Select Committee on Work and Pensions Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by CARE (CP 17)

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  1.  The Government has pledged to halve child poverty by 2010. It has set a PSA target to reduce by a quarter by 2004 the number of children living in households with equivalised income below 60% of the contemporary median—this target is based on the 1998-99 Household Below Average Income (HBAI) tables.

  2.  In 1998-99 4.2 million children lived in households with equivalised income of less than 60% median after housing costs (AHC). To achieve the PSA target, this figure must be reduced to 3.1 million by 2004, but by 2001-02 it had been reduced to only 3.8 million. The rate of reduction looks likely to be insufficient to enable the target to be met by 2004; to enable it to be met shortly thereafter, and for the longer term target to be met, the reduction must be speeded up.

  3.  Of those 3.8 million children living in poverty in 2001-02, 1.7 million lived in lone parent households and 2.1 million children in couple households. But there was a marked difference between the two groups. Whereas 80% of the children in poverty of lone parents lived in workless households, the comparable figure for children of couples was 30%. In other words, the problem of child poverty is primarily one of workless lone parents and of couples in work.

  4.  The focus of many of the Government's measures has been to reduce the number of children living in poor workless lone parent families. Insufficient attention appears to have been given to the problem of poor in-work two parent families. Unless the equivalised incomes of these families can be increased, it is difficult to see how the 2004 target can be met—let alone the 2010 target.

  5.  The reason why the new tax credits, like the previous credits, do not lift an in-work two parent family out of poverty whereas they do so for most in-work lone parent families is that they are not designed to target couples with low equivalised income—the measure of income used for the PSA target. The formula used to calculate equivalised income takes account of the number of adults in the family whereas the tax credits do not do so except for the purposes of calculating a couple's income. Moreover, many in-work families living below the poverty line do not get the full benefit of the tax credits because of the taper.

  6.  Unless structural changes are made to the tax credit regime, it seems unlikely that the Government can meet poverty targets expressed in terms of equivalised income. What is needed is not only additional expenditure but better focussed expenditure. This means doing something for two parent families in work but living below the poverty line.

  7.  One possibility would be to increase the couples element in the Working Tax Credit: an alternative would be a higher taper threshold for couples. Any proposal must be cost effective, i.e. it must be judged against the likely impact on the number of children living in poor families: either of these measures, while costly, would significantly reduce the number of children living in poor in-work couple families. The child element within the Child Tax Credit could also be increased for teenagers in order to bring some families with teenage children out of poverty.

INTRODUCTION

  1.  The Government has pledged to end child poverty within 20 years and to reduce it by half by 2010. It has a Public Service Agreement ("PSA") target to reduce child poverty by a quarter by 2004, ie to reduce by a quarter the number of children in low-income households (below 60% of contemporary median household income (Great Britain))[191].

  2.  The Department of Work and Pensions ("DWP") has stated[192] that the PSA target is explicitly based on the 1998-99 Household Below Average Income ("HBAI") baseline figures and methodology so that this target would not be subject to any methodological change. HBAI presents figures both on a before housing costs ("BHC") and after housing costs ("AHC") basis and, until this year, including and excluding the self-employed. Ministers have normally used the AHC figures[193]. and the figures in this paper are on this basis unless otherwise stated.

  3.  In its response to the April 2002 Consultative Paper on measuring child poverty, the DWP accepted that income—and particularly relative income—was central to any approach to measuring poverty although, of course, it is not the only element. Access to education, decent housing, good quality health services and a safe environment, as well as income, all affect the quality of a child's opportunity.

  4.  The Government has introduced a range of measures aimed at reducing the number of children in low-income households. For those in work—and they are the focus of this memorandum—tax credits are the principal instruments for raising the income of low income families. For 2002-03 and earlier years these were the Working Families Tax Credit and the Children's Tax Credit; for 2003-04 and later years they comprise the Working Tax Credit ("WTC") and Child Tax Credit ("CTC"). However none of these credits are particularly well structured to reduce the number of children living in poverty, and it seems unlikely that the Government will be able to achieve its PSA target without making structural changes to the new tax credit regime. The projected cost of tax credits in 2004-05 is £14.9 billion and in 2005-06 £16.3 billion[194].

HBAI FIGURES

  5.  It is necessary to look at the HBAI figures in some detail in order to understand the difficulty the Government is likely to have in meeting the 2004 PSA target or its more ambitious longer term targets, even though it is planning to spend over £16 billion pounds on tax credits.

  6.  HBAI measures household disposable income. The assumption is made that all individuals in the household benefit equally from the combined income of the household. Income before housing costs (BHC) for this purpose is taken as comprising:

    —  net earnings from employment or self employment;

    —  all Social Security benefits (including Housing Benefit and Council Tax Benefit) and tax credits;

    —  pensions;

    —  investment income;

    —  maintenance payments received directly;

    —  educational grants;

    —  cash value of certain income in kind, eg free school meals.

  Income is net of:

    —  income tax;

    —  national insurance contributions;

    —  domestic rates/council tax;

    —  pension contributions;

    —  maintenance payments.

  Income after housing costs (AHC) is derived by deducting the following:

    —  rent (gross of Housing Benefit);

    —  rates;

    —  mortgage interest payments (capital repayments are not taken into account);

    —  structural insurance premiums;

    —  ground rent and service charges.

  7.  Household weekly income is then adjusted to take account of the size and composition of the household. Income adjusted in this way is called "equivalised income". The DWP explains[195] that the adjustments reflect the common sense notion that a household of five will need a higher money income than a single person living alone to enjoy the same standard of living. Household money income is either increased or, more generally, decreased in accordance with long established standard scales (McClements scales). To give an example, the AHC equivalence value for a household consisting of a married couple with two young children (aged one and three) would be 1.25 (0.55+0.45+0.07+0.18). Net weekly income for this household is then divided by 1.25 to arrive at the measure of equivalised household income. Two separate scales are used—one for income before housing costs (BHC) and one for income after housing costs (AHC). The scales used are set out at Appendix 1 together with details of the Modified OECD scale.

  8.  In 1998-99 4.2 million children were living in households (including the self employed) with equivalised income after housing costs below 60% of median. The DWP has advised that this figure breaks down as follows:


Number of children
millions

Lone parent households
1.82
of which
in full time or part time work
0.37
not working
1.45
Couple households
2.42
of which
one or more parents are in full time or part time work
1.63
(including self employed)
not working
0.79



  9.  In 2001-02 there were 3.8 million children living in households (including the self employed) with equivalised income below 60% of median. This figure breaks down as follows:


Number of children
millions

Lone parent households
1.70
of which
in full time or part time work
0.36
not working
1.35
Couple households
2.11
of which
one or more parents are in full time or part time work
1.45
(including self employed)
not working
0.65



  It can be seen that in 2001-02, of the 2.1 million children living in poor two parent families, 70% lived in households in which one or more of the parents were in paid work and therefore potentially entitled to the full range of tax credits. Of the 1.7 million children in poor lone parent families only 21% were in families where the parent worked. Looked at another way, almost 80% of the children in poverty whose parent or parents work lived in two parent families. A similar picture is presented by the BHC figures—the BHC percentage is 84%[196]. It will also be seen that the number of children in poverty in lone parent households has scarcely fallen since 1998-99. The reasons for this are not entirely clear—there are a number of possibilities. The parent may not be working 16 hours a week or may have savings in excess of £6,000. In both cases this would result in an in-work family not getting tax credits in the years concerned. Another possibility is that these are families with teenaged children (see para 26)

  10.  As the Institute of Fiscal Studies (IFS) has pointed out[197], in 2001-02 the Government was less than half way towards meeting its target. To achieve the PSA target, the number of children living in low-income families (as defined) would need to come down to 3.1 million. When the last set of HBAI figures were published, the IFS said that, if the rate of decline in child poverty observed since 1998-99 continued for three more years, the Government would miss its target.

WHY THE GOVERNMENT MAY MISS ITS TARGET

  11.  The focus of many of the Government's measures to reduce the number of children living in poor families has been children living in workless lone parent families. This is understandable given the significant increase in the number of workless lone parent families in the eighties and nineties and the fact that children are at a greater risk of being in poverty if they live in a lone parent household than if they live in a two parent household. As, however, the above figures show, there are more children living in poor two parent households than in poor one parent households. The evidence we present below suggests that insufficient attention has been given to the problem of poor in-work two parent families and as a result the Government may have difficulty in meeting its PSA 2004 target. It is difficult to see how it can reach, let alone go beyond, this target in later years without dealing with the problem of in-work families who, not withstanding the new tax credit regime, will have equivalised incomes below, often well below, 60% of median. The present mix of policies seems unlikely to reduce this number significantly.

  12.  The great majority of children living in poor lone parent households are in households where the parent does not work. As, however, the Committee's report "Childcare for Working Parents"[198] showed, many lone parents still find it difficult to take up paid work. Childcare problems are clearly one factor, but for some the gains from moving off benefits and into paid work can be modest and, when childcare costs are taken into account, the lone parent can actually be worse off. It seems unlikely therefore that, despite the welfare to work policy, the number of children in workless lone parent households is going to come down quickly. If, however a lone parent with two young children is able to work 16 hours a week, the tax credit regime should in most cases lift the family above the official poverty line.

  13.  The position with two parent families is different. The great majority of children living in poor two parent families are living in households where one or both parents work. The problem the Government faces in reducing the number of children living in poor two parent families is that, even when the parent works, many of these families are still in poverty even at relatively high pre-tax incomes. For them tax credits do not deliver enough income to raise their equivalised income above the 60% median. On the other hand, this does mean that, if it wished, the Government could take these families out of poverty by appropriate changes to the tax credit regime. It is not dependent on action by the family.

  14.  Table 1 below shows the equivalised incomes of families selected for analysis in the DWP's Tax Benefit Model Tables for June 2001 and compares this with the HBAI figure for 60% of median equivalised income (AHC) for 2001-02. The figures are the amount in pounds by which the weekly household equivalised income is above or below the 60% median—negative numbers are in bold type. For example, a lone parent family with one child aged one living in local authority housing and earning £90 per week would have had in 2001-02 an equivalised income of £56 above the poverty line. By contrast a married couple family with one child earning £90 per week would have had an equivalised income of £28 below the poverty line.

Table 1

DWP TAX BENEFIT MODEL FAMILIES 2001-02; EQUIVALISED INCOME IN POUNDS ABOVE OR BELOW 60% MEDIAN (AHC)


Gross weekly earnings (£)
Family Type
90
100
150
200
250
300

Lone parent one child aged 1

(LA tenant)

(Table 1.2a)

56
61
93
119
143
168
Lone parent one child aged 1

(private tenant)

(Table 1.2.e)

56
59
70
79
88
111
Lone parent two children aged 2 and 4

(LA tenant)

(Table 1.3.a)

21
23
45
62
79
96
Lone parent two children aged 2 and 4

(private tenant)

(Table 1.3e)

21
23
31
37
43
48
Married couple one child aged 1

(LA tenant)

(Table 1.5a and b)

-28
-27
-8
5
21
36
Married couple one child aged 1

(private tenant)

(Table 1.5c and d)

-28
-27
-12
-7
-2
3
Married couple 2 children aged 2 and 4(LA tenant)

(Table 1.6a and b)

-33
-33
-19
-7
4
15
Married couple 2 children aged 2 and 4

(private tenant)

(Table 1.6c and d)

-33
-33
-21
-17
-13
-10
Married couple 3 children aged 8,10 and 12

(LA tenant)

(Table 1.7a and b)

-42
-42
-28
-19
-10
-2
Married couple 3 children aged 8,10 and 12

(private tenant)

(Table 1.7c and d)

-42
-42
-32
-29
-26
-23


Data source: DWP Tax Benefit Model Tables June 2001, references are to the DWP tables. None of the published DWP tables for lone parents take account of the 30-hour credit.

  15.  Two points stand out. The first is that if a lone parent was able to work 16 hours a week (this was a necessary condition for the WFTC), the tax credits lifted the family out of poverty, as defined. To this extent the WFTC will have achieved one of its objectives. The second point is that the WFTC failed to lift comparable two parent families above the 60% line even if the parent were in work. Even at £300 three of the ten families selected for analysis by the DWP had incomes below the 60% figure. The Table 1.7d family (ie a married couple family with three children aged eight, 10 and 12 living in private tenanted accommodation) would have needed to earn £480 a week (£24,960 pa) to have an equivalised income in 2001-02 of more than £165 per week.[199] This admittedly might be regarded as an extreme example.

  16.  Tables 1 and 2 deal only with one earner couples because that is what the DWP Model Tables deal with. Figures for a two earner couple in 2003-04 are given below.

Do the New Tax Credits Solve the Problem?

  17.  Changes have, of course, been made to the tax, tax credit and benefit systems since 2001-02. In particular:

    —  An enhanced children's tax credit (so called "baby credit") was introduced in April 2002

    —  There was a £2.50 increase in the WFTC basic credit in June 2002.

    —  Child benefit was increased.

    —  New tax credits were introduced in April 2003.

    —  Under the new regime the child related credits are not conditional on a parent working a minimum number of hours.[200]

  These changes have not, however, changed the picture much. Table 2 below shows the position in 2003-04 for families selected for analysis in the DWP Tax Benefit Model Tables for June 2003. We have assumed that the contemporary 2003-04 figures for 60% median equivalised income after housing costs will be £181. The DWP has told us that this is not an unrealistic estimate.

Table 2

DWP TAX BENEFIT MODEL FAMILIES 2003-04; EQUIVALISED INCOME IN POUNDS ABOVE OR BELOW 60% MEDIAN (AHC)

Gross earnings (£)
Family Type
90
100
150
200
250
300

Lone parent one child aged 1(LA tenant) (Table 1.2a)
54
59
89
113
137
161
Lone parent one child aged 1(private tenant) (Table 1.2.e)
54
58
68
77
85
94
Lone parent two children aged 2 and 4(LA tenant) (Table 1.3.a)
20
22
37
54
70
87
Lone parent two children aged 2 and 4(private tenant) (Table 1.3e)
20
22
29
35
41
47
Lone parent two children aged 14 and 16 (LA tenant)
-30
-28
-7
5
18
30
Lone parent two children aged 14 and 16 (private tenant)
-30
-28
-13
-9
-4
0
Married couple one child aged 1(LA tenant) (Table 1.5a and b)
-34
-33
-17
-3
11
25
Married couple one child aged 1(private tenant) (Table 1.5c and d)
-34
-33
-19
-15
-10
-5
Married couple 2 children aged 2 and 4(LA tenant) (Table 1.6a and b)
-37
-36
-25
-18
-7
-4
Married couple 2 children aged 2 and 4(private tenant) (Table 1.6c and d)
-37
-36
-25
-23
-19
-16
Married Couple two children aged 14 and 16 (LA tenant)
-63
-62
-53
-48
-39
-30
Married Couple two children aged 14 and 16 (private tenant)
-63
-62
-53
-52
-49
-45
Married couple 3 children aged 8,10 and 12 (LA tenant)(Table 1.7a and b)
-45
-44
-35
-30
-21
-13
Married couple 3 children aged 8,10 and 12 (private tenant)(Table 1.7c and d)
-45
-44
-35
-34
-31
-28



Source: DWP Tax Benefit Model Tables April 2003

  It will be seen that for most families the position has actually deteriorated since 2001-02. A lone parent living in local authority housing with one child aged one who works 16 hours a week earning £4.50 per hour would have an equivalised income in 2003-04 of £228, ie £47 above the estimated contemporary 60% median and a lone parent with two children aged two and four would have an equivalised income of £197, ie £16 above.

  18.  The DWP tables do not enable comparisons to be made where there is more than one earner in the family. The equivalised income of a two earner couple will be higher than that of a comparable single earner. However, the difference will not be as great as might be expected because the income tax and national insurance saving will to a significant extent be clawed back by a cut in Housing Benefit and Council Tax Benefit. For example, a single earner married couple with two children aged two and four living in private tenanted accommodation on an income of £200 a week, would have equivalised income of £158 ie £23 below the estimated contemporary 60% median. Even if the income of the couple was split 50:50, their equivalised income would increase to only £165 and would still be £16 below the 60% median.

  19.  The negative figures in Table 2 do not reveal the full extent of the problem the Government faces. Where a family has a McClements factor of more than 1, its income will need to be increased by more than the amount by which its equivalised income falls below the 60% median. For example, Table 2 shows that a married couple with two children aged two and four living in local authority housing and earning £90 per week is likely to have in the current year an equivalised income of £37 below the 60% median. The McClements factor for this family is 1.36. To raise this family's equivalised income to the £181 per week (estimated contemporary median) would need a cash increase of £50 (£37x1.36). Table 3 below shows the increases which Table 2 families with equivalised incomes below the estimated contemporary 60% median would need to bring them up to that level.

Table 3

INCREASE IN WEEKLY INCOME REQURIED TO LIFT POOR TABLE 2 FAMILIES TO ESTIMATED CONTERMPORARY 60% MEDIAN


Gross earnings (£)
Gross unequivalised income (%)
90
100
150
200
250
300

Lone parent-two children (14,16)(LA tenant)
36
34
8
Lone parent-two children (14,16)(private tenant)
36
34
16
11
5
Married couple, one child (1)(LA tenant)
36
35
18
3
Married couple, one child (2)(private tenant)
36
35
20
16
11
5
Married Couple two children (2 and 4)(LA tenant)
50
49
34
24
10
Married Couple two children (2 and 4)(private tenant)
50
49
34
31
26
22
Married couple two children aged 14 and 16 (LA tenant)
105
103
88
80
65
50
Married couple two children aged 14 and 16 (private tenant)
105
103
88
86
81
75
Married couple 3 children aged 8,10 & 12) (LA tenant)
77
76
60
52
36
22
Married couple 3 children aged 8,10 & 12) (private tenant)
77
76
60
58
53
48





MAINTENANCE PAYMENTS

  20.  None of the tables above take account of maintenance payments received. They also ignore maintenance payments made. Maintenance payments received directly are treated as income for HBAI purposes but not for income tax or tax credit purposes. The most recent Family Resources Survey (2000-01) shows that 22% of lone parents (4% of two parent families) receive maintenance payments. Well over two thirds of parents who do receive maintenance payments receive £25 or more per week—13% of lone parent recipients get £100 or more. If a family does receive maintenance payments, this will have a major impact on its equivalised income and may be another factor which explains the comparatively small number of children in poverty who live in lone parent households where the parent is in work.

EUROPEAN ACTION PLAN

  21.  The Lisbon European Council held in March 2000 called for action on the eradication of poverty throughout the Union by 2010. The European Union also uses equivalised incomes in compiling poverty statistics but uses an OECD scale compiled on a before housing cost basis. Appendix 2 shows the position that would apply if the OECD scale were used.

WHY THE TAX CREDIT REGIME IS FAILING POOR FAMILIES

  22.  Tax credits are failing to lift out of poverty many working two parent families and their children, even though they do so for most working lone parent families. This was true of the previous tax credit regime as it is for the current one. The reason is that, as devised so far, the credits do not target effectively families with low equivalised incomes. Yet this is the measure of the PSA target.

  23.  The Government's poverty target is based on equivalised income which takes account not only of joint family income and the number of children but also the number of adults in the family. Tax credits on the other hand ignore the number of adults in the family. Unlike the out-of-work benefits and social security benefits, such as Housing Benefit and Council Tax Benefit, no allowance is made for the second adult. This means that a lone parent and a two-parent family who are identical in all other respects (same children, gross incomes etc) will have different equivalised incomes. The two-parent family would need to have higher earnings to have the same equivalised income as comparable lone parent families. Appendix 3 compares Tax Credits with out-of-work benefits and also with Housing and Council Tax Benefits.

  24.  Another important factor is that many in-work families do not get the full benefit of the tax credits. This is because they are tapered out at the rate of 37 pence in the pound on pre-tax weekly income above £97. Many in work families with equivalised incomes below 60% of median do not fully benefit from the new credits.

  25.  Chart 1 below shows the extent to which a Married Couple with two young children living in local authority accommodation is likely in 2003-04 to have equivalised income below the estimated 60% contemporary median.


  26.  A subsidiary factor is that the Treasury has given insufficient weight to the additional costs of older children. The McClements scale gives a weight of 0.38 to children aged 16 and over compared with 0.07 for a child aged under 1. The Child element in the CTC is the same (£27.65) irrespective of the age of the child. It will be seen from Table 2 that a lone parent family with teenaged children will have equivalised income below 60% of median whereas comparable families with younger children have incomes above this figure.

POLICY OPTIONS

  27.  An initial reaction is that that additional spending on families will be required if the Government is to meet its child poverty targets. This may well be the case, but what is equally necessary is that the spending is better focused—ie directed to those families with the lowest equivalised incomes.

  28.  It might be thought that the best way of reducing child poverty among in-work families would be for the tax credit system to be enhanced at all points, increasing incomes for all families. However to do so would not only be very costly but perversely it would not be very effective. Since child poverty is defined as a relative concept, it will be reduced most quickly if the incomes of those above the poverty level are not also increased. Hence it will be both less costly and more effective in reducing child poverty if any enhancements to the tax credit system are concentrated on those families living below the poverty level. The inevitable downside of this is that the marginal deduction rate for those above the poverty level will remain high: this reflects the continuing tension between universal and means tested benefits.

  29.  For this reason we not believe that a general increase in the CTC child element would be a cost effective means of tackling child poverty: nor would a general increase in child benefit. Nor again, given the present structure of the tax credit would be an increase in the minimum wage, because for many families at that level of income the marginal deduction rate is 85% or even more.

  30.  By contrast, enhancements to the WTC for couples would be more likely to be cost effective as their impact would be less directly felt by those with higher incomes. We have considered two possibilities:

    (i)  an increase in the couples element in the credit; or

    (ii)  an increase in the threshold for couples after which the credit is tapered.

   We look at each in turn.

AN ENHANCED CREDIT FOR COUPLES

  31.  At present the couples element in the credit is the same as the lone parent element, despite the fact that the incomes of a couple are aggregated, and despite the higher weighting for a couple within the McClements scale. As we pointed out in paragraph 23 above and as is illustrated in Appendix 3, the additional costs incurred by a second adult are taken into account in making awards to the out of work benefits and to Housing and Council Tax Benefit. Hence to increase the couples element would bring WTC into line with what is done in the benefits system generally. One option the Committee might wish to consider is that the couples element in the WTC should be double that of the lone parent element, ie £57.40 compared with £28.70, so that, in addition to the basic element of £29.19, the credit for a couple would be £86.59 compared with £57.89 for a lone parent. This would bring tax credits closer into line with the out-of-work, Housing and Council Tax Benefits.

TAPER THRESHOLD

  32.  Alternatively, the tax credits for a couple should be kept at the same level as those for a lone parent, but the income at which they become subject to be withdrawn under the taper should be higher for a couple than for a lone parent. It seems inappropriate that families with children in poverty should find that their tax credits are not paid in full. One option might be to set the taper threshold at a level which would approximate to the income level at which a typical two parent family might move out of poverty if credits were paid in full. The difficulty is however that this figure varies considerably according to the size and composition of the family. It would not be possible to fix the taper threshold in terms of a family's equivalised income, but in principle it would be possible to set different taper thresholds for different types of family. Table 4 below shows the income point at which the families selected in the DWP Tax/Benefit Model Tables would have incomes above the poverty line if tax credits were given in full.

Table 4

GROSS INCOME NEEDED TO EXCEED 60% MEDIAN ABC (TAX CREDITS GIVEN IN FULL)


Family type
Gross income (£)

Married couple one child aged one
(LA tenant)
152
Married couple one child aged one
(private tenant)
217
Married Couple two children aged two and four
(LA tenant)
181
Married Couple two children aged two and four
(private tenant)
278
Married couple three children aged eight, 10 and 12)
(LA tenant)
221
Married couple three children aged eight, 10 and 12)
(private tenant)
340

Note: Data extracted from DWP Tax Benefit Model Tables April 2003


  33.  In Chart 2 we take the family illustrated in Chart 1 and show how, the position would be improved if the WTC credit for couples was £86.59 (as suggested in paragraph 31) and the taper threshold for couples was doubled, ie increased from £97 to £194.

Chart 2

ENHANCED CREDIT. HIGHER TAPER THRESHOLD AND PRESENT SYSTEM COMPARED


  Note: Data source DWP Tax Benefit Model Tables April 2003

  34.  It will be seen that of these two possibilities an enhanced couples credit would be the more effective in reducing the extent of child poverty among in-work couples with the lowest incomes, but increasing the taper threshold would have a broadly similar impact for couples with rather higher incomes. The proposals would therefore reduce the number of children in poverty by much the same extent, but at an increased cost the enhanced couples credit would reduce the severity of the poverty for more children.

  35.  We recognise that both these suggestions to reduce child poverty among couple families would be very costly. This reflects the extent to which the current tax credit system discriminates against couples and leaves their children in poverty where the children of other families in comparable circumstances would be above the poverty line. Any increase in the couples credit or the taper threshold could be phased in over a period of years: our suggestion of doubling them is illustrative and lower figures could be taken at first at the expense of retaining more children in poverty. If even with phasing the cost of our proposals was too high, part of the cost might have to be clawed back by increasing the tax charge or reducing the tax credit further up the income scale.

  36.  Increasing the CTC child element by, for example, £5, would appear to have little impact on the number of children in poverty in families in work. Chart 3 below compares this proposal with an enhanced couples credit and an increase in the taper threshold. It will be seen that this proposal would have little effect on the income level at which the illustrative family crosses the 60% median line. This is largely because of the very high marginal deduction rate for a family in work of the tax credit taper together with income tax and NIC.

Chart 3

ENHANCED CREDIT, HIGHER THRESHOLD AND £5 ADDITIONAL CHILD CREDIT COMPARED


  37.  If the Government wished to reduce the number of families with older children living below the poverty line in both two parent and one parent families, one solution would be to increase the child element within CTC for teenagers to bring it more into line with the McClements scale. This would also benefit larger families where some of the children are likely to be older.

  38.  A critical factor of any proposal for reducing child poverty would obviously be its cost. It would be important to determine not only what would be the cost to the Treasury of any change to the structure of the tax credits, or indeed any proposal to reduce the number of children living in poor families, but also the cost effectiveness of the proposal, ie how effective any change would be in reducing the number of children living in households with equivalised income below 60% median.

  39.  However, whatever the cost may be, unless structural changes are made to the tax credit regime along the lines suggested in this memorandum, it seems unlikely that the Government will be able significantly to reduce child poverty among families in work and hence to meet poverty targets expressed in terms of equivalised incomes.



191   Measuring Child Poverty paragraph 22. Back

192   Department for Work and Pensions, Analytical Services Division Child and Family Branch letter 24 August 2001. Back

193   IFS Briefing Note No 32, section 2, third paragraph. Back

194   HM Treasury Tax Benefit Reference Manual 2003-04 edition. Back

195   HBAI 2001-02, Appendix 2. Back

196   Figures supplied by DWP. Back

197   IFS Briefing Note No 32. Back

198   HC 564-1. Back

199   The Tax Benefit Model Tables show the net income after housing costs as £287.33. The McClements factor is 1.72 (0.55+0.45+0.23+0.23+0.26 ). £287.33 divided by 1.72 gives an equivalised income of £166.86. Back

200   The Working Families Tax Credit was paid to families where either the applicant of their partner (if they had one) worked at least 16 hours a week and were responsible for one or more children under 16 (or 19 if in full-time non-advanced education. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 22 January 2004