Price caps
67. The price cap of 1% on Sandler products originally
proposed was fiercely criticised by some witnesses before our
inquiry. Ms Francis, Director General of the ABI, told us that
"At 1 per cent the UK would be unique in the world in the
low level of fees that were charged. Every other country that
you compare with, including countries such as Australia, have
a higher charge
you do need some additional charging up-front
to enable you sensibly to cover the cost of advice, information
and so forth." [204]
Others within the industry were more positive and Invesco noted
that "products priced at less than 1% already exist and have
enjoyed growing market share throughout the 1990s."[205]
68. Many of those opposed to the 1% price cap pointed
to what they viewed as the disappointing experience of stakeholder
pensions. Prudential told us "we believe that the aim of
promoting and selling Sandler stakeholder products would not be
achieved in a 1 per cent regime
We urge the Treasury to
relax the 1 per cent charge cap to allow the industry to promote
and distribute Stakeholder pensions effectively."[206]
Others, however, took a dramatically different view of the success
of stakeholder pensions. The National Consumer Council, for example,
observed that "over 1.5 million consumers (on a variety of
incomes) of stakeholder pensions are now building up savings in
a low-cost, flexible product. In addition, millions of consumers
who continue to save in personal pensions have benefited from
the general reduction in charges that followed the introduction
of stakeholder pensions. Similar downward pressures on charges
across the market might follow the introduction of the other stakeholder
products."[207]
The evidence we heard from the Building and Civil Engineering
Benefits Schemes (B&CE) illustrated the success of some organisations
in selling stakeholder pensions with a 1% price cap. They told
us "We will be able to live within the 1% cap
This
partnership between employers and individuals in the construction
industry has given B&CE an advantage. But we believe that
innovative commercial providers should have, from the outset,
been looking to work with employers and unions in the manual industries
to build a joint approach to pension provision."[208]
The B&CE went on to suggest "the financial services industry
as a whole has failed to rise to the challenge of the 1% world."[209]
69. Alongside the new basic advice regime the Treasury
announced that it was setting the price cap for Sandler products
at 1.5% for the first ten years, reducing to 1% thereafter. This
announcement has been welcomed by many in the industry. HBOS plc,
for example, wrote to us that they believed "that a 1.5%
annual charge is realistic" and that the decision "will
increase access to advice and products
[which can]
only
be good for consumers."[210]
70. The Treasury also announced that the 1% price
cap for stakeholder pensions would be raised to 1.5%. The Financial
Secretary told us that the extra 50 basis points on the price
cap above Mr Sandler's proposals was a "charge explicitly
for advice but only for the first ten years" and that "returns,
over a period of 25 years say, are virtually identical to [those]
if you charged one per cent the whole way through."[211]
The Financial Secretary went on to tell us that for those with
stakeholder pensions already "We very much expect that the
industry will retain their current charging structures. We will
be negotiating this closely."[212]
We also asked the Financial Secretary if she had considered linking
charges more explicitly to performance and she told us that the
fact that there was no up-front fee or exit penalty was a good
incentive for the industry to deliver good returns in order to
encourage client retention.[213]
71. The Committee notes the 1.5% price cap set
on the first ten years of non-cash Sandler products and notes
also that the advice component of the new products is higher than
that proposed by Mr Sandler when he recommended a 1% price cap.
We are disappointed, however, that part of the charge is not more
clearly linked to the investment performance of the products.
Given that the higher charges for stakeholder pensions are explicitly
for additional advice in the selling process, it would clearly
be unfair for product providers to levy the higher charge on existing
stakeholder pension contracts. We expect the Government to monitor
charges on existing contracts very closely as the new stakeholder
charges are introduced.
The price cap setting process
72. As well as ensuring reasonable charges to the
consumer, price caps on regulated products can help improve the
efficiency of the industry by encouraging low cost producers and
placing additional pressure on others to lower their costs. Mr
Sandler indicated that "improving the efficiency of the industry
presents a considerable challenge. Consumer weakness and the absence
of meaningful incentives from within the industry to address inefficiencies
mean that, without some form of external intervention, persistence
of the status quo is inevitable. Such intervention is unlikely
from the FSA, whose remit as regards consumer protection does
not, in practice, extend to a concern about industry efficiency
considerations and levels of charges."[214]
The current system of setting price caps by Ministerial announcement
has been criticised, however, for its lack of openness and vulnerability
to lobbying. Ms Johnstone, Director of Policy at the National
Consumer Council (NCC), told us "a price cap is a kind of
economic regulation and you have to set it properly with proper
economic analysis on a basis of fact. At the moment it is just
who can shout the loudest; it appears to be just about lobbying
and that is a hopeless way".[215]
The NCC pointed out: "A rigorous, analytical framework is
needed to make decisions of this nature. Ministers and government
departments are not responsible for setting price-caps in other
sectors, such as telecoms or energy. Decisions in these sectors
are now made by independent regulators based on extensive research,
open consultation and clear time-frames."[216]
73. Regulated price caps for regulated products
in the financial services industry serve the dual role of guaranteeing
the client the price he will pay and putting additional pressure
to improve efficiency on an industry where consumer weakness has
reduced the normal competitive pressures to drive down costs.
But caps set too low can reduce product range and stifle new product
development, thus limiting real choice for consumers. Where such
caps are to be set, it would be preferable if they were set by
an independent body after clear and transparent analysis. The
price cap should be consistent with fair returns to both savers
and the most efficient producers in the industry but should maintain
downward pressures on the cost base of less efficient producers.
195 Medium and Long-Term Retail Savings in the UK,
A Review, HM Treasury July 2002, page 23 Back
196
ibid., page 24 Back
197
Q 1762 Back
198
HC 275, Ev 146 para17.1 Back
199
HC 275, Ev 123 para 32 Back
200
Q1452 Back
201
HC 275, Ev 153 para 5.6 Back
202
HC Debates, 17 June 2004, col 53WS Back
203
HC 71-II, Ev 357 para 16 Back
204
Q 66 Back
205
HC 275, Ev 135 para 4.5 Back
206
HC 275, Ev 165 paras 5 and 9(g) Back
207
HC 275, Ev 161 para 25 Back
208
HC 275, Ev 71 para 19 & 21 Back
209
HC 275, Ev 71 para 18 Back
210
See list of Memoranda placed in the Library of the House and in
the parliamentary Record Office p. 78 (Memorandum by HBOS) Back
211
Q 2131 Back
212
Q 2137 Back
213
Q 2193 Back
214
HC 275, Ev 179 para 5 Back
215
Q 1518 Back
216
HC 275, Ev 161 para 27 Back