Select Committee on Education and Skills Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 60 - 76c)

MONDAY 29 NOVEMBER 2004

MR PHILIP COLLINS

  Q60  Chairman: How do you compare the SureStart success or lack of success with the work that has been mentioned only in the last few days, work in Oxford showing even a short time in pre-school, in a nursery? The evidence there is showing that is a very good investment because even a short time in pre-school raises the educational achievement of a child.

  Mr Collins: That is right. The evidence to my mind is overwhelming. We are starting to gather a body of evidence in the UK that confirms the evidence that we have from Denmark, Sweden and the United States where there are a number of projects, the Head Start project, but plenty of others too, which show that a year of good pre-school is immensely valuable to children and has a disproportionate effect on children of lower socio-economic status. That evidence is really suggestive and telling. I just emphasise something I said before—and this is true of Kathy Sylva's work too—you have to stress the quality of that provision is absolutely crucial. It is not enough. There are two separate objectives here. One will be to ease access of women into the labour market. The second will be to improve the cognitive development of children. They are complimentary up to a point but they are not the same. You could get more women into work if you had a thin coverage, just had somewhere for children to go that would meet your labour market objective. If you want to really get to the cognitive development of children then you have to attend to the quality of the provision. Crucially what that means is the quality of your staff. It brings us back to the point about people. You have to have a workforce which is properly trained and qualified, that means properly remunerated and we are miles away from that now, absolutely miles away.

  Q61  Chairman: We are not talking about that so much in the other provision for social workers, people working with children in hospitals. There are reasonably well-remunerated people working with children in some of these silos. Is that not the case?

  Philip Collins: In some. My own view is that they are not well remunerated enough and that the vacancy rates are evidence of that. We are struggling to recruit in most of these areas and we are certainly struggling to retain people. As I said before, that is partly to do with levels of pay. I do not think we can duck this, but we are not talking simply about plugging the gaps which currently exist. The sort of thing that we are working on implies quite a major extension of the workforce and improvement in its skills. For example, in New Zealand there is a very good example of a country that has made a major transformation in its early years services. The Government set itself a target by 2012 having a fully graduate level workforce, not necessarily graduates, that is an important thing to come back to, but graduate level workforce. It recognised that until you have that standard of provider then you are not going to get the benefits to your pound invested earlier on than you would otherwise.

  Chairman: Could we hold that for a moment. Paul.

  Q62  Paul Holmes: Just on that, talking about resources and the roll out of the programme everywhere, if Every Child Matters then it should be of benefit to every child. SureStart is very much lauded for its success and quite rightly but it is targeted on the poorest percentage of children who most need it. Even with that targeting, 40% of the children who would qualify do not get it because they live in areas where there is a more thinly scattered population. If we are going to extend under Every Child Matters these benefits out to everybody what are the resource implications? Is the Government committing itself in reality to extending it to everybody or is it still a very, very rationed process?

  Philip Collins: It is a very incremental process and it has to be. I think it would be fairly fantastic to demand of Government that they do this in one big step. It is inconceivable because the short answer to your question is: if you were to extend what I think you need to every child you are talking about something in the order of £15 billion. It is a colossal amount of money. You need to think about the steps to get there. It is something like a 10 or 20 year answer. In order to provide the standard of provision that I am talking about that is consistent with the data on good returns, to provide 12 months' paid parental leave, which is again crucial because prior to that age all the evidence tells us is that if a parent can spend the first year with their child this has enormous benefits to the child. Of course, that is not available to most people who cannot afford six months unpaid. Then that second year between one and two, in Finland you probably saw they have a home care allowance which essentially allows the parent, if they wish, to extend that contact with the child.

  Q63  Chairman: It is controversial.

  Mr Collins: It is. My own view is that that would be a good idea. To do that package of things you are looking at a shift in GDP spent on this area from currently about 0.8% to something like 2.7%. It is very large. It is worth then asking what would we stop doing? We modelled all these questions and it depends crucially on what you perceive to be the benefits. The benefits follow five, 10 years hence. PWC did some work for us when we modelled that scenario and we asked them what they thought would be the balance of costs and benefits. They came through, not to our surprise but to our delight, to say the benefits would outweigh the costs to the tune of something like 2% of GDP over time, 700,000 jobs created, and so on. We have all the details. You have to take a leap of faith, in a sense, that in due course those benefits would outweigh the cost.

  Q64  Chairman: This is your graduate profession?

  Philip Collins: Not alone. That is not the only thing. In the work we did we modelled a number of different scenarios, but one to which the figures I just quoted refer included an all graduate profession, a home care allowance between one and two, and paid parental leave for 12 months. We added the costs of those together and then we computed benefit and even on a relatively cautious set of assumptions there are returns on it which you can imagine is plausible. Indeed, the returns on that earlier expenditure are good. It must feed through in some sense to reduce welfare bills and reduce crime bills.

  Q65  Paul Holmes: You say the benefits are very great so it is worth doing, but you are also saying therefore we need to decide what we stop doing. Do you rule out the idea of a greater tax break, since we are in the bottom third of Europe whereas Finland is way above the top of the league.

  Philip Collins: No, I was not ruling that out, but in order as a think tank if you come out and say, "Let us have £20 billion more money", in a way it is a really easy thing to do and not very helpful for ministers. What we try to do is set ourselves a much tougher question which is to say: let us try and work out how public expenditure will be organised if it is consistent with the data on the return on every pound. We set ourselves that question artificially. Of course, another way of doing it would be to argue for tax increases. What we tried to do was essentially we took two graphs, one of which was the work with James Heckman, the Nobel economist, who showed that the return on a pound spent at age nought significantly outweighs that at age 15. If we look at the current pattern of public expenditure according to the life cycle, we discover, you will not be surprised, that it is organised in exactly the opposite way, it really bulges from about 13 onwards when we spend very little early on. We thought one interesting thing would be to see what we would have to do to make those two graphs run together, so that just purely on efficiency grounds that would make sense. That was just the artificial task we set ourselves in a way, but it does pose interesting questions. It does get you thinking about second chance training schemes, for example. There is precious little evidence that Government training schemes have any great return. Subsidised employment does, if you subsidise employers to take people on. This is   confirmed in the New Deal evaluation. The subsidised employment part of New Deal has a very good return and is successful, whereas those people who took up training options it seems to have had zero impact on their employability return, that sort of thing, where we might start to look at what we do not do as well as what we do more of.

  Q66  Paul Holmes: Did you model at all how far with an increasing ageing population and a decline in the number of children how far you could meet the gap by keeping spending at current levels over the years and, therefore, having more available per child?

  Mr Collins: We did not specifically, no, but it is a very good question. The one person who has done a lot of work on that is a Swedish man who has essentially pioneered the view that the burden and risk in a welfare society is shifting from men to women. The crucial people will be women. He points out that across all societies across time women have said they wanted 2.2 children, actually over most of Europe they are having significantly fewer than that now. The pressures on them are really quite intense. The one exception to this is in Denmark where they are having just about the number of children they say they would like to have. He attributes that to their universal childcare provision which over 30 years has filled in the gap. The presence of women in the Danish labour market is better than other places. It also gives them the flexibility through childcare to have the children they want. It is a crucially interesting question. It is not something we have included specifically in our work.

  Q67  Mr Pollard: If you look at the commitment in ECM policy involving children in the decision making, how do you best do that?

  Philip Collins: It is very difficult I think.

  Q68  Jonathan Shaw: Go on. Be positive for a change.

  Mr Collins: I think what is quite useful to do as this goes by is to think what the difficult questions would be. Involving children: when you say certain children want to be involved for a start, the best involvement of children is to provide really good quality services to them. The model of involvement we always work with is one where we have some form of committee or consultation process which people have to sit on. In defiance of all the evidence people do not want to do that. One of the reasons I think is that the welfare state generally has produced more benefits to the middle classes. The working class is precisely this model of involvement because the consumer voice has been monopolised by the articulate middle class. It depends what you want. If you think the trickle down theory of people's voices and the articulate people will make the service better for everyone by making their voice heard, that might be fine. What I would want would be extensive involvement with as many people as possible so that the service can be responsive to them. Then you really want everyone else to be involved. Across all public services it has proved to be quite easy to get some social groups involved in public services and much more difficult for the lower socio-economic groups. I will be positive though. One of the big successes of SureStart was that it managed this. People said prior to that it could not be done, we have given up, we cannot reach these groups. SureStart did it and they did it by going out and knocking on doors essentially. Outreach work was the answer. They got people involved which all the evidence and all the doom sayers said you could not do. The positive answer is that it can be done, but it is expensive because you cannot sit and wait for the people to come. You have to go to them. It is very labour intensive. I do not think at the moment that hard pressed workers in the system have the capacity to do it. Again, most of my answers require extra money, which I think inevitably is a requirement in this area.

  Q69  Chairman: Can it not be done on the cheap through the voluntary sector?

  Mr Collins: No, not entirely. Of course, the voluntary sector has a big role to play in it, but I do not think it can be done on the cheap with them, no. Again, I do not think there is capacity to do what needs to be done. You can make it better than it currently is by just using the voluntary sector, but if we are looking at real serious advance it is going to need some serious resources.

  Q70  Chairman: Some of us who remember the miners strike know that families and especially the wives of miners suddenly became articulate and very active in the community which had not been the same way as before. Research that has been done on that showed what a transformational experience it was.

  Mr Collins: Yes, but go through all the public services and just jot down everything that the Government wants you to do, to be involved in and you have no time for any work or anything like that. You are doing nothing other than being an active citizen. It is inconceivable that people can do all this stuff. It is the old Oscar Wilde line: "Socialism will never happen", and so on. The Government is asking us to do so much. The idea of co-production will require even more of us. What we know about this is that people do get involved when it is deeply important to them and where they know they can have a genuine impact. I think there is loads of scope for citizen involvement in the provision of local services.

  Q71  Chairman: How does that square with declining numbers of people participating in the electoral process or indeed local parties or action?

  Mr Collins: I am more optimistic on this because I think that if you try and put up a phone mast near someone's house and see whether they are politically apathetic or not—

  Chairman: —or build an incinerator.

  Mr Collins: Yes, quite.—I do not think that politically activity has disappeared; it has just moved. People have moved into areas where they know they can make a genuine impact. Therefore, what we need to do is provide a genuine voice to them where they have some sort of impact on the service. That is going to require some sort of partnership with them and the professionals, which again the professionals will not yield very easily.

  Q72  Chairman: Phillip, you can get parents involved in broader action outside their narrow confines of earning a living and keeping lots of things going to support the family. The one time you could get an outlet is when the children are in education, particularly early education. This is the opportunity of the Children Act, is it not, that that kind of relationship between the professionals, if they can come out of it, be teased out of their silos, and parents and other members of the community could be quite transformational?

  Mr Collins: Yes, it can. There is an opportunity. Again, SureStart gives us some little evidence on this because the effect on mothers is as stark in some cases as the effect on their children. The confidence generated by involvement in the process and employability rates, for example, of mothers after involvement in SureStart is really quite interesting. So there are clear benefits here.

  Q73  Paul Holmes: Just backtracking slightly to one of the earlier comments on this particular bit: are you being slightly cynical or realistic about all the talk on getting young people involved in taking decisions on this sort of thing is paying lip service? You seem to be implying it was not really very effective.

  Mr Collins: I think it is paying lip service. It could be effective. I am not saying it is inconceivable to design it so that it is effective, but in order to be effective people have to have a genuine authority. Their voice has to have some sanction attached to it. One way to attach sanctions to someone is to give them the right to exit a service if they do not like it, if it does not do what they want and give them the right to go somewhere else, normally known as choice. The other way is you give them some voice. If all you give them is a talking shop and in the end then their voice is not heard, it is not made effective, then that leads them to become cynical. I do not see at the moment that we have the mechanisms by which people's views feed through into the way the service is provided. It is perfectly possible to do it, but it involves a new relationship between citizen and professional as well.

  Q74  Chairman: Voice not choice: a nice slogan. Sorry to tease you out on this particular area of inquiry, but are you modelling the impact, say, of a deprived community where 11 to 16 education is struggling in the light of the impact of specialist schools? Are we talking about a lot of money?

  Mr Collins: Yes, we are. That is the next stage of the work because there is a danger we think that there is great promise in the Early Years work. I am a bit of an evangelist for it. I think it can make an enormous difference, but there is a danger that if we think we get the Early Years provision right, then that is somehow done. People are kind of inoculated against failure later on, and that is not true. The academic community knows a bit about the way in which those gains start to fade—not very much—but it is starting to become a major topic of study about once you have had a boost from an extra year of education, when does it start to fade and what can you do later in life to try and ensure those gains are retained? That is where we are moving on to now. I do not know the answer to my own question. I do not think anybody has quite asked the question as precisely as that which is how would you organise comprehensive product services from 11 onwards which are specifically designed to try and retain the gains you had earlier? It is a return to the question of what would you stop doing. I do not know the answer, but it is something which we are actively thinking about.

  Q75  Chairman: Just to take you back to SureStart. This is fascinating to us because it is a joined-up service and there is some inspiration at the moment here. Perhaps it is in SureStart; you said some reasonably positive things there. How much of the analysis of what does work has been written up and now is available to other SureStart programmes or other Government departments?

  Mr Collins: It is written up and it is in principle available to them if they go to the website where the FE work is written up. How many of them do in fact do that? I rather suspect it is a small number. There is no mechanism, as far as I know, for spreading that around, but the first evaluation has been written up and published and so that is there and available. There is a very important question how we get really good ideas spread through. The number of people employed in local authorities, for example, just to be spies on other local authorities is very small. Keeping an eye on what the others are doing is a very crucial part of any provision of any good.

  Q76  Chairman: It happened with football teams.

  Mr Collins: Absolutely: scouting. Why do we not have scouts in a local authority or just keeping an eye on it?

  Q76a  Chairman: Phil, we are running out of time in this committee room. We have three minutes. Is there anything you wanted to tell the Committee in three precious minutes that it is right at the beginning of totally new territory for us in terms of looking at this area? What else? What words of guidance and navigational drives?

  Mr Collins: I think that to counteract the sense in which I have been deeply pessimistic, it is worth keeping in mind all the while that this is not just about scandal-led policy. This is not just an area which is an attempt to avoid terrible things happening. The promise of this is really quite serious. For a long time, particularly the political Left has thought that social mobility and life chances could really be altered by policy from 11 onwards. The main hope is in comprehensive schooling. I think that it has shifted really to the thought that actually, no, it is not there because most of the formative influences are then settled and it is much earlier. I am really quite optimistic that this could be very serious, but it has to be done right because we do not know a lot about this. The political pressures will always be for the resources to be reduced because it is incredibly hard to find them and for different interests to be traded off. I always plead for clarity. There are many reasons why you might do an Early Years policy. One of them might be that you want lots more women into the labour market; a very laudable aim in itself but it is not the same aim as improving the cognitive development of children. Different outcomes lead to different policies. I just ask people to be clear about what it is they are looking for. Our objective has been to try and find what is the benefit for children, that leads you to a series of conclusions which would be alarming to the Exchequer and also involve relationships between citizens and providers and between different professions which are really quite revolutionary which they will find very difficult. Whenever any profession comes in and minimises the difficulties they think they will face in integrating themselves into the new world then I get extremely sceptical.

  Q76b  Chairman: Thank you then. The Sutton Trust gave evidence to this Committee about social mobility commissioned by the London School of Economics. What is your view on that? Has social mobility declined in recent years compared to the 1950s and 1960s or is that suspect research?

  Philip Collins: No, it is true, but the thing that has happened in the 20th century is that absolute social mobility has increased, ie there are more lawyers, there are more accountants, and there are more middle class people. There are much more ex-working class lawyers than there were in 1900. However, your chances of going from social class five to social class one: the odds ratio is exactly the same. Absolutely, yes, it has increased. Relatively it has not increased at all. The principal driver of that social mobility is in changes to the labour market. Insofar as you can separate them it has not been Government policy in the labour market changing. The big question that comes out of the LSE work is: is that growth in the service sector of the labour market itself slowing down? If it is, then you would expect that growth to slow. That is the big question. It connects with this argument because I think the work from Scandinavia, which is by the way the most socially mobile country in the world, Sweden, would suggest that universal childcare is, of all government policies, probably the most important if that is your objective.

  Q76c  Chairman: Phillip, thank you very much for your time and we have had a great deal of stimulation from your evidence. We hope to see you again.





 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 14 April 2005