Select Committee on Office of the Deputy Prime Minister: Housing, Planning, Local Government and the Regions Written Evidence


APPENDIX 1

VISUALISING LANDVALUESCAPE: DEVELOPING THE CONCEPT FOR BRITAIN

  Evidence from an ongoing research project by the author that relates to this submission to the House of Commons ODPM Committee Enquiry on Local Revenue:

    I.

    Most experts in relevant fields expect UK to be "value mapped" by 2015. A Policy Delphi (virtual committee) of 29 people43 has been convened for the study. They participate in complete anonymity and without meeting face-to-face and can therefore neither influence (nor be influenced by) each others" individual prejudices. Four types of expert are included: property valuers; spatial analysts; geo-data policy specialists; and land/tax policy specialists. There are also several types of "stakeholders" in the development of value mapping such as: data and software suppliers; urban planners; investors and underwriters; environmental campaigners; business executives; property agents. The Delphi research technique involves three or four iterations of a questionnaire, exposing ideas on the way a complex policy area may develop and seeking views which are then fed back to the group with new information gleaned by the researcher (Vickers 2004b). This was the mean of 21 answers in Round One to the question: "When do you expect Britain to have been value mapped?"

    II.

    e-government projects involving GIS greatly exceed their initial business aims, where they receive strong multi-sector leadership. Examples are the Ordnance Survey digitising programme of the 1980s, the National Land Information Service (NLIS) for on-line conveyancing, and the National Land & Property Gazetteer (NLPG).

    III.

    Joint working between Government departments and agencies on such projects has been greatly hampered by lack of clarity on pricing, licensing and liability policies and by Treasury's insistence, until recently, that data exchanges are "traded" between public sector bodies—even though the data themselves are fully paid-for at point of collection and cannot be "used up". The EU Public Sector Information (PSI) Directive will force limited changes on the UK.

    IV.

    The Valuebill project pilot, which has its national launch in London on 8 June 2004 and uses Value Maps, has enabled the 10 participating local authorities to achieve 100% data matching of NLPG property addresses—crucial to at least 85% of local and central government functions, let alone uses by business and citizens—as a by-product of "finding" some of the 3% of "missing" payers of CT and NDR. The target for Valuebill is to cut the erosion of local government finance, estimated at £825 million per year, by just 25% within six years (Newham London Borough 2004). 44

    V.

    The Acacia Project, aiming to achieve a UK national land management system comparable with that of every other EU and OECD country, 45 has had no funding from Government and looks set to be abandoned, just as Valuebill appears to provide a clear business case for it—even ignoring probable benefits outside the public sector (IDeA 2002).VI.   Modern property tax systems elsewhere cost far less than the UK's46 and produce land values as a by-product, so that even if a country doesn't adopt LVT it can make beneficial use of Value Maps. 47

    VII.

    ODPM's House Price Index, published quarterly since 1968, went monthly in September 2003 (ODPM 2004). This is a direct result of advances in electronic data transfer. It is now easier for mortgage lenders, who supply the data, to transmit 100% rather than the 5% originally requested. This much larger sample (about 70% of all domestic property sales) also includes full postcode and other information about the property and transaction. Statistical analysis can be much more sophisticated and its results are extremely useful to a wide range of people in all sectors. Although ODPM has no plans at present to produce detailed Value Maps, other researchers are looking at this and maps of quarterly trends at local authority level have been produced experimentally from this and Land Registry data. It is possible therefore to derive CT bands or domestic LVT assessments direct from this Index.

VIII.

We spend far more maintaining property tax lists between Revaluations than on doing the Revaluations. The 1990 business rate revaluation cost £130 million, yet the cost to VOA (ie local government's share of the ODPM budget) over five years of artificially correcting property assessments to the 1989 "antecedent date" for changes in the list between 1989 and 1995, plus contesting appeals against assessments, plus adjusting the rate paid by others because of the "leakage" resulting from lost appeals, amounted to about £800 million (VOA 2000)! That takes no account to the costs to taxpayers of employing professionals to contest their side of appeals, or of paying more than they should through "transitional arrangements" to smooth out the changes when a Revaluation occurs! Whilst this is very good income for rating experts (qualified lawyers and surveyors, as well as less reputable "appeal chasers"), would it perhaps have been cheaper—and more equitable—for the nation as a whole, to move to a "rolling revaluation"? The tax rolls could be "frozen" every year at the time councils set their rate. Most independent experts think this is feasible and desirable with a modern valuation system—the kind that also produces land values as a by-product. But Government takes its advice from people with a vested interest in the status quo.

Endnotes

1 When LVT is set by a local authority for its own use, in this country it is termed Site Value Rating (SVR). Other countries that have forms of LVT use different names for it and supporters of LVT never cease to look for names that avoid the impression it refers to "rolling acres"! The value of rural land is insignificant compared to that in towns and cities, except where there is pressure to develop at the urban fringe in areas of expanding population.

2 LVT is usually based on the capital value, not the rental value, of land. Some jurisdictions apply a formula to convert capital to rental value before applying the tax. This author does not regard the debate on whether to use rental or capital value as important at this stage: the choice mainly depends on the nature of the property market and professional practice of valuers who do the work.

3 LVT is never seen by its supporters as a source of additional revenue for governments. It would replace other sources of public revenue and by stimulating economic activity would probably allow a significant reduction in taxation overall, mainly through reductions in benefits and subsidies paid for by taxes. It would be up to the Government which introduced it to decide which other taxes to reduce as it did so: there are many practical and political considerations to be taken account of, some of which are covered later.

4 Many existing taxes and charges include an element of LVT. Even council tax, because it is levied annually and includes land value, has some LVT features. Parking meters, congestion charging, bridge tolls and the business rate are somewhat closer to LVT: they all take account of the relative economic values of locations. The revenue from licensing access to the broadcast spectrum above the UK is a form of LVT!

5 Speaking at a Symposium on 13 May 2004 at the Town & Country Planning Association (TCPA), Ms Barker claimed it was not her but the Treasury who had given her proposal the name Planning Gain Supplement. At the time of writing, no report of this event has been seen but a note has been circulated privately by a TCPA member and local councillor who was there, as was this author (Powell 2004).

6 The "increment" can be negative, eg to land next to a new motorway but far from access to it. LVT provides a means of compensating those whose land values decrease, as well as of financing the infrastructure investment from those whose land values increase.

7 It is not clear how PGS, as opposed to the earlier one-off land taxes such as Betterment Levy, would operate. Planning permission can be awarded to anyone who seeks it and can be opposed by the owner of land. Would the owner have to pay a tax for development that he opposed?

8 One-off charges on transactions in property could continue alongside LVT for some time, even after "full" implementation. The time between acquisition of an option to purchase and realisation of full development value through sale of the finished properties is often far longer than the time suggested here (7-10 years) for introduction of LVT. Therefore considerable "unearned increment" will be "in the pipeline" and available for capture by local authorities through Planning Gain—or by Treasury through CGT. Eventually however these other land taxes should be phased out. Connellan (2004) Chapter 12 and pages 124-125.

9 The International Union for LVT and Free Trade www.interunion.org.uk founded in 1926 became a UN-recognised NGO in 1999. It is based in London although most of its work is developed via sister organisations in North America. In the US, Philadelphia (the fifth largest American city) has just decided to introduce LVT in 2005 (Schaffer 2004).

10 The Scottish Office Land Reform Policy Group (LRPG), mainly in the context of rural policy, called for "a comprehensive economic evaluation of the possible impact of moving in the longer term to an LVT basis" in its final report (Scottish Office 1999), having earlier listed more benefits for LVT than for any other of the 64 policy instruments it looked at (Scottish Office 1998). Different political, legal and technical factors apply in Scotland and will not be pursued further in this paper, except to point out that the Scottish Green Party appears not to have been harmed in its 2003 Parliamentary campaign by featuring LVT among its top five priorities: it went from one to seven MSPs. The Greens are currently drafting a Bill to be debated in the Scottish Parliament, with some support from MSPs in all parties except Conservatives, that promotes LVT as the main source of revenue for Scottish unitary authorities (Scottish Green Party 2004). The constitutional settlement for Scotland allows this to be implemented without reference to London. However although rural land makes up about 87% of Britain's total land area, it represents only about 5% of the total land value, so the burden of LVT would overwhelmingly fall on urban areas (Pickard 2004).

11 In the KPMG report for the UTF, LVT was rated as high as any of the fiscal measures studied (KPMG 1999).

12 This "mixed model" or "split-rate" property tax has been introduced into over twenty cities in Pennsylvania (PA) since 1975 (Hartzok 1997) and is due to be introduced to Philadelphia—the fifth largest city in the US—in 2005. Two cities in Virginia have also petitioned successfully since 2001 to be allowed to move towards LVT in this way. North American property taxes are normally based on a split valuation, with separate assessments of the land and building elements. The author led a multi-disciplinary British study tour of five PA split-rate cities in 2001 (Vickers 2002a).

13 FoE was one of the first organisations to join The Progressive Forum (PF) that year: PF was created on the initiative of the Henry George Foundation of Great Britain (HGF) to bring together those interested in applying "resource rents" to public revenue. A launch event and subsequent study of the attitudes of political parties, lobby groups and think-tanks towards "tax shifting" (off jobs and onto resource usage) was published by PF at a seminar hosted by FoE in London in January 2002 (Oshitani 2002).

14 Muellbauer's paper for HM Treasury states: "One possibility worth serious exploration is a land value tax not on occupied residential property but on all other sites. Property tax reform for homes could then be phased in gradually."

15 See note 1.

16 It is not clear whether voters would understand that responsibility for schools, police, home care (etc) had transferred away from local councils and councillors to some Whitehall Department or unelected regional QUANGO: fifteen years after transferring housing stock to a housing association, West Berkshire Council voters still blame councillors for problems with housing!

17 Disposable income, after taking account of housing costs, varies regionally far less than gross pay. Increasingly those paying a mortgage live in a very different economy to those who have no mortgage debt. Local authority staff confined to national pay-bargaining are increasingly hard to retain or recruit in areas of high land values, as they trade up—and out—as soon as they can afford to, to increase their disposable income and quality of life.

18 Except that differences in housing costs, a reflection of land value differences, increase labour-related costs for councils.

19 This is particularly the case with smaller service-oriented businesses, which cannot balance the higher costs of branches in high-tax local authority areas against lower costs in other parts of the country: there is very limited flexibility in regional location of hairdressers, care homes, estate agents and take-away food shops. Their higher costs are either passed on to the rest of the local economy or they are replaced by identikit national chains.

20 Research in the US shows that for every 1% tax shift off buildings onto land, there is a 16% increase in construction activity. Construction is known as one of the motors of any economy. Economic growth automatically increases the general tax base (Plassman & Tideman 1999) .

21 A 10-minute video Smart BIDs for Britain was produced to show prospective BID stakeholders in focus groups during the author's third and final David C Lincoln Fellowship in LVT (Vickers 2003).

22 Although maintaining tax rolls and billing for council tax and NDR would continue, no planning for full periodic revaluations (next due in 2016 and 2008) would occur until after LVT pilots had been reviewed. The transition from UBR/CT to LVT would involve parallel running of billing systems but only one type of valuation from the date of a national decision on LVT: Valuation Office Agency (VOA) resources would switch immediately: see Valuebill Project below.

23 This is quite a different scenario to that of the Poll Tax, where London imposed its "solution" first, untried, on Scotland, having already decided on implementation throughout Britain.

24 The Local Government Act 2003 gave BIDs a single statutory source of revenue: a supplement to UBR. This was despite a strong campaign, involving some surprising allies, to allow property owners to be tied into BIDs" funding and governance. Campaigners prepared legislative amendments and procedures that could easily be resurrected to allow use of LVT instead of (or in addition to) to current BID levy.

25 Local Government Act 2003 Part IV. Government has promised to review BID funding in 2006.

26 The London Olympic 2012 bid needs to secure a means of funding Crossrail if it is to succeed.

27 Research being undertaken on behalf of ODPM, TfL and RICS has shown that, although it is possible to isolate the core areas influenced by a single transport project, the multitude of other factors influencing property values all the time gives the wider area "fuzziness" of definition (RICS 2004).

28 A conference on the potential of LVT to finance transport infrastructure projects is being held in London on 6 July 2004.

29 At the very time the Thatcher Government was imposing Community Charge on Britain, Brisbane commissioned a study to review its tax system (Brisbane City Council 1989). LVT, which it already used, was concluded to be the most equitable system available, on the basis the beneficiaries of the City's expenditure payed in proportion to benefits received.

30 Findings (Vickers 2003) include:

    —  A national (England & Wales) land valuation could cost no more than the existing periodic valuations for property taxes, over the valuation cycle.

    —  LVT could be phased in, as a full replacement to local property taxes nation-wide, while the 2003 (non-domestic) and 2006 (council tax) valuations and taxes based on them are phased out, over less than 10 years starting with trials as part of the pilot BIDs in several cities. The changeover could be cost-neutral in administration terms.

    —  Business managers overwhelmingly prefer Smart Tax to Business Rates, which they do not understand, and are particularly eager to see it being piloted in BIDs, where they do not believe a voluntary system of owner payments can work.

    —  The Valuation Office Agency's replacement IT system should not be specified until further research has been carried out relating to the need for a parcel-based national land management system and fundamental reform of property taxes.

31 See www.thewaterfront.co.uk/pdfs/current-conferences/oxford.pdf

32 See www.landvaluescape.org/archives/000003.html for more detailed information on this project and links to other research.

33 This is irrespective of any move towards LVT, although the likely conclusion of the study is that Value Maps and LVT will help each other's case: whether LVT justifies Value Maps more than Value Maps justify LVT is a moot point. It is noteworthy that far more countries use Value Maps than have LVT, although almost all countries that have LVT use Value Maps.

34 A more complete list of Questions and Answers on LVT is provided in Questions Around the Smart Tax, an on-line publication of PF now hosted by the HGF website at www.progressiveforum.info/taxbook/ (Vickers 2000b).

35 Both measures could be adopted to ameliorate the hardship of CT as well. It is no accident that LVT supporters usually favour a Citizens Income as well (Robertson 1998).

36 Taiwan, Singapore and some US cities have such "homestead" allowances, in recognition that everyone has a basic human right to a place to live (Tsai 2001). It would be far cheaper to administer than CT benefit, as there would be no need for a means test. The level at which the allowance was set could be such that people living in the most cramped of dwellings paid nothing. Identifying entitlement to the allowance could be achieved by linking each billing authority's property and electoral registers: once both lists were continuously updated, calculation of the net tax liability of each property on the date councils need to set their budgets would be very simple.

37 For pensioners living in larger properties where a tax-free allowance still left a large LVT bill, a deferment option would remove any accusation that LVT was causing genuine hardship: those suffering would be the heirs of the deceased! Where it is used, it seems not to be taken up excessively.

38 Certainly residential property as "investment" would be hit, leading to greater owner-occupation and lower rents under LVT—especially if LVT living-space allowance was only granted to owner-occupiers. LVT liability is to the owner not the occupier. Owners can only pass on as much of the tax as the market can bear: if their tenants leave they retain the full tax liability. The LVT bill could, at least to begin with, be served on the occupier (if there is one), until ownership is known. See Connellan (2004, 128) Annexe 4 for explanation of a method of apportioning liability between the "hierarchy" of "beneficial owners".

39 Some supporters of LVT suggest it should first be applied only to the increment in value above that on a "base date" of the first land valuation. However this would greatly reduce both the initial economic effects and the overall initial tax base of the reform: if LVT was to be an extra tax, it would be justified, but as a substitute for other property taxes it is not. A gradual shift off building value and onto land value, as in Pennsylvania's "split-rate cities", using the whole value, is recommended here too.

40 The basic valuation of a piece of land takes account of its potential to provide wealth and an income stream to its owner. For example, a piece of city centre land designated for public worship alone has a very low value, so the Church will pay little LVT as long as it continues to use that site for that purpose. But should a church organisation be allowed, as in the US, to own very valuable sites that it leases to commercial companies or to wealthy individuals at market rents tax-exempt?

41 A prototype Tax Effect Demonstrator (TED) was developed for the Liverpool LVT trial (Vickers 2003) and is being further developed for the Oxfordshire study, where most land parcels are residential.

42 Adrian Sanders MP (Liberal Democrat, Torbay) in an interview for the magazine Land & Liberty given January 2002.

43 LVT campaigners were excluded from the Delphi Group.

44 Councils have been paying heavily for an inefficient property tax system controlled by Treasury via the Inland Revenue who "own" the data and have hitherto refused to let it be used more widely—even for publicly funded research projects. Councils have also had insufficient money from Government to complete their LLPGs, with many achieving less than the 90% matching of incompatible address list necessary for viability of NLPG.

45 The European Land Information System (EULIS) takes for granted that land values are part of such systems. The EC's INSPIRE initiative (Infrastructure for Spatial Information on the Environment), arising from the Water Directive, will require member states to be able to identify ownership, use, occupier and value of all property by 2010, if accepted by Heads of Government and EP. Otherwise how can claims relating to pollution and land use be settled? The UK is the only state with no comprehensive record of land ownership—let alone land values—at present.

46 For example, Denmark adopted computer-aided mass assessment (CAMA) twenty years ago. Initially the authorities then got rid of 4-5 valuers but then decided to re-engage most of them, so that revaluations could be done every two years instead of every five. This improved equity and collection rates. VOA says CAMA is inappropriate in this country but hasn't justified the claim: Northern Ireland is adopting CAMA for domestic rating in 2007. Denmark's property taxes cost £1.50 per property per year; England's £9.

47 Lucas County, Ohio, has possibly the most advanced Value Maps in the world, used free of charge by residents and businesses who can find everything they need to know about the nature and value of every piece of land and property. It doesn't use LVT but if their system is "down" their switchboard is jammed by property agents who cannot do business (Ward et al 2002).

References and Bibliography

Andelson R V (2000) Land-Value Taxation Around the World, Edition 3. Oxford: Blackwell.

Barker K (2003) Review of Housing Supply: Interim Report. London: HM Treasury.

Barker K (2004) Review of Housing Supply: Final Report. London: HM Treasury.

Brisbane City Council (1989) Report of the Committee of Inquiry into Valuation and Rating. Summary published at http://www.landvaluetax.org.uk/brisbane.htm

Connellan O (2004) Land Value Taxation in Britain: Experience and Opportunities. Cambridge MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Jacobs M (2000) Paying for Progress: A New Politics of Tax for Public Spending. London: Fabian Society.

Evans B & Bate R (2000) A Taxing Question: The Contribution of Economic Instruments to lanning Objectives. London: Town & Country Planning Association.

Hartzok A (1997) Pennsylvania's Success with Local Property Tax Reform: The Split-Rate Tax. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 56(2): 207-214. New York: Robert Schalkenbach Foundation.

IDeA (2002) The Acacia Programme: Memorandum of Understanding 12 Sep 2002. www.idea-infoage.gov.uk London: Improvement and Development Agency.

Jacobs M (2000) Paying for Progress: a New Politics of Tax for Public Spending. Report of the Commission on Taxation and Citizenship. London: Fabian Society.

KPMG (1999) Fiscal Incentives for Urban Housing. Paper for the Urban Task Force. London: Stationery Office.

McLean I & McMillan A (2003) New Localism, New Finance. London: New Local Government Network.

Muellbauer J (2003) Housing, credit and the euro: the policy response. Paper for HM Treasury www.housingoutlook.co.uk/Papers/outlook.pdf

Newham London Borough (2004) Valuebill Project Newsletter No. 2 http://apps.newham.gov.uk/valuebill/

ODPM (2004) A new, experimental, monthly price index http://www.odpm.gov.uk/stellent/groups/odpm—control/documents/contentservertemplate/odpm—index.hcst?n=1618&l=3

Oshitani, S (2002) Towards Sustainable Taxation London: Progressive Forum Pickard D (2004) Lie of the Land. Edinburgh: Land Research Trust.

Plassman F & Tideman N (1999), A Markov Chain Monte-Carlo Analysis of the Effect of Two-Rate Property Taxes on Construction. Journal of Urban Economics.

Powell W (2004) Revenue from Planning Gain (unpublished) email to author 24 May 2004 whpowell@bigfoot.com

Robertson J (1998) Beyond the dependency culture. London: Adamantine Press.

Robertson J (1999) The new economics of sustainable development: A briefing for policymakers. London: Kogan Page.

Rogers R et al (1999), Towards an Urban Renaissance Report of the Urban Task Force, London: E&F Spon.

Schaffer M C (2004) Street presents new city budget. Posted by Philadelphia Inquirer 18 March 2004. http://www.philly.com/mld/philly/news/8218426.htm?1c

Scottish Green Party (2004) Labour follows Green lead on land value taxation. Posted 17 March 2004. http://www.greenparty.org.uk/index.php?nav=news&n=1286

Scottish Office (1998) Land Reform Policy Group: Policy Options. Edinburgh: Stationery Office.

Scottish Office (1999) Land Reform Policy Group: Recommendations for action. Edinburgh: Stationery Office.

Tsai C Y (2001) Land Taxes in Taiwan: Problems, Impacts and Reforms Journal of Property Tax Assessment & Administration 6:3 (81-108).

Vickers A J M (2000), Preparing for Land Value Taxation in Britain Working Paper WP00AV1, Boston MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Vickers A J M (2002) Preparing to Pilot Land Value Taxation in Britain. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Vickers A J M (2002a) Preparing to pilot land value taxation in Britain. Working Paper WP02AV1. Cambridge MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Vickers A J M (2002b) "Shrouded in cobwebs" in Land & Liberty 109:1202(6-9)

Vickers A J M (2003) A Blueprint for Smart Tax in Britain. Working Paper www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/pub-detail.asp?id=861

Vickers A J M (2004b) Visualising Landvaluescape: The Concept in a British Context, Delphi Group Round One Responses Research paper posted 4 April 2004. www.landvaluescape.org/archives/000012.html

VOA (2000) Report of the 2000 Review of the Activities of the Valuation Office Agency. London: The Stationery Office

Ward R, Guilford J, Jones B, Pratt D, & German J (2002) "Piecing Together Location: Three Studies by the Lucas County R&D Section". Assessment Journal September/October 2002 pp21-53.

Whelan J (2003) Funding London's Transport Needs. London: RICS.

RICS (2004) Land value and public transport: stage 2—summary of findings. www.rics.org

Wilks H M (1974) The Rating of Site Values: Update of Report of Pilot Survey at Whitstable. London: Land Institute.

Wilks H M, (1964) The Rating of Site Values: Report of a Pilot Survey at Whitstable. London: Rating and Valuation Association.

Wolf M (2004). "Why on earth not put a tax on land?" in Financial Times 20 February 2004.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 27 July 2004