Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Friends of the Earth England, Wales and Northern Ireland

Whether an international ETS is feasible, given that targets and compliance penalties would need to be rigidly enforced and bearing in mind the political pressures to which an international ETS would be subject;

  1.  When considering international emissions trading it is important to differentiate between the system of inter-state trading in emissions allowances that will come in to force when the Kyoto Protocol is ratified, and begin in 2008; and the development of "company level" or "private sector"[36] emissions trading at an international scale.

  2.  The Kyoto Protocol is a market-orientated international agreement between nation states. It requires Annex 1 countries (developed countries) to hold sufficient allowances (AAUs) to match the level of emissions in that country in the first compliance period (2008-12). The number of AAUs initially allocated, represents the level of emissions from that country in 1990, plus or minus the amount of reduction or increase in emissions that have been agreed for each country—set out in Annex B of the Kyoto Protocol. Countries therefore contribute towards meeting the target within the Protocol by either, delivering reductions at home, or, through purchasing emissions allowances from countries who have exceeded their target (AAU trading), or by purchasing approved emission reductions from projects in other Annex 1 countries (Joint Implementation, JI) or in non-Annex 1 countries (Clean Development Mechanism, CDM).

  3.  The ability to trade and generate credits is intended to enable participants to find the least cost route to achieving reductions. For greenhouse gases, where the geographical point of release is irrelevant, a market solution of this kind is ideal. However, the initial aim of achieving a 5% reduction in developed country emissions by 2012, relative to 1990 levels, is unlikely to be achieved without the participation of the US. Indeed the degree to which Russia can sell its "hot air" or excess allowances to all other countries in the scheme, raises the question of whether the Kyoto Protocol will deliver any additional savings at all, beyond those that have resulted from lower than projected growth in Russia's emissions.

  4.  The inclusion of credits from countries who have yet to take on targets also raises the possibility that Annex 1 countries will simply buy their way out of their commitments, and in doing so, reduce the potential for countries who host these projects to benefit from the potential for emissions savings these projects represent, if and when they themselves take on a target. A cap on the number of project credits that can be used for compliance would provide some protection against this. [37]

  5.  Only one commitment period has been defined in the Kyoto Protocol and questions relating to the development of international trading between countries will inevitably arise as negotiations begin over the second commitment period.

  6.  There have been many criticisms of the Kyoto Protocol but the agreement was a political success given the fierce opposition that existed, and still exists, to any kind of legally binding agreement. The Kyoto Protocol and the Marrakech Accords that govern trading within the Protocol are an important first step towards the establishment of an inter-country emissions trading scheme. However, elements are missing and lessons can be learnt from experiences to date. For example, to ensure more certain delivery of reductions in emissions within participating countries, the list of participating countries will need to be determined in advance of targets being set (the assumed list of participants in the first phase (which crucially included the US) clearly was not delivered). Allowance allocation methodologies or target setting procedures will need to be clarified and refined. Penalties for non-compliance will also need to be established to drive the market—at present there are none. All of these issues will need to be resolved before the Kyoto Protocol and its successors can be claimed to have successfully introduced a working international market in emissions reduction credits.

  7.  The process of allocation of emission allowances under Kyoto can really only be described as a version of political horse trading with no serious methodology underpinning it. There was no systematic consideration of, for example, historic liabilities, economic and technological potential for reductions, current or projected per capita or per unit of GDP emission levels, or geographic circumstances. This has lead to some commentators calling for an altogether more prescriptive approach to be adopted. Allocation systems based for example on pure per capita calculations are simple and elegant in their design, however, they fail to take into account important political and economic realities. In a world where existing economic superpowers are quickly being caught up by rapidly developing economies, there is little appetite for creating additional redistributional effects in the global economy.

  8.  Such is the urgency with which rising global emissions need to be reversed, reductions can and should be the goal of every country that is in a position to deliver them. Rich developed countries must go first. Economic assistance will be needed in some countries and therefore all existing international finance institutions should be re-orientated, and new funds created, to ensure that technological leaps to low carbon solutions are incorporated in all countries currently investing in their energy infrastructure.

  9.  Having touched briefly on inter-country emissions trading we will concentrate the majority of our remaining comments on the development of company trading at an international level. The difference being that company level trading schemes apply to individual sources of emissions within countries, with Governments deciding who will participate, how many allowances to hand out and what the rules for non-compliance will be. The EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) is the first example of an international ETS and it has already proved to be easier (although by no means easy) to agree the framework for this scheme than for the preceding UN-negotiated Kyoto framework.

Markets need clear rules and regulations to govern them if they are to develop effectively

  10.  The EU, in devising the EU Emissions Trading Scheme has broken new ground. The mechanism provides, in one integrated economic instrument, the ability to control approximately 50% of the Union's emissions of carbon dioxide. The mandatory nature of the scheme and the relatively high penalties for non-compliance (40 Euros per ton in the first phase, rising to 100 Euros a ton in the second—with cancellation of equivalent future allowances in both) give it the potential to be a highly effective tool in the fight against climate change.

  11.  However, allocation of allowances within the scheme has proven to be a highly politicised process. Concerns over effects on industrial competitiveness have served to hamper Governments' ability to use the scheme to deliver emissions reductions. These will need to be overcome and genuine effort required from participants if it is going to deliver a significant environmental outcome.

  12.  This issue, however, applies to all conceivable efforts to combat climate change—no matter what mitigation tool you might choose, the question of balance remains—regulate too hard, set the level of a tax too high, hand out too few credits and economic growth could be severely damaged. Do the opposite and the tool will fail to deliver environmental benefits.

  13.  The question facing policy makers is how best to achieve control over emissions whilst providing industries with flexibility and incentives to change business models. All this must be done in as least disruptive a way as possible to the economy. Trading is one flexible way of doing this and the degree of control, the absence of the need for public spending and the fact that savings can be achieved at least cost has made company level emissions trading a popular concept.



  14.  Trading also allows industries to determine the cost of compliance and arguably they are far better placed to do this than Governments, who will be relying on estimates rather than experience. Little is genuinely known about the cost of abating carbon—even in the UK—experience in the sulphur market has shown that it is likely to be a lot less than imagined. This means that if the right balance can be found we will see considerable reductions but at a relatively modest price. Abatement cost discovery is one of the most important ancillary benefits of any trading scheme as this can be used to counteract industry alarmism in future rounds of target setting.

  15.  Despite concerns over the high level of allocations of allowances in the first pilot phase of the EU ETS, from Jan 2005, across the EU, emitting carbon will carry a price and for the first time industries directly responsible for greenhouse gas emissions will have the price of those emissions factored in to their company accounts. The effect of this on corporate purchasing and investment decisions is potentially very significant.

Implementation of Kyoto through trading

  16.  The idea of moving forward with emissions trading schemes at regional, national and international scales is gaining ground around the globe. The hiatus created by the prolonged uncertainty over the future of the Kyoto Protocol and the US's steadfast refusal to take part have, perhaps, given impetus to this trend. It must be stressed, however, that Kyoto still represents the only credibly multi-lateral approach to tackling climate change. Company level emissions trading schemes are merely one tool amongst many that will need to be used to help countries meet the requirements of the UNFCCC and subsequent legally binding international frameworks to drastically reduce global emissions of greenhouse gases.

  17.  The EU is not on currently on track to meet its Kyoto reduction target (in 2002 a reduction of 2.9% had been achieved meaning that we are some distance from the linear path to meeting the target where we should have achieved a 4.8% reduction). All eyes are therefore on the European Union's Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Directive which introduced a trading scheme which will establish the world's first international mandatory cap and trade scheme for the control of carbon dioxide emissions.

  18.  Norway is developing a scheme in parallel with the EU that will be linked to the EU scheme. Canada another early ratifier of Kyoto is also in the process of implementing an emissions trading scheme and a schemes is also being talked of in Japan and very recently even in Russia[38]. In non-ratifying countries such as the US and Australia state level emissions trading schemes are being discussed in defiance of Federal level inaction.

  19.  In addition, countries such as China and most recently Chile are taking their lead from the US's highly successful sulphur and NOx emissions trading schemes and adopting their own trading mechanisms to combat environmental problems. It is not inconceivable that these and other non-Annex 1/B countries may wish to implement their own national carbon emissions trading schemes to enable them to comply with UNFCCC and Kyoto which require that they develop national strategies to constrain emissions.

Links between schemes

  20.  As the location of emissions reductions is in environmental terms immaterial, and the achievement of least cost reductions desirable, there is a strong argument in favour of creating interconnected company level trading schemes to bring down global emissions.

  21.  In political terms, however, it does matter where emissions reductions take place and the world is looking to the rich developed countries, who are responsible for the majority of historic and current emissions of greenhouse gases, to take action first. This raises a political problem in that early action in these countries will disadvantage certain industries putting them at a competitive disadvantage. This risks emissions being exported rather than reduced as environmentally damaging industries move to countries who have yet to take action. The European Aluminium Association, or EAA, is claiming that as much as 50% of aluminium smelters across the EU might move to non-Kyoto countries due to rising EU energy prices as a result of the Emissions Trading Scheme. [39]

  22.  One way of limiting competitiveness impacts in the EU is to support the linking together of emissions trading schemes. The EU Emissions Trading Directive already establishes the possibility for discreet trading schemes involving Annex 1 countries to be linked together, however, there is little detail available on how such a link might operate. In addition, the European Parliament recommended an amendment to the Linking Directive that would enable trading schemes in non-Annex 1 countries also to be "linked". Again, there is little detail available about how this might be achieved. Indeed it could be that this recommendation was as much a political statement as a serious statement of intent. Nevertheless it seems certain that the EU will not wish to remain isolated in its pursuance of cap and trade measures and will seek to encourage other countries to follow their lead.

ISSUES OF CONCERN:

Likely diversity of schemes

  23.  Emissions trading schemes can be designed in many different ways and it is highly likely that schemes in different parts of the world will adopt different rules and methodologies. This is already the case between initial proposals for the Canadian scheme and EU one although modifications are now expected to the Canadian scheme to make it more compatible with the EU.
EU schemeCanadian scheme (proposed)
MandatoryMandatory
CO2 only to begin withAll six gases
Overall cap set at beginning of scheme Intensity targets create "cap"
Caps established by MSs—Commission state must be consistent with Kyoto targets and domestic policies Caps set by Gov—16% below BAU
No cap on costs—fine for non-compliance 40E ton/CO2 in 1st period plus allowance reduction Cap on costs of $15 Canadian per ton CO2e
No use of domestic creditsUse of domestic credits
Proposed link to KP flex mex—eligibility criteria likely to be restricted Proposed link to KP flex mex eligibility criteria unlikely to be restricted
No fungability with AAUsNo fungability with AAUs


Compliance implications

  24.  Diversity between schemes makes the establishment of links potentially problematic. If allocations are more generous, or the rules in one scheme more lax than another, then complete fungibility would result in a race to the bottom with participants in stricter schemes circumventing the rules by buying in lower value credits from other schemes. Gateways and restrictions on the flow of emissions credits can help to minimise this risk, however, they would need to be carefully designed. At present it looks likely that this job will fall to the EU where questions relate to linking to the EU scheme, however, over time a fully independent supra-national body will be needed to oversee this process.

Verification

  25.  As well as careful consideration of rules and methodologies the linking of schemes requires rigorous compliance mechanisms including monitoring and verification of baselines and emissions. Confidence amongst traders, participants and NGO stakeholders is essential for the proper functioning of any internationally linked emissions trading scheme. If links are created between schemes, the integrity of all schemes will be determined by the least tightly verified scheme, if the flow of allowances is unrestricted. It is in the interests of all parties, and in the proper functioning of a market, that verification is rigorous. A supra-national independent body that is able to verify the verifiers would help to build confidence in the carbon market by providing an additional layer of security for all participants.

The rules gap

  26.  The desirability of internationally consistent rules, compliance and verification regimes was accepted when trading was introduced to the UNFCCC in the drafting of the Kyoto Protocol. The Marrakech Accords provide detailed provisions for this. There is no equivalent rule book for company level trading. It is important that compliance and verification rules keep pace with the fast moving political discourse about international company level emissions trading. To date these issues have been given insufficient attention and too few resources have been applied to considering the framework and rule book that must be in place before links can be established.

Prompt action on Trading

  27.  It was accepted in COP 7 that in for the Clean Development Mechanism within the Kyoto Protocol to operate effectively rules should be established under the UNFCCC that enabled it to be set up early in expectation of ratification.

  28.  The same rationale and set of provisions used to establish the CDM Executive Board can be used to establish a monitoring and verification body for company level carbon trading schemes that would help to facilitate the establishment of schemes in more countries and enable schemes to be effectively linked without risking their environmental integrity.

  The suggested supra-national body would not necessarily become involved in the setting of targets within individual trading schemes but would concern itself primarily with overseeing the relationship between company level trading and the achievement of internationally agreed reduction targets. It could also set criteria for linking, design gateways between schemes, and monitor and verify the environmental integrity of individual trading schemes once designed. It could also play an important role in communicating best practice, capacity building, and encouraging the development of common international standards.

Examples within other multi-lateral agreements

  29.  The precedent of establishing supra-national bodies to verify compliance with international agreements is well established. In 1957 countries came together to establish the International Atomic Energy Agency. They recognised that atomic energy represented a risk of potentially global proportions—the widespread effect of the Chernobyl disaster only serving to prove the case. An independent Secretariat was formed under the auspices of the UN with signatory countries providing funding. Rights were established that enabled IAEA teams to independently inspect and verify national monitoring and reporting procedures with respect to civil uses of nuclear power.

CONCLUSION

  30.  The establishment of a global system of governance for company level trading is essential if schemes are to be introduced in other countries and links between them established. The UK is well placed to begin international discussions towards this goal having been the first country to introduce its own domestic carbon trading scheme, and, consequently, having become a global centre for emissions trading expertise through early experimentation with this important mitigation tool.

What other alternatives to an international ETS exist; and whether an ETS would be more effective than such alternatives in maximising carbon reductions worldwide and in channelling investment in low-carbon technologies into less developed countries

Russia is considering setting up a domestic emissions trading scheme that could link to the EU scheme, and a potential Canadian one, from 2008. http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=5148&categoryID=147.


  31.  An international company level ETS is simply one way of stimulating emissions abatement activity in countries and sectors of the economy that are included in the scheme. Alternatives range from the maintenance of discreet trading schemes in individual countries or blocks of countries, to the introduction of a global tax on all sources of greenhouse gases.

  32.  The reason there is considerable interest in company level trading is that it provides participants with flexibility, enables savings to be achieved at least cost and Governments with a degree of control over emissions (in cap and trade schemes Governments limit the total amount of emissions allowances created, whereas taxes rely on high enough price signals to effect demand).

  33.  There is momentum behind company level trading that indicates that it will be widely adopted as an emissions mitigation tool—the pressing question is with what degree of environmental integrity? The same cannot be said of either global taxes or carbon taxes and given the urgency of the need to limit global emissions there may be insufficient time for this to develop. Of course as the impacts of climate change become more apparent this situation may change.

  34.  The question of how to channel investment into low carbon technologies in developing countries is a crucial one given the rate at which some countries are industrialising. The introduction of cap and trade schemes in rapidly developing countries would establish a price for emissions, meaning that more polluting developments would have a financial penalty relative to cleaner alternatives. However, this is unlikely to be a viable option in the short term for all but the most rapidly developing countries. Not least because many countries lack the well established regulatory, monitoring and verification infrastructure and culture that are essential to underpin trading schemes. An alternative and complementary approach would be to establish international financing facilities that will provide loans and guarantees for clean technologies and refuse financing for high emission projects. Existing financing institutions should adopt new policies that create a maximum emissions limit for all new infrastructure projects funded.

What approach and specific objectives in relation to climate change the UK Government should adopt during its presidency of the G8 and EU in 2005; and

G8

  35.  The G8 summit in July will need to lead to a firm consensus amongst the G8 that immediate and sustained activity is necessary to tackle climate change under a legally binding internationally agreed framework. A key test of work streams begun in the G8 will be whether they culminate in re-invigorated discussions and negotiations at and around the first meeting of parties to the Kyoto Protocol in December of the same year.

  36.  Key milestones towards this goal could include:

    —  agreement to review the adequacy of commitments which should have happened in 1998 (UNFCCC Article 4 para 2.d);

    —  agreement to establish an international framework governing the development of company level emissions trading schemes enabling in the long term all UNFCCC signatories to design and implement effective schemes to control their domestic emissions;

    —  consensus amongst G8 and OECD countries to divert public funding away from projects which lock us into high emissions pathways and to support instead truly sustainable renewable energy developments; and

    —  consensus between developed and developing countries about the reorientation of global agricultural subsidies towards supporting biofuels and away from food production.

Re-engaging US and Australia

  37.  Pressure must be applied to Annex 1 countries remaining outside the Kyoto Protocol to re-engage in international negotiations and take on legally binding emissions reduction targets. Under the Kyoto Protocol negotiations for second commitment period targets must begin in 2005. However, if these negotiations are only carried out with under the Protocol, non-signatories will be excluded. It is therefore important that a parallel negotiation is begun under the auspices of the UNFCCC. Article 4 para 2 (d) requires that a review of the adequacy of commitments under the Framework Convention be carried out no later than 31 December 1998 and such a review is clearly therefore long overdue.

  38.  In addition to restarting negotiations the EU should also take action to protect the competitiveness of its directly affected industries be seeking redress through traditional trade measures. Sanctions could be applied if non-ratification of the Kyoto Protocol can be shown to create trade distortions, in which non-compliance is shown to create an effective subsidy.

More on G8 ask on trading

  39.  The G8 offers an opportunity to achieve agreement to work together to introduce an international framework for the development and potential linking together of company level emissions trading schemes.

  40.  For the EU countries represented at G8, this provides an opportunity to insulate against competitiveness impacts that may occur as a result of their early action. For Japan and Canada it offers similar advantages enabling them to meet their Kyoto commitments without being isolated. For the US it offers a means of consolidating initiatives already gathering pace at State level.

The need for co-operation

  41.  The Marrakech accords to the Kyoto protocol outline rules governing inter-country trading but there is no equivalent for company level schemes. Without a strategic international framework, interlinked company level schemes could result in poor environmental integrity and a weakening of individual schemes as abatement costs and verification standards will naturally drop to the level of the least tightly implemented scheme.

  42.  Company level trading means that Nation States have reduced control over their in-country emissions. It can therefore result in countries being traded out of compliance with any national or international targets they may have—resulting in a negative financial impact on the public purse as compensating credits will need to be purchased by the State.

  43.  The work stream for the G8 would therefore need to cover:

    —  Governance structure

    —  Standardised verification and monitoring rules

    —  Harmonisation of compliance and allocation rules

    —  Rules for linking schemes

    —  Extension of best practice

    —  Capacity building internationally (especially in rapidly industrialising countries)

    —  Assessing implications for compliance with UNFCCC and Kyoto.

EU Presidency

  44.  The UK's EU Presidency offers an opportunity to influence the future development of the EU Climate Policy. Russia's ratification of the Kyoto Protocol now means that targets for future commitment rounds can begin to be discussed. The EU must continue to press ahead not only with meeting its existing target but also in setting challenging new targets.

  45.  To date the EU has failed to adhere to a linear path towards its Kyoto target and few, if any, countries within the EU can claim to have achieved adequate control over their emissions. In the face of uncertainty the question of control is key. If it transpires that climate sensitivities are greater than first thought then we must have in place policies and measures that can be quickly adapted to new information.

  46.  In this context the biggest challenge for the EU is therefore not meeting a long term reduction target in 20 or 30 years but in successfully placing itself on a linear reduction pathway as soon as possible and working to seek agreement from other countries that they will seek to do the same. Friends of the Earth is currently consulting internally on the level of targets we will be recommending, however, initial discussions indicate that they will need to be in the region of a 3% per annum reduction from 2010.

  47.  Another important point that must be accepted is that departure from linear reduction paths towards targets, means that targets must be made more stringent to compensate. Increased concentration levels of gases will be achieved if the volume of emissions over time is higher than would be the case if a linear reduction path is adopted. This is the case if high emissions are sustained and reductions only achieved towards the end of the target period—if this occurs to achieve the same reduction in concentrations a deeper cut needs to be achieved at the end of the period.

  48.  As successive commitment periods are likely to run consecutively from 2008 this will be less of a problem in the future, however, the degree to which non-linear pathways to existing targets have been taken (ie between 1997 and 2008) and the increased commitment to global warming that has occurred as a result, must be assessed and considered in the process of setting new targets.

  49.  In addition, the EU has significant influence over how public money is spent in international finance institutions. Historically huge sums of money have been spent underpinning fossil fuel developments, locking in emissions for many years to come. Friends of the Earth is calling for public money in the shape of international loans and guarantees to be diverted away from projects with high emissions—particularly export focussed projects, which have delivered little in the way of economic advantage to host countries and simply served to provide developed countries with cheap fuels. Instead public subsidies for truly sustainable renewable energy projects should be greatly increased.

On trading

  50.  The EU Emissions Trading Directive is the most significant piece of climate legislation to date anywhere in the world and the EU should be congratulated for introducing it as it is an example of the kind of policies and measures that will be needed to give Governments control over emissions.

  51.  However, implementation to date has been weak with the substantial lobbying power of directly affecting industries undermining Governments' ability to set challenging caps on emissions.

  52.  The UK should use its Presidency to ensure the review of the EU ETS recommends the setting of an EU-level cap for total allowances that is consistent with the EU's Kyoto target. It should also seek to achieve greater harmonisation of allocation rules and tougher critieria in Annex III of the Directive to prevent over allocation.

  53.  The Directive can and should be strengthened for the second phase.

  Friends of the Earth recommends the following

  (for more information please refer to Annex 1):

    —  set a challenging European level cap on total allocation of allowances in the second phase of trading (2008-12);

    —  increase the harmonisation of rules governing how Member States allocate allowances to participants including: fixing the baseline years for future allocations; introducing compulsory auctions; establishing technology benchmarks for new entrants; providing consistent incentives for plant closures; and agreeing banking and borrowing rules;

    —  committing to 100% auctioned system in the third phase of trading;

    —  introducing tough penalties for abuses;

    —  introducing tough caps on use of overseas credits (ie Joint Implementation and Clean Development Mechanism credits) to meet domestic targets.

  54.  If progress can be made on these issues then the EU should also continue to explore ways in which trading can be extended to cover other greenhouse gases and other sources of emissions eg aviation and land-based transport emissions.

  55.  The latter are likely to be best accounted for at the point of production fuel rather than through downstream customers or car manufacturers. The fact that emissions from these sectors are projected to grow (although recently land based emissions appear to be levelling off) means that their inclusion in the scheme could provide important additional demand for credits, raising the price of carbon meaning that more expensive abatement options in other sectors become economic. If they remain outside, with no comparable policy interventions, then industrial sectors will quite correctly start to complain that the burden of meeting reduction targets is not being equitably shared across the economy. This will lead to increased pressure on Governments to provide generous allocations.

  56.  Additional measures to constrain growth in emissions in these sectors will, however, also be needed irrespective of whether they enter the scheme.

What contribution individual departments can make (eg. FCO, DEFRA, HMT, DfT, and DFID), and whether they are sufficiently "joined-up" in delivering a coherent UK agenda

  57.  Government has made efforts to create links between Departments by for example creating the interdepartmental Sustainable Energy Policy Network to oversee the delivery of the Energy White Paper. Integrating environmental considerations, in particular climate change, throughout Government policy, continues, however, to present something of a challenge to Government.

  58.  Even though the Department for Trade and Industry was the lead Department on the Energy White Paper they are also a powerful voice within Government opposing measures that they believe will threaten certain sectors of industry's competitiveness. This was never more apparent than in the discussions surrounding the allocation of emission allowances within the first phase of the EU ETS. The section of the DTI which specialises in maintaining relations with industry acted as a conduit for a range of industries to make very strong cases against challenging targets. The DTI has an important role to play in maintaining the wellbeing of the industry operating in the UK but this must not be at the expense of progress towards a low carbon economy. Certain high emitting or energy intensive industries will need to adapt to life in a carbon constrained world and it should be the role of DTI to facilitate that transition as quickly as possible—not to seek to reduce Government's ambition to deliver easily affordable carbon savings.

  59.  The Department of Transport now has a Public Service Agreement committing it to helping to deliver the Government's climate change targets and this is welcome. However transport is responsible for roughly a quarter of the UK's emissions of carbon dioxide, and this share is set to rise in coming years, making the Department for Transport (DfT) a key player in reducing emissions.

  60.  DfT must play a full and positive role in reducing emissions of CO2. However events since the Spending Review do not bode well. The Transport White Paper "The Future of Transport: a network for 2030", published in July, projected CO2 emissions from road transport continuing to rise for at least the rest of this decade[40] with emissions still possibly above 1990 levels in 2025[41]. DfT has failed to address the problem of rising traffic levels as a cause of rising emissions, seemingly placing all its faith in technology as a solution. We share the concerns of your Committee that "the Future of Transport White Paper had nothing new to say on the practical steps the Department for Transport would take to tackle carbon emissions from transport"[42].

  61.  The draft guidance to local authorities on Local Transport Plans (LTPs), published by DfT in August, did not include tackling climate change as one of the priorities. Instead it is included in a list of "other quality of life issues" about which the draft guidance says "the Department does not expect local transport strategies and LTPs necessarily to be aimed at dealing with these issues as key priorities"[43]. Given the importance of local authorities in delivering integrated transport, we find this astonishing.

  62.  DfT must accept that technology alone will not be enough to substantially reduce emissions from transport. The Interdepartmental Analysts Group (which was set up to inform the Government's response to the RCEP recommendation of a 60% cut in carbon dioxide emissions by 2050 and brought together officials from DTI, DEFRA, DTLR, HM Treasury and the PIU) concluded that: "substantially reducing carbon emissions from transport will require a combination of measures to reduce traffic demand, enhance the transport infrastructure across all modes, improve the energy efficiency of vehicles and encourage the introduction of low carbon fuels"[44]. The Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research has reached the same conclusion[45].

  63.  There must be a "climate filter" on all of the DfT's work. There should be clear targets for reducing carbon dioxide emissions from the transport sector, with specific targets for both the contribution of technology and for demand management. Among policies required are:

    (a)  DfT should press for tougher regulation on vehicle fuel efficiency, with the next agreement between the EU and ACEA, representing car manufacturers, being made mandatory rather than voluntary.

    (b)  The introduction of a renewable transport fuel obligation to stimulate the development and commercialisation of alternatives to fossil fuel based fuels.

    (c)  Continuing traffic growth will make a major contribution to rising carbon dioxide emissions and must be tackled through a range of measures including investment in improved public transport alternatives, investment in making streets safer for cycling and walking and the cancellation of road-building schemes that will lead to traffic growth. These policies reflect the manifesto of the "Way to Go" campaign, of which Friends of the Earth was a key part[46].

  64.  Tackling climate-changing emissions must also be a priority for transport at the regional and local levels, as this is where much of the delivery of integrated transport takes place.

  65.  DfT's responsibility also covers aviation, an area in which your Committee has worked tirelessly in recent months to expose "the glaring inconsistency of facilitating so large a growth in carbon emissions at a time when we need to make huge cuts to minimise the worst impacts of global warming"[47]. We share the Committee's concerns and believe that expansion of aviation on the scale forecast by DfT will make achieving longer-term carbon dioxide reduction targets at best much more difficult and at worst near impossible. We believe that emissions targets impose a limit on aviation growth, which must be the key factor in future decisions about airport expansion, and that the Government, including DfT, must use a range of powers—planning controls, local air pollution emissions controls, fiscal and other economic measures—to ensure that these limits are met.

  66.  The Treasury is clearly hugely important and has made some important moves towards setting the right economic framework to deliver a low carbon economy. It has not however been anything like as bold as it needs to be. The Climate Change Levy was an important step towards progressive green taxation. However, its implementation has been confusing. It is unclear whether the tax is a tax on energy use or on carbon emissions. Practically speaking it is both as it applies to direct use of emitting fuels and indirect emissions arising from electricity. In terms of acting as a carbon tax, however, it fails to grade taxation according to the carbon content of fuels and therefore fails to incentivise a switch to cleaner fuels. As an energy tax it fails to properly incentivise behavioural change as it is set a too low a level to make a difference to the companies who pay it. Energy intensive companies who would be affected by a tax, even one set this low, are required instead to meet a voluntary emissions reduction agreement that is negotiated with DEFRA.

  67.  The Treasury has a potentially important role to play in the development of UK and International climate policy. The Chancellor could champion root and branch reform of IFIs for example to ensure that all loan and finance agreements for energy infrastructure projects meet minimum efficiency standards and maximum emissions limits. He could also encourage the setting up of new adaptation and mitigation funds to help poorer countries tackle climate change.

  68.  Closer to home he will need to integrate the management of carbon emissions into the budget. From 2008 the level of our emissions will become a potential asset or liability, with a price attached. The Chancellor could and should manage our carbon budget on behalf of all of Government in such a way that minimises the risk that the public purse will need to pick up the bill as a result of us failing to meet our international targets, and maximises the financial benefit we would accrue from making early and cost effective reductions in our emissions.









Department for International Development

  69.  The UK is a significant shareholder in many Multilateral Development Banks (MDBs), and DFID is the UK Government department with responsibility for formulating and communicating UK policy for MDBs. MDB investment portfolios in extractive industries and power generation are currently weighted heavily towards fossil fuels. DFID support for existing MDB policy contradicts the UK Government aim of promoting global action on climate change through promotion of low carbon energy technologies.

  70.  International financial institutions play a significant role in development of global energy infrastructure through provision of direct loans, and facilitation of private finance through guarantees and insurance. IFI energy finance is heavily weighted towards fossil fuels, which, eg comprise 83% of World Bank energy portfolio, while renewables comprise 14%.

  71.  The lifetime of this energy infrastructure is of the order of 40 years or more. Thus present day investment in fossil fuel locking-in to considerable period of fossil fuel dependence. In the case of IFI's this is often in countries with poor existing energy infrastructure and huge potential to follow less carbon intensive development pathways.

  72.  IFI financed projects make a significant contribution to global fossil fuel infrastructure and hence greenhouse gas emissions. Friends of the Earth estimates that over the last 10 years IFIs have provided at least $110 billion for fossil fuel projects. Since 1992 the World Bank alone has provided over $11 billion for fossil fuel projects, this included $4 billion for oil projects, of which over 80% were export oriented. The cumulative lifetime ghg emissions from these World Bank financed projects is estimated at 47 billion tons of CO2.

  73.  IFI finance of fossil fuel projects promotes society's continued dependence on high carbon energy technologies in a number of ways. IFI are providing substantial levels of funding for fossil fuel projects, but its significance is greater than a simple calculation of total finance. IFI funding guarantees political stability, insures the deal, reducing the associated risk and therefore the cost of private capital, effectively subsidising fossil fuel production, and ultimately consumption. The benefits of IFI subsidy are enjoyed by Kyoto signatories and non-signatories alike.

  74.  The recent World Bank Extractive Industry Review (EIR) concluded that IFI funding of extractive industries fails to alleviate poverty and promote development, and recommended a moratorium on World Bank funding of coal projects, and a 2008 phase-out from oil in order to meet the challenge of climate change. The EIR also recommended a rapid switch of World Bank energy finance renewable energy.

  75.  Renewable energy technologies have huge potential in developing countries. The G8 renewable energy task force identified lack of finance as the key barrier to deployment of renewables, and suggested that with concerted action, in a decade 200 million people in developing countries could have access to significantly improved biomass cooking, and access to electricity for up to 800 million, including 600 million in developing countries

  76.  There is substantial evidence to demonstrate that developing countries whose economies are heavily dependent on extractive industries display poor developmental outcomes. Furthermore, the emissions generated when these fuels are combusted contribute to climate change—itself the biggest threat to global sustainable development. IFI finance should be redirected away from high carbon energy sources, and towards provision of sustainable renewable energy.

  77.  DFID must acknowledge the significant contribution to promotion of fossil fuels represented by IFIs, and work to divert public funding away from projects which lock us into high emissions pathways and to support instead truly sustainable renewable energy developments. DFID should cease support for high emitting fossil fuel development through IFI finance and bilateral aid, and address the lack of financing available for low carbon and renewable energy technologies.

  Specifically:

  78.  DFID should adopt a climate policy consistent with UK Government aspirations for global action to avoid dangerous levels of climate change.

  79.  DFID should assess its current and historical support for fossil fuels and whether these projects have helped or undermined the meeting of Millennium Development Goals.

  80.  DFID should formulate a strategy to address the causes of climate change to augment its strategy for adaptation. This must involve a coherent strategy of support for sustainable low carbon and renewable energy provision in developing countries, including timings and targets, and withdrawal of support for high emitting fossil fuel projects over a clear timetable. Minimum efficiency and maximum emission standards should be set for all energy infrastructure projects to facilitate the development of only the best available technologies.

  81.  DFID should promote G8 Rnewable Energy Task Force recommendations of enhanced IFI support for renewables through increased R&D, subsidy programmes, capacity building and finance.

  82.  DFID should take a proactive responsibility for its votes in multilateral development banks, requiring a rigorous assessment of the cumulative impacts of projects, and their climate impacts, and only vote in favour of projects which have a significant and demonstrable poverty alleviation benefit. These assessments should be published on DFID's website.

References:

  Papers presented to EA/INECE International Conference on Compliance and Enforcement of Trading Schemes in Environmental Protection, Oxford, 17-18 March 2004.

  Greenhouse Gas Market 2003—emerging but fragmented, IETA, December 2003.

  Linking Domestic and Industry Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Systems, by Erik Haites in association with Fiona Mullins for EPRI, IEA and IETA, October 2001.


36   Neither "company level" nor "private sector" is a truly adequate descriptor, in practice Governments themselves will be involved in these schemes as they themselves are point sources of emissions (eg schools, hospitals). "Installation level" or "point source" emissions trading would be an alternative but this too fails to capture the fact that in future, mobile sources of emissions, for example, aeroplanes, and, sources of emissions that are derived from down stream consumption, eg petrol producers, are likely to be participants in these schemes. "Sub-national" might work but this becomes confusing when you consider sub-national participants can trade internationally. Back

37   An interesting side effect of the EU ETS also enabling the use of international project credits for compliance, is that companies and countries will now be competing to secure low cost credits from overseas projects (CERs). If supply is limited this will push the price up above abatement costs for in-country emissions reductions reflected in the price of European Allowance Units (EAUs). Emissions in the EU will in reality be able to be achieved relatively cost effectively and with a reasonably high degree of certainty so the relative price of CERs and EAUs will be carefully monitored by companies in the scheme when deciding on abatement strategies. Back

38   Point Carbon 03.11.04 RUSSIA KEEN TO LINK TO EMISSIONS TRADING SCHEMES Back

39   Dow Jones Newswire 11/11/04 EU Emissions Rules To Hit Aluminum Competitiveness. Back

40   "Department for Transport "The Future of Transport: a network for 2030" (July 2004) chapter 10. Back

41   "The Future of Transport" chapter 1. Back

42   Environmental Audit Committee "Budget 2004 and Energy" (August 2004) paragraph 46. Back

43   Department for Transport "Full Guidance on Local Transport Plans Second Edition" (August 2004) chapter 3 paragraph 76. Back

44   Interdepartmental Analysts Group "Long-term reductions in greenhouse gas emissions in the UK" (September 2002). Back

45   Tyndall Centre "How can we reduce carbon emissions from transport?" (July 2004). Back

46   Details of the Way to Go campaign's manifesto and how much it would cost to implement are contained in "Paying for Better Transport", available at http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/paying-for-better-transport.pdf. Back

47   Environmental Audit Committee "Aviation: Sustainability and the Government's Second Response" (September 2004) paragraph 3. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 29 March 2005