Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witness (Questions 92-99)

MS HEIDI BACHRAM AND MR ADAM MA'ANIT

1 DECEMBER 2004

  Q92 Chairman: Good afternoon. Thank you very much for an extremely pungent written submission, which we have enjoyed reading. Could you possibly explain precisely who you are and who you are representing this afternoon?

  Ms Bachram: The submission was mostly written by our partner, The Corner House, Larry Lohmann. We contributed to parts of that submission and we are from the Transnational Institute project called Carbon Trade Watch.

  Q93 Chairman: You are both from the same organisation.

  Ms Bachram: Yes.

  Q94 Chairman: Okay, thank you. You are very welcome. We get the impression from your written submission that you are not terribly keen on emission trading schemes, is that fair?

  Mr Ma'anit: That is very fair.

  Ms Bachram: That is very fair.

  Q95 Chairman: You say that there are numerous more effective, more efficient, more egalitarian alternatives, including regulation, taxation, support for existing low fossil carbon economies, various alternative schemes for creating and distributing property in the earth's carbon cycling capacity. That is a very clear position, but does it represent a basis on which we can actually move forward to get international agreement?

  Mr Ma'anit: It depends. Inasmuch as the UK government is willing to engage with emissions trading, it would. It depends on how far we want to go with it. In international negotiations that option is there; it does not mean that we have to take that option in the Kyoto Protocol. It is a voluntary act; we do not have to engage in emissions trading. What emissions trading does do though is distorts the primary point of this whole exercise of climate change policy, which is that we need to reduce emissions at source. That should be a primary focus of our efforts and if emissions trading can be demonstrated to show that reductions at source happen across the board, then we would be in favour of it. Unfortunately, to date there has not been a sufficient body of evidence to suggest that any emissions trading scheme in existence or proposed will achieve that. By its very definition emissions trading allows for some sources to increase their emissions and that has knock-on effects. One of the misleading angles about emissions trading is that we are only talking about greenhouse gases and because we are only talking about greenhouse gases, those gases do not have localised effects on communities in which these factories are sited. There are many co-pollutants involved in the combustion process which do have local effects and are a part of the process of production of greenhouse gases. Any increase in emissions at source will involve an increase of those co-pollutants, many of them extremely toxic and with damaging effects on human health: carcinogens fluorocarbon compounds, polycyclic aromatic hydrocarbons, fine particulate matter, etcetera. Just today, we read a report that the asthma incidence arising among children in the UK has increased fourfold since the 1970s. This is a public health crisis and we have to start looking at ways to reduce emissions at all sources, not just one here and increase somewhere else.

  Q96 Chairman: Reading through your submission, I kind of got the impression that you object in principle to emissions trading because it involves commerce. Would that be correct?

  Mr Ma'anit: That is not fair. The commerce angle only distorts the relationship. It is the question of what actually happens on the ground that we are concerned with. We are concerned with weak environmental regulations; we are concerned with weak oversight of factories and the emissions at each site; we are concerned about the verifiability of emissions reductions. We have already seen that the data we have at the moment, in terms of our requirements for reporting to the EU and to the UN, are grossly inefficient. You yourself tabled a question recently in parliament about HFC emissions. We have discovered that HFC emissions are actually 40% higher than we previously thought. This is a huge problem. The only thing we know that works for sure, guaranteed, is effective government regulation of emissions at source. Anything else complicates the matter.

  Q97 Chairman: That is interesting because, actually one of things I felt, having read your memorandum, was that you were good at critique, but pretty short on solutions. Obviously the context of this whole inquiry is that we have a serious problem. What we are struggling to find is a solution which is going to work. If you reject emissions trading, as you do, in favour of some other thing, we have to be sure that the "some other thing" works. What sort of chance in hell is there that an international tax regime is going to be put in place that is acceptable to all the parties concerned? Is that credible?

  Mr Ma'anit: Maybe not an international carbon tax regime, but certainly there is a huge momentum for an international tax on speculative flows, for example, which has a lot of support, mainstream support even in many governments in the European Union. That is not unrealistic. Another realistic option would be to look at fossil fuel subsidies; this is something that even the World Bank admits is a huge problem and needs to be dealt with. Fossil fuel subsidies in the EU alone amount to $15 billion a year annually; the UK's contribution to that is something like one point two, one point three on average each year. Those are distortions of the market; they are not market-based mechanisms.

  Q98 Mr Challen: These things are not mutually exclusive, are they? I think we might well support all of these things, including ETS, if that delivers what we want. If that were the case, would you still maintain your opposition? Do you think that there is some underlying reason why emission trading schemes make it more difficult to obtain these other results in other areas such as fossil fuel subsidies?

  Mr Ma'anit: We have to look at why we are even talking about emissions trading in the first place. The reason why is because industry in the United States originally had felt that the regulatory burden placed upon it was too much and there needed to be something a bit more flexible, something that allowed industry to be competitive, to be efficient, to engage in commerce, but without the regulatory red tape. This gave birth to the existing trading schemes in the United States, including the RECLAIM programme, the sulphur dioxide trading programme in the Los Angeles area and Safer Trading with Sulphur trading, which was part of the title for our Clean Air Act in the United States and now we are talking about it here. The problem is that what we have seen in the United States' schemes, for example, is that rather than complement regulatory discipline, emission trading schemes have subverted regulation, in other words, regulation has disappeared from the agenda and has been replaced by an emissions trading package. For example, in the LA RECLAIM scheme 10 years of work in terms of achieving smog reduction commitments in the LA region has been rolled back almost overnight by the decision to move to an emissions trading scheme. Meanwhile what we have seen from the evidence from the RECLAIM programme was that the emissions trading results were heavily fraudulent, a number of cases were involved with direct fraud in the market, in fact no emissions had actually been reduced and all the existing regulatory disciplines that were in place have been rolled back. This was a dramatic loss. The scientific advisory panel advising on this scheme resigned en masse in protest at what was taking place and we see this across the board. We see this with all the existing emissions trading schemes in place in the United States: mandatory pollution trading now; a lot of pollution trading being devised. It is instead of government's duty to regulate directly.

  Q99 Chairman: Obviously there are people who believe that it has actually been pretty successful, particularly in relation to sulphur.

  Mr Ma'anit: In the case of sulphur, that is a myth, it is a mythology and this is part of the problem. On the sulphur trading scheme, a New York Times investigation in 1998 and another investigation in 2003 found that sulphur dioxide emissions had gone down in the United States, not because of the emissions trading system but because of the switch from coal to gas and because of legally mandated pollution technologies, controlled technologies, that the States had imposed on the sites. These accounted for most of the reductions in sulphur dioxide and recently the EU Environmental Protection Agency has admitted that sulphur dioxide emissions have actually increased by 4% in the last year alone in the United States. So part of the problem with all this data that we are dealing with from emissions trading schemes is that a lot of the data is voluntary; it is voluntarily produced by industry itself to report on its emissions portfolio. We see a huge problem and a capacity problem within the Environment Agency here in the UK to deal with monitoring of emissions. They themselves admit that they cannot visit all sites. In some sectors, for example sectors involved in metals processing, less than 1% of the sites were physically visited by an inspector.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 29 March 2005