Select Committee on Office of the Deputy Prime Minister: Housing, Planning, Local Government and the Regions Written Evidence


Memorandum by the Land Value Taxation Campaign (HIS 38)

A.  REPLIES TO THE QUESTIONS

The Campaign wishes to respond to just one of the questions: What fiscal and legislative changes should be made?

  1.1  The Campaign would wish to see a shift from existing taxes to Land Value Taxation (LVT) for numerous important political economic and social reasons. In this overall picture, a relatively minor benefit is that it would give crucial support to policies for the protection of historic buildings and creation and enhancement of public spaces. LVT would both assist conservation positively and allow the removal of existing taxes that actively work against the preservation of our historic buildings and environments.

  1.2  The present tax system is highly detrimental to building conservation and repair. All taxes on such work ultimately have to be paid by the owner of the building, including VAT and taxes paid in the first instance by the builder, including income tax and employees' and employers' National Insurance contributions, and vehicle fuel duty. These taxes comprise about 45% of the cost of the works. The problem is aggravated because a substantial proportion of the tax is charged on labour inputs, and work on old buildings is by its nature labour-intensive.

  1.3  The situation with regard to VAT and listed buildings is perverse, in that new work is exempt but repairs are subject to the tax. This does not encourage owners to protect historic features of old buildings—on the contrary, it is an incentive to destroy.

  1.4  LVT would actively promote conservation, both in urban and in rural areas. This may be seen by considering how LVT would operate in relation to Conservation Areas. Local planning authorities have a statutory duty to identify and designate as Conservation Areas those locations which it is considered should be preserved and enhanced. Within Conservation Areas, consent is required for demolition, and planning applications for new development are submitted to specialist advisory committees.

  1.5  Unfortunately, legislation has had only limited success in preventing the destruction of historic areas, and the erection of harmful developments. In some cases, owners of listed buildings have neglected them to the point where demolition has become the only option, and have then exerted pressure on local authorities for consent to redevelop and intensify the use of their sites. In other circumstances, pressures for relaxing conservation provisions have built up because land values were approaching a peak in the boom-slump cycle.

  1.6  LVT would increase the protection given to designated historic buildings and areas, and trees protected by preservation orders, because it would reduce the pressure for development within them. Valuations would reflect the advantages and restrictions of such designation, and because the tax would be payable regardless of whether the building was in use or not, the neglect of listed buildings mentioned in the previous paragraph would become uneconomic.

  1.7  A system of LVT would therefore automatically compensate for any economic disadvantages from having to protect particular buildings, trees, or wildlife habitats, or sites of archaeological importance; with LVT at a sufficiently high rate, owners would have no incentive to overturn the protected status of their land.

B.  FURTHER EXPLANATORY COMMENTS

1.  AIMS OF THE LAND VALUE TAXATION CAMPAIGN

  1.1  The Land Value Taxation Campaign is a non-party organisation which was established with the aim of securing legislation which would fundamentally change the basis of public revenue in the United Kingdom. It proposes that existing taxes on wages, goods and services should be progressively replaced with a property tax on the rental value of all land. This is referred to as land value taxation (LVT). The policy advocated by the Campaign would ultimately secure 100% of the rental value of land[44]for the Exchequer, but it is recognised that, as with any radical change in the tax system, a transition period would be desirable. The Campaign therefore accepts that the introduction of LVT would be phased in a series of deliberate steps.

  1.2  Although the Campaign was established to promote the case for a national land value tax, we would point out that, as is the case with all forms of property tax, LVT is suitable for all tiers of government and could be readily adapted to any multi-tiered structure including devolved bodies in Scotland, Northern Ireland, Wales, London, and any future English regional assemblies, as well as existing local authorities.

2.  SUMMARY

  2.1  Existing taxes act as a deterrent to the repair of old buildings.

  2.2  By imposing a cost on land holding, LVT would encourage owners of historic buildings to keep them in optimum use, or to pass them on to somebody else who would do so.

  2.3  But because land value tax assessments would automatically reflect restrictions on the use of land resulting from designation of the land itself or structures upon it, a system of LVT would therefore automatically compensate for any economic disadvantages from having to protect particular buildings, trees, or wildlife habitats, or sites of archaeological importance; with LVT at a sufficiently high rate, owners would have no incentive to overturn the protected status of their land.

  2.4  To promote policies designed to protect historic buildings and enhance urban spaces, the Campaign therefore urges that all land in the United Kingdom should be valued frequently and accurately, in accordance with its optimum use within the current planning regulations, and made subject to an ad valorem land value tax, with existing taxes being phased out as quickly as practicable.

3.  THE COMPENSATION/BETTERMENT MECHANISM INHERENT IN LVT

  3.1  Under a system of LVT, the valuation would be based on the full rental value of the site, at its optimum permitted use. Thus, increases in land value (betterment) arising from planning decisions such as the creation and enhancement of urban spaces would automatically be collected as a revenue stream, along with existing land values and betterment arising from all the other causes which influence land values.

  3.2  Furthermore, the system would contain a built-in compensation mechanism. Where the value of land was depressed by—for instance—planning blight, traffic noise, or the presence of listed buildings or other restrictions on its use, this would naturally be reflected in the valuation, and the landowner would be relieved accordingly.

  3.3  Thus, LVT is a payment for benefits actually received, and falls only upon values which can be enjoyed or realised. If planning restrictions prevented more intensive or rent-enhancing use, eg, requiring preservation of a building or other structure, or limiting a piece of land to use as a golf course, or for agricultural purposes, the land value would be assessed accordingly. The introduction of LVT would not conflict with the existing system of planning controls; on the contrary, it would greatly reinforce the planning process by removing, or at least reducing, the financial incentive for overturning restrictions on development contained in existing statutory plans, such as listing and Conservation Area designation.

4.  FOR FURTHER INFORMATION

  4.1  The London Rating (Site Values) Bill of 1938-1939 is an example of model LVT legislation. This would obviously have to be updated and adapted to suit present circumstances and to conform to the law in Scotland and Northern Ireland. Copies are available or may be downloaded.

  4.2  The URL is http://www.landvaluetax.org.uk/1939bill.htm

  4.3  Proposals for a transition from existing local taxes to a land-value based system are set out in the Campaign's publication "Options for Property Tax Reform. Copies are available or may be downloaded.

  4.4  The URL is http://www.landvaluetax.org.uk/lvtprpsl.htm

  4.5  Following a comprehensive study of local taxation, commissioned in 1986 by Brisbane City Council and chaired by Sir Gordon Chalk, KBE, LlD, formerly deputy premier of Queensland, a report was published in 1989 in which the committee strongly recommended that the city keep its existing system, based on site values. This is essentially the stance advocated by the Land Value Taxation Campaign. A copy of the summary of the Chalk Committee's two-volume report is available on request or may also be downloaded; http://www.landvaluetax.org.uk/brisbane.htm

  4.6  The interrelationship between land value taxation and planning was discussed in a submission to the Royal Town Planning Institute.

  4.7  The document may be downloaded; http://www.landvaluetax.org.uk/planning.htm

5.  APPENDIX

The Royal Infirmary Edinburgh: A Case History

  "Although the Royal Infirmary sits in the very centre of the capital, and covers 25 acres in a prime area for redevelopment, the site, which could be worth £50 million, is unlikely to be sold for more than £10 million" (George Hume, The Herald, 14 January). "The factor acutely depressing the value of the site . . . is a battery of A and B category listings by Historic Scotland on buildings covering almost the entire hospital. Demolition is out of the question". The main block was completed in 1879, but there have been numerous later additions. In the circumstances, refurbishment is the order of the day, for whatever uses can best be made of the different parts.

  If LVT were fully operating, the listed site would yield, say, £0.5 million per year. The cleared site would bring in £2.5 million. The brutal question facing politicians, planners, and public would be whether preserving the Royal Infirmary buildings is worth foregoing £2 million per year. Looked at the other way round, with LVT fully operating and site rental revenue replacing presently levied taxes, the occupier of Edinburgh's Royal Infirmary location would be assessed on the assumption of optimum permitted use. If the present structures have to be preserved, he would pay £2 million per year less than if he had a free hand. This is compensation for following public policy. He would receive no rebate if he were to allow a building to fall into disrepair—still less if he were to vandalise it so as to render it unusable! Thus he would have every incentive to preserve the property in top order and maximise his income from it, which is presumably what Historic Scotland wishes.

Henry Law

Land Value Taxation Campaign




44   The term land is used here not in its legal sense but is given its meaning as defined in political economy, ie "that part of the material world other than human beings and the products of their labour". Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 26 January 2004