN FARM AND NON-FARM WORK

By age and gender (No of people) OPVPKO KAGUMD

Farm
Men06 70016
Women03 70014
Children00 000 4
Non-farm
Men013 12114
Women08 0204
Children00 000 1



  Source: Household Census


6.  ACCUMULATIVE AND COPING MIGRATION STREAMS

  A common element in the history of migration in all the locations is the way in which it began—usually as a consequence of the push created by a lack of employment opportunities at home. But different migration streams have evolved differently for different groups of people.

  As a rule, the older, better-established migration streams offer high returns and predictable employment for migrants. These are often streams where stable relations with employers have been built up by particular castes and communities over a long period of time; where specialized skills (often caste-based) are possessed or have been acquired; or where other assets that are needed for migration are available. Well-known examples of this are the legendary "Palamur" labourers from Mahbubnagar district in AP, who are famous for their constructions skills and are employed by the Public Works Department even in far off places, including the Narmada Valley project. Similarly, earthworkers from Chittoor district in AP are migrating to destinations all over south India and also regularly employed by government.

  These kinds of accumulative migration streams have now become a major source of income for many erstwhile poor communities and have significantly contributed to improving their lives through more investment in their farms, houses, children's education and marriages.

  On the other hand are the less rewarding and more risky kinds of migration streams, which involve a more opportunistic search for work. Often, there is no stable relationship with any particular employer. This happens either when the migrants are relatively new, poor and unskilled or when traditional forms of discrimination work against them so that they may never graduate into better-paid work. This is seen in the case of SC migrants working on earthwork projects, who, although working side-by-side with the Vaddi, earn only two-thirds as much as them. SC migrants from the coastal districts are similarly excluded. Even though they live in areas which regularly import labour, they do not get enough work during the peak seasons to tide them over the lean season and are forced to migrate for part of the year.

  We identify six migration "streams" from the study villages in AP, most of which have not been documented before. Table 9 below provides summary information on the different streams. This information was collected through focus group discussions, key informant interviews and participant observation by research officers who were posted in the villages for the entire duration of the study. As the table shows, there can be more than one completely distinct type of migration stream or "option" from the same village.



7.  MIGRATION "STREAMS": ACCUMULATIVE MIGRATION

Sugarcane cutters from Medak district

  MD is a remote village in the backward north-western part of Medak district with unreliable rainfall. Land ownership is still along feudal lines—a Brahman landlord possesses 300 acres of land, demonstrating that land reforms have not made any difference here. The landless account for 13% of the population and marginal farmers, a further 32.5%. Their main occupation is labouring. They are mostly uneducated and unskilled. By caste, the Mudiraj (erstwhile fisherfolk BC) comprise 57% of the village population. Most of them are small and marginal farmers. Next are the Lambada (ST), the Madiga (SC) and Mala (SC). The Mala and Madiga are mainly agricultural labourers, which is testimony to their continuing position of disadvantage in society.

  Migration for sugarcane cutting is said to have begun roughly 30 years ago from MD and surrounding villages, when contractors came to look for cheap labour to cut sugarcane in irrigated parts of the district. What started as a coping mechanism has now become an extremely well-paid alternative to local agricultural wage labour and is attracting more and more households who are able to mobilise the necessary contacts and resources. According to the villagers, more than 40% of the population migrated for this work in 2001. On average, a team of three adult workers will bring back Rs 15,000 as savings from one season's work. These people have accumulated successfully, having large and well-maintained houses, together with the growing numbers of milch animals.

  Migrants usually stay away from October/November for four to six months. The main castes migrating are the Mudiraj, Lambada and Madiga. This kind of migration requires assets in the form of a pair of working bullocks and a bullock cart. Many sugarcane cutters take an advance of roughly Rs 5,000 in the month of June, well before the cutting season. This is usually given by farmers to known parties, therefore social contacts and networks are all-important. This interlocking of credit and labour markets provides the employer with a guaranteed workforce at a predetermined rate. Whether or not the labourer is disadvantaged by this arrangement depends on whether they are in a position to negotiate a good wage. That in turn depends on their access to information about the state of the labour market for that particular season.

  The money from the advance may go towards a new pair of bullocks or cart or other supplies and is repaid the following May after the cutting season is over. These days, there are no middlemen involved. Farmers and labourers deal with each other directly. There is no written agreement and the arrangement works on the basis of mutual trust from previous relationships. Some families have been doing this work for more than 20 years.

  Although this kind of migration is viewed very positively in terms of its economic impact, it has some negative implications too, particularly for children's education. Smaller and younger families face the greatest hardship because they may not have childcare in the village and must take their children with them. The children are not admitted by schools in the destination. In addition to that, households may lose their access to Public Distribution System (PDS) rations if they cannot maintain a presence in the village. A common practice is for one person to come back to the village every month to claim the PDS rations and also give money to relatives at home. In some instances, migrants mortgage their PDS card for Rs 300 with the grain outlet. The dealer claims the rice illegally on their behalf and sells it on the open market. But the arrangement is mutually beneficial because this way the migrants do not lose their entitlement and can reclaim the card when they return.

  Living conditions are rough in the destinations. Migrants stay in the field in a makeshift hut with poor access to water and medical facilities. Social networks are important and migrants help each other in various ways by looking after children and sharing provisions.

  An NGO, Sadhana, has recently started a residential school for the children of migrants from this part of Medak. This has proved very popular among the migrants. The project is being supported by the Hyderabad office of UNICEF as well as the district administration. Children who were previously forced to accompany their parents because there was no one to look after them in the village are now able to carry on with their education.

Earthworkers from Chittoor district

  VP village is in the dry part of Chittoor district and has suffered from drought for the last four years. This area has strong trade links with Karnataka, particularly Bangalore city which is 120 km by road. Only two castes, the Vaddi (BC) and Mala (SC), migrate out for seasonal work. Here we cover only Vaddi migration, which is accumulative. Migration undertaken by the Mala is covered under coping migration.

  The Vaddi, also known as Vaddera, were traditionally skilled stonecutters and well-diggers. They have adapted this skill to digging trenches for telephone cables, graves, desilting tanks and road works and have now become well known all over South India. In rural areas, they have benefited from public works executed by Gram Panchayats and State agencies through schemes for rural water supply, housing, food for work, watershed development, the construction of schools, public buildings and offices. They work almost all year round but the nature of the job varies by agricultural season: desilting of tanks and forest department work is undertaken in the dry season and road works and trench digging is done in the rainy season. Both the poor and non-poor migrate. All of the landless households migrate. In general, there is growing demand for the kind of work that the Vaddi can do but few other castes seem to have been able to join this accumulative stream, a theme we return to under the section on coping.

  Groups of Vaddi relatives (15-30 persons) migrate together and go for 15-30 days at a time. They make 10 such trips in a year. Each group is headed by a mestri (contractor), usually a Vaddi, who bears all travelling and food expenses. The mestri may give an advance to the labourers to send remittances to their family. He later cuts this from the wages of the labourers. There are 12 mestris in the village. Earlier, mestris would be the main source of information about new jobs and wages but over time their power has eroded and they now play a more facilitating role rather than controlling and exploiting labourers. These days most Vaddi do not have fixed mestris and work for the person who makes the best offer.

  The Vaddi have accumulated visibly through migration. Nearly 48% of the Vaddi respondents said that they had built, bought or extended their house. They are also investing their newly acquired wealth into buying land, drilling tubewells and growing vegetables. VP is clearly a village where money is coming in.

  Part of this success stems from their social cohesiveness and collective bargaining power. The Vaddi formed the Narsapur Labour Cooperative Society, a registered society, in 1998. They maintain good relations with local government officials and this has enabled them to win several contracts for public works. There are other manifestations of this social cohesiveness. They have a strong caste-council which has introduced strict rules of behaviour by which everyone must abide. One such rule is the ban on alcohol consumption which was introduced as a way of conserving community wealth. Punishments for those who break the rule are severe—one man was banished from the village for drinking. There is also a rule that all migrants must return to the village at election time and this was said to be behind their recent victory in the local Panchayat elections where they defeated a Yadav caste family that had held power for the previous 37 years. They also have a rule that they must return to the village for major festivals.

  There are negative aspects to the Vaddi migration too. Some of the commonly stated problems are the rough living conditions in the destination where they must live in tarpaulin tents provided by the employers. Many stated that migration adversely affects children's education. Employers and mestris may not pay the promised amount and they may not pay promptly.


8.  MIGRATION "STREAMS" AS A COPING STRATEGY

Construction workers from Medak district

  Several families of poor Mala (SC), landless and marginal farmers who cannot find work locally or grow anything on their land have migrated from MD to urban areas but they have strong links with the village. These people are much poorer than the better-off sugarcane cutters who migrate from the same village. Quite a few of them were not able to enter sugarcane work because they have no collateral for the loans that are required to purchase or hire bullocks and carts. Hyderabad is the most common destination (40 families migrated there in 2001), where they go for construction work. Most of them leave the village around November and return in June to look after their land. But as droughts in the area have become prolonged, some families are leaving their lands fallow and are more or less permanently away and come back only to celebrate festivals. Half of them take their families along. Both women and men work.

  Such migrants work alone or in groups. They are prepared to do any kind of labouring. The construction workers work either under a contractor or freelance by standing at "addas" (on the street) where they try to attract trade. If they work freelance then the men earn roughly Rs 80/day and women earn Rs 60. Although the wages are reasonable, work is not available everyday and most average three working days a week. Women may also work as domestic maids in nearby houses. They spend roughly half of the income at the destination and earn roughly Rs 4,000/year through such work.

  Working under a mestri gives them more days of work but they complain that they are exploited by mestris who take a 15% cut of the wages. Even if such labourers have been in the business for several years they may continue to depend on contractors because they lack the contacts, education and confidence to find work and negotiate contracts. In addition, their caste makes them prone to multiple forms of discrimination so that they can rarely break out of their traditional station of working under someone on exploitative terms. Contractors routinely flout the many regulations that are meant to give migrant labourers security and basic provisions. Several families choose to leave their women behind because living conditions for new migrants in the city are difficult, particularly getting access to drinking water. Accidents, sexual exploitation and disease are major risks.

Agricultural labourers from coastal villages

  KO is a large, well-connected and well-endowed village typical of the better-off villages of the delta zone. It has a characteristically large population of 1,429 households. This reflects the many work opportunities present in the village that have attracted people from outside over the years and also kept the villagers from moving to other destinations. The village is highly developed and there are many amenities, such as a variety of shops including bookshops, dispensaries, pesticide shops, etc. The cropping pattern is normally paddy followed by pulses. The village is a destination for seasonal immigrant labourers who come for three to four months in a year to transplant and harvest the paddy.

  The landholding is highly skewed with over 65% of the population reporting that they are landless. More than 48% of all landless households reported their main occupation to be labouring. There are 29 castes and the most numerous castes are Mala (SC), Madiga (SC), Kapu (OC), Kshatriya (OC), Gowda (BC) and Yadava. (BC) In addition, there are a significant number of Muslim households. The landless are mainly Malas and Madigas, together making up 34.7% of all landless households.

  KA is also a prosperous village with assured canal irrigation which enables farmers to take two paddy crops in a year. Of 464 households, 209 (45%) are landless. There are more marginal and small holdings in this village and therefore the requirement for labour from outside is greater during the peak agricultural seasons. Roughly 1,000 people migrate into the village in July-August and again in November-January to work on the paddy crop, first for transplanting and then to harvest.

  Caste-wise, the Kapu are the largest community, making up nearly half of the population, followed by the Gowda (erstwhile toddy-tappers) who make up just under a quarter of the population at 23.5%. Most landless households are Kapu, followed by Mala, Gowda and Madiga. Most semi-medium, medium and large farmers are Gowda and Kapu. The Mala and Madiga are almost all landless, which is worse than their status in the study villages in other parts of the State.

  In both KA and KO, there are certain times of the year when there is no work for agricultural labourers. During this these times, the landless poor labourers migrate out to find work in nearby areas—either within the district or just beyond. Both men and women migrate and they earn roughly Rs 30/day. Without this work and income, these households would go into debt and have to borrow from local moneylenders, which is what they would have done historically in the lean season. But seasonal migration has offered them an important coping mechanism.

9.  MAIN FINDINGS

  The main findings from this study are summarised in the following points:

    —  A large cost in migration is the search cost and moral hazard of being cheated. Migration options become more and more secure, and thus attractive, over time. For those who have risked going to find new opportunities, and have maintained the link, the investment often pays off.

    —  Migration is increasingly opening up to women, particularly those from lower castes. Often the woman working as well as the man can make the difference between surplus and deficit.

    —  Non-farm work is often better paid, but conditions are poor. The work is hard, and is often taken up in the hot summer when agricultural labour markets are slack. Also, because the nature of the work is often transient, there is not the possibility to form longer-term links as with employers.

    —  All types of migration can bring new skills. Likewise, construction work can often bring access to quarter- and semi-skilled work like masonry work.

    —  The social and domestic trade-offs to migration can be severe. Risk of industrial accident, poor sleeping conditions all bring hazards. If families accompany, then wives, and particularly children, are at great risk from lack of supervision. However, if families migrate together, there are stronger support networks available.

10.  CURRENT INDIAN POLICY

  Migrant workers have not received legislative support or protection because of their legal status because they usually work in unorganized or informal sectors. The Union and State Governments, through their Ministry of Labour and Departments of Labour, have a general mandate for formulating and implementing policies to protect the interests of migrants. Various existing labour laws are "applicable" to the workers in the informal sector. For example the Minimum Wages Act (1948), Equal Remuneration Act (1976), Inter-State Migrant Workmen Act (1979), Contract Labour Act (1970), and Building and Other Construction Workers Act (1996). However, these labour laws are very poorly enforced.

  Migrant labour also comes under the purview of several Ministries or Departments such as Agriculture, Rural Development, Food and Consumer Affairs, Health and Family Welfare and Education and Social Welfare. However, there is no separate department or machinery to address migrants' problems.

  The recently formulated Unorganized Sector Workers Bill (2003), is potentially powerful. Based on the recommendations of National Commission on Labour (2002) and scheduled to be introduced in the Parliament, the Bill includes many provisions that could benefit migrant workers. For example, it seeks to ensure, inter alia, a minimum level of economic and social security, old age benefits, group insurance, medical benefits, registration of unorganized workers and provision of identity cards.

  The proposed legislation though is not free from controversy and some labour unions have already opposed the Bill in the present form and offered several suggestions. Perhaps the most contentious part of the Bill is that the proposed protective measures are in the nature of guidelines for States. It puts the financial onus on the States without delineating the ways and means or allocating funds for the proposed measures. Many observers feel that some crucial proposals could be made mandatory instead of treating them as optional.

11.  RECOGNISING AND SUPPORTING MIGRATION AS A LIVELIHOOD STRATEGY

  Policy needs to recognise that migration is an integral and regular part of livelihood strategies and production systems; that it is also undertaken for high-return employment and not only because of shocks and stresses such as drought i.e. that migration can be accumulative or coping; and is a diverse phenomenon with various non-economic determinants including caste and gender. This reflects wider themes with respect to political-economy determinants of access and opportunity. Regardless of whether migration is accumulative or coping, most migrants receive little support and live in very difficult conditions in their destinations. Although their efforts are the real engine of growth in several sectors, providing a cheap and flexible labour source, they remain without an identity and are unable to claim State resources for education, health care, water and sanitation all the time that they are on the move. Women and children suffer the most from this kind of existence.

  The mainstream view is that migration should be reduced or curbed by creating employment in villages. This is to be achieved through increasing the productivity of dryland agriculture. But it could take several years or even decades for natural resource management and agricultural development programmes to arrest migration, something which they may never achieve where population growth is high. In the meantime, steps need to be taken to support migrants so that their hardships are reduced and they are ensured access to basic needs. For example Mosse et al (2002) argue for a rights-based approach to guarantee minimum wages, avenues for protection and redress, freedom from bondage, sexual exploitation as well as compensation for injury and death suffered by migrant labourers. They call for NGOs, labour unions, State governments and employers to work together to ensure labourers rights (see below). Rogaly et al (2001) advocate public action to address the exclusion of migrants from health education and other social protection.

  The residential school for migrant's children opened by Sadhana is a good example of how NGOs, donors and the State can work together to reduce the vulnerability of migrant labourers. Another initiative that could be explored through multi-stakeholder consultation is providing migrants with computerised identity cards that they can use to access services at their destinations, such as basic healthcare and enrolling their children in the local school. In addition, ways need to be found to ensure that migrants do not lose their entitlements to PDS rations in their homes.

12.  HOW THE UK GOVERNMENT CAN HELP

Migrant Support Programmes[88]

  DFID funded Rural Livelihoods Projects in India have started to experiment with interventions to support migrants. These include the Migrant Labour Support Programme being implemented by the Gram Vikas Trust and the Western India Rainfed Farming Project (WIRFP), Migrant Support and Drought Management Programmes under the Andhra Pradesh Rural Livelihood Project (APRLP), and other joint projects with district governments such as the Western Orissa Rural Livelihood Project (WORLP). Key characteristics of the WIRFP Migrant Labour Support Programme (Mosse 2003) are a rights-based approach defending the legal right to fair wages, freedom from bondage or exploitation through union membership; the focus on immediate practical and welfare needs of highly vulnerable indebted migrants; and an inter-organisation approach which (a) involves simultaneous work in villages of origin and in urban centres of migration; and (b) brings together government, NGOs and unions. Photo-identity cards (not with any formal government status) have been issued MoUs have been negotiated with urban based trade unions and NGOs. such initiatives have made a difference to labourers who face continual police harassment and other exploitative situations. Illiterate people have been issued with pre-written postcards, allowing them to contact their families. The migration support scheme is planning to expand, to include literacy education, and awareness building on HIV/AIDS.

  Both APRLP and WORLP are exploring ways of linking with the DFID Urban Livelihoods programme and NGOs such as Action Aid in Hyderabad, the capital city of Andhra Pradesh which is the destination for most Oriya migrants. It is hoped that these programmes will impact at policy level, influencing State governments to address the problems faced by migrants in securing entitlements across state boundaries; to generate and sustain the interest of municipal authorities, health and labour departments and the police in places of migration; involve elected representatives at the village, Mandal and district levels; work with the construction industry to promote socially responsible business; and promote a self-run network and raise the profile of labour migration.

  It is hoped that these initiatives will be well documented at the DFID policy level so that the government of India can be presented with another poverty reduction option within the "watershed-plus" framework that it is using. It is also anticipated that this policy debate will assist the government to appoint ministerial responsibility for migrants, which is a gap in current policy.

October 2003

REFERENCES

  Deshingkar, P and D Start 2003. Seasonal Migration For Livelihoods, Coping, Accumulation And Exclusion. Working Paper No 220. Overseas Development Institute, London.

  Dev, S M (2002) "Pro-poor Growth in India: What do we know about the Employment Effects of Growth 1980-2000?" Working Paper 161, London: Overseas Development Institute.

  Lee, E S (1966) "A Theory of Migration", Demography 3:1, pp 47-57.

  Mosse, D, Gupta, S, Mehta, M, Shah, V, Rees, J and the KRIBP Project Team (2002) "Brokered Livelihoods: Debt, Labour Migration and Development in Tribal Western India", Journal of Development Studies 38(5): June, pp 59-87.

  Mosse, D "Supporting Rural Communities in the City—The Migrant Labour Support Programme" Consultant report for WIRFP, May 2003.

  Rogaly, B, Biswas, J, Coppard, D, Rafique, A, Rana, K and Sengupta, A (2001) "Seasonal Migration, Social Change and Migrants Rights, Lessons from West Bengal", Economic and Political Weekly, 8 December: 4547-59.

  Skeldon, R (2002) "Migration and Poverty", Asia-Pacific Population Journal, December, 67-82.




84   We define a migration as a specific combination of caste, origin, destination and type of work at the destination. Therefore, a change in any of these four factors would made a different migration stream. Back

85   For a much fuller discussion of the conceptual basis of migration studies, see Deshingkar and Start, 2003. Back

86   Caste in India is based on a traditional Hindu hierarchical system that ascribes occupation to people in different groups. From bottom to top of the hierarchy, there are four broad caste categories: scheduled caste (SC-so-called untouchables), backward castes (BC) and other Castes (OC also known as FC or Forward Castes), plus the Scheduled Tribes (ST) which are outside the traditional hierarchy but are generally placed below SCs. BCs were mainly artisans and farm labourers in traditional agrarian society. Economic, political and social power is concentrated in the hands of OCs. In Andhra Pradesh the BC are numerically the strongest, followed by the OC, SC and then ST. Back

87   Basic information on occupation structures, caste, income and asset ownership was collected through a census survey that covered all households in the study villages of the state. Back

88   This section draws on a RLAG Lesson Learning Brief prepared by Annika Stanley (DFID India), "Social Protection and Rural Livelihoods Programmes in India". Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 29 January 2004