Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 420-439)

PAUL DAWSON, LOUIS REDSHAW AND CHARLES DONOVAN

12 JANUARY 2005

  Q420 Joan Walley: It is a question of how you get a level playing field, if everybody is contributing fairly and equitably.

  Mr Redshaw: Yes.

  Q421 Joan Walley: Can I ask you as well about extending the scheme and if you have comments about extending it to other greenhouse gases—we have really just been talking about carbon—what would be the implications of that?

  Mr Donovan: We have seen in a couple of situations now where the non-CO2 gases, the cost of reducing those gases is really quite diverse, and so you have seen incidences, particularly in the emerging CDM market, where reductions have been made in HFCs at very, very low cost; and there are instances where it is actually much more expensive, so we are not seeing perhaps renewable energy projects come through in the developing countries that was in fact part of the objective of the CDM. So wider coverage and more gases in some sense is a good idea because you get more opportunities and you get more gasses, but we also know that the costs of reducing all of those now we have just made a much bigger pool and we may end up resetting the supply and demand equation, and where that comes out we want to make sure that that is consistent. So there has to be thinking that it is not just a positive in terms of bringing in, we have to know that economists use this marginal cost of abatement, and there is a marginal cost of abatement for greenhouse gasses across all of those different sectors, across all of the different countries, across all of the different types of greenhouse gases, and some thinking needs to go into at what point and how do you bring in those types of sectors, gases and countries into a trading scheme?

  Mr Redshaw: Just to expand on that a little further. Our view, like with increasing the sectors that are covered, is to increase the gases that are included because the more opportunities you have to reduce, again the more efficient the reduction that can take place. What I am reading from Charlie's evidence there is that if you suddenly introduce a new gas into the Trading Scheme that has a very low cost abatement you will send our a price signal—in fact you will drop the price of CO2 allowances which will cause an aberration. So these things need to be done carefully. An example would be methane capture. In the UK you have to capture the methane from a landfill gas site and flare it, and methane per tonne has a global warming potential of 21 times that of CO2. In other countries—I am not certain how it works across the EU—of the world there is no legislation for the capture of that gas, so you have a slightly un-level playing field already with one country potentially making money out of capturing gas when another country has to do it already through legislation. So there are some potential distortions, so it needs to be done with some consideration of the full picture.

  Mr Donovan: I really believe that Emissions Trading is a very, very powerful tool for what we are trying to do, but that does not preclude the possibility that dealing with some greenhouse gases may be better done through traditional forms of regulation.

  Q422 Joan Walley: I am exploring the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme just that little bit further. Do you think that there could be other key improvements in what comes out at the stage of Phase 2? What sort of changes do you think would be helpful to see in there?

  Mr Dawson: I think it would help to have a more streamlined and common approach to the determination of the National Allocation Plans, and I think it would be good to get those agreed sooner rather than later. Inevitably when the scheme was being introduced over such a short timescale there was always going to be delays in putting the Plans together and getting those agreed. I think having done that once I would certainly hope that Member State governments and the Commission could curtail and streamline the process for agreeing the Plans the next time around, and I think a common allocation methodology in terms of allocating the allowances between sectors would be hugely valuable.

  Mr Redshaw: And common ways of treating new entrances and common rules for closure of plant across the whole of the EU.

  Q423 Joan Walley: Common laws of?

  Mr Redshaw: Of closure, the definition of closure of a plant. So in Germany, for example, you could close an inefficient coal fired power station on one site in one part of Germany and the same company could open another power station in another part of Germany that is a clean gas fired power station. They can transfer the allowances from one to the other and actually make a profit out of being cleaner. The UK, if you close your power station you lose allowances and walk away and if you open another gas fired power station then you would get an allocation from a new entrant reserve, which per megawatt hour produced by a power station would be lower than you would have got from a coal station. So in Germany you have a bigger incentive to be cleaner than you have in the UK in that instance.

  Q424 Joan Walley: Which could well be uncompetitive as well.

  Mr Redshaw: Because the compartmentalisation of electricity markets it is difficult to say if there would be any competition issues as such, but it would certainly be a more level playing field if those rules were common.

  Q425 Joan Walley: None of you have mentioned about the possible use of greater use of auctioning or having a single European-wide emissions cap. Not important?

  Mr Redshaw: I guess they are attempting to achieve the same objective. A single auction would undo the good work that has been done, giving free allocations to companies that are facing international competition. A single cap for the EU would have to be sub-divided into companies and countries nonetheless.

  Mr Dawson: And unlike Phase 1 of the scheme Phase 2 takes place in the context of the first Kyoto commitment period, where country targets are already determined. So it becomes a lot easier to crosscheck the National Allocation Plan against the Kyoto target rather than arguing about whether or not you are on the path in three years' time to the Kyoto target.

  Q426 Joan Walley: Having said that, you are not saying that Phase 2 is already set in stone and there is not any flexibility or changes that can be made moving from Phase 1 to Phase 2?

  Mr Dawson: I think that is true, but I do not think—

  Q427 Joan Walley: You think it is set in stone?

  Mr Dawson: I do not think it is set in stone but I think there is less flexibility in Phase 2 because of the Kyoto commitment.

  Q428 Joan Walley: So we are set on the track that we are going down?

  Mr Redshaw: If a country objects to that or is not particularly happy about the Kyoto target they have signed up to—and one is—then the further socialisation of that would be unpopular in one and popular in another.

  Q429 Joan Walley: I am sorry, which country were you referring to?

  Mr Redshaw: There are countries that have gone past their CO2 emission limit by quite a large amount—Greece, Portugal, Spain, Ireland—and there are countries that have got very close to their emission reductions, such as Germany and the UK, and to then turn around and ask those countries to make further reductions is probably rather problematic, having negotiated the reductions that are already being met, and in the case of Portugal and Spain they have actually negotiated increases under their Kyoto target.

  Q430 Mr Savidge:   Joan's line of questioning has been basically talking about Phase 2 and I would like you to look beyond 2012 and picking up one of the questions Joan has asked. With the Barclays' Blueprint you are talking in terms of including air and road transport, commercial and domestic sectors and therefore almost creating a situation where other policy instruments might be redundant if everything would depend on international ETS. I wondered whether you think that we need more evidence of Emissions Trading working before we can go quite that far?

  Mr Dawson: I think it is an interesting perspective because I maybe see it from the other end of the barrel. Many of the difficulties associated with Emissions Trading as it is currently being implemented are associated to some extent with Emissions Trading not going far enough. It is not including other sectors, so some sectors are saying, "Why are we getting a reduction target when transport"—as a classic example—"is allowed to go on increasing its emissions unmitigated?" Part of the problem with ensuring Kyoto ratification has been that some countries—one in particular—deciding not to accept an emissions target when other countries are not going to mitigate their emissions. I think the arguments tend to be on who gets what and to some extent that is inevitable, but I do not think that that undermines the theoretical purity of Emissions Trading, which is that it has an absolute cap on emissions. You know what the reduction in emissions is going to be and you let people trade and it delivers that reduction at the least cost. Many of the so-called difficulties of Emissions Trading are either associated with arguing about who bears that burden or associated with any form of scheme to reduce emissions. The classic example would be the monitoring and verification. Any scheme of emissions reduction must monitor what emissions are reduced by whom, and that is as much the case for Emissions Trading as any other form of global reduction. So I think more ambitious plans to introduce Emissions Trading would improve things immeasurably and remove a lot of the current disagreements.

  Mr Redshaw: And making it truly international removes even more problems, in that we talked earlier about the UK government giving 100% allocation to companies that are competing on the international arena. If every country in the world is facing the same cost production of CO2 as every other company you are in a situation where you have a completely level playing field. At the moment all companies that consume oil pay the same price for oil and therefore there is no competitive distortion because of different oil prices because everyone pays the same price. If that cost is then increased by forcing companies to pay for their CO2 as well, but on an equitable basis across the whole world, then you have a level playing field.

  Q431 Mr Savidge: Charles, would you like to comment further on this issue of the idea of an international Emissions Trading System as the all-encompassing policy instrument, because you spoke in your submission about a wider range of policies and you have already mentioned the possibility of the need for regulation in relation to greenhouse gases, but I wondered if there were other policies also that you felt ought to be used?

  Mr Donovan: The most important thing for me—and while it is enjoyable to try to explain all of the fine details about what is going to happen in the next few years—we have a massive, massive undertaking ahead of us, and that is where the focus should be just as much as on some of these details we have gone over in probably excruciating detail today. So in terms of looking at the long-term, Emissions Trading is just one tool and I think the thing that I tried to highlight in my memo was, yes, the policies that we have in place now need to be implemented effectively, and that is the very first thing that we could do with any kind of leadership that would arise from the Presidencies of the G8 and the EU. But the other—and really responding to your question directly about long-term—we need a massive undertaking in social and technological research in order to get to the kind of goals that we are talking about, and it is not going to be sufficient to play around at the margin with some of the rules of the scheme as we currently know it. That one instrument—it would be impossible to deliver the kind of investment that we are talking about, simply using one policy tool; it is a fallacy to think that we could rely so heavily on one instrument. So there is a mix of things. But I think as the paper that Barclays drew up pointed out very, very accurately, Emissions Trading could be the lead in that and if you bring everything under that umbrella you start to have a fairly coherent vision of one of the major pieces that could help deliver.

  Q432 Mr Savidge: An International ETS system will be immensely administratively complex and costly. Is there a natural geographical limit to the scale on which an ETS can work, and beyond which it will become too complex or insufficiently efficient to operate? I ask that generally.

  Mr Redshaw: We are in an international Emissions Trading Scheme right now with the EU ETS. You talk about it being costly but any system whereby you have to monitor and verify emissions, be it for taxation purposes or for any other compliance obligations put on companies, the cost of that verification is going to be the same, and the additional cost of Trading Emissions versus being taxed is nominal. We do not believe that the geographical constraints exist either. If the US, for example, would accept a cap on their emissions that was similar to the EU's and therefore would allow the two systems to operate together, it would be simplicity itself. There is nothing to stop me having an office in Bermuda and trading emissions on behalf of customers with the aid of electronic platforms, et cetera. I guess the difficulty comes with verification of emissions, but so long as you have—as we have highlighted in our blueprint—audited emissions from companies and governments underwriting their companies' emissions you avoid companies cheating and you put countries on the hook and so avoid countries cheating, and I imagine the electronic nature of trading means that the administrative burden is actually very small.

  Chairman: We have to go and take part in a division; I am sorry about that. I think there will only be one, so if you could bear with us until just around 5 o'clock. We should be back within the next five minutes or so, and we can then carry on.

  The Committee suspended from 4.35 pm to 4.43 pm for a division in the House   Chairman: We can now start again.

  Q433 Mr Savidge: As we were saying before we were interrupted, your Emissions Trading System you suggest expanding it to expand the EU ETS. Might it be more feasible to think in terms of linking the EU system to other trading systems like the one in US and Canada and so on? Might that be the more practical approach for seeking a single worldwide trading system? Again, perhaps you would like to say something about how feasible you think it would be to get a single worldwide trading system at all?

  Mr Dawson: In terms of an extension of the ETS we were talking much more in terms of extending the concept of the ETS and that would require a global agreement, rather than extending the ETS in and of itself: ie trying to agree an international scheme that looked relevantly similar. I think that carries over to consideration of linking to other schemes. I think that the key element of an effective Emissions Trading Scheme is that there is an absolute cap on emissions and the ability to trade those emissions to meet that cap. I think the problem with some of the other so-called Emissions Trading Schemes is that they include relative caps on emissions where credit is given for emitting less than a certain established baseline, where that baseline typically is still upwards and emissions continue to grow. I think you see that within the project-based credits under the Kyoto Protocol and the CDM-JI. I do not know too much about the Canadian scheme—I think Louis can talk a bit more about that. I think unless they have that inherent cap and trade—absolute cap, not a relative cap—then it becomes very difficult to link into a scheme like the EU's. The danger is that you allow credits to be given a common currency within the EU when they are achieved in economies and countries where emissions are actually continuing to grow, and you are thereby devaluing the absolute reduction of emissions that you are achieving through the cap.

  Mr Redshaw: So absolutely, linking of any trading scheme to the EU ETS is desirable because it broadens the scope and increases the opportunity to reduce at a lower cost. The Norwegians are actively seeking to link their scheme to the EU scheme—of course they are not part of the EU. The trouble with the current American scheme is that it is a voluntary scheme and emission credits over there trade for between half a dollar and a dollar. It is voluntary; there is no price signal. If the price in a voluntary scheme got high people will just walk away from it. In the EU scheme if the price gets higher people have to pay more for it because they have to comply—there is a finite supply of emissions allowances. So there is no prospect at all of linking with the existing US trading scheme—and it is not a US trading scheme, it is actually a group of companies that have got together and put this thing together. There is also no prospect, in our view, of a link with the Canadian scheme, for the reasons that Paul has highlighted, but, in addition, the Canadian government intends to cap the cost of CO2 at 15 Canadian dollars, which is around eight or nine Euros. That means that you could not have the EU scheme working hand in hand with the Canadian scheme because if the going gets tough Canadian companies can go and buy allowances from their government, essentially, and, okay, so there is a potential gateway to stop the allowances going into the EU. But if the allowance price in the EU is 12 Euros European companies cannot buy Canadian allowances to meet their requirement; but if the price is lower in the EU, say six Euros, then Canadian companies can buy EU allowances and comply with their obligations with those EU allowances. These are some of the ideas that have been floating around. Which means actually that you are going to drive the price of the EU allowances up for European companies because there is no two-way street. The chance of linking with those are extremely slim until those schemes are designed so that they are comparable to the EU scheme. We will definitely encourage that linkage but there are hurdles that need to be overcome before it can ever happen.

  Q434 Mr Savidge: You suggest using a potential finance tariff levied against non-participating countries as a way of encouraging compliance. Do you feel that a similar measure might be appropriate in the short-term as far as addressing competitiveness issues are concerned?

  Mr Redshaw: What it does is give that level playing field that everybody is looking for and actually incentivises, because if you have a country that is facing, as, say, the US is facing an import duty into the EU, that company not only is competing on a level playing field with EU companies but actually back at home their costs are probably higher because they are potentially less efficient. So what that does is to incentivise those companies to push for Emissions Trading within their own countries and those countries then to adopt Emissions Trading in order that there is a truly level playing field for those countries that do not have emissions caps. So it is a highly complex subject; you could not just slap a tariff on imports of certain goods: (a) you have to work out what the what the CO2 intensity of that good is, which is no simple feat—the CO2 intensity will vary from one country to another and one factory to another within that country—and (b) of course you have the issue of the WDO.

  Q435 Mr Challen: This is to Mr Dawson and Mr Redshaw. You say on page 5 of your document, which Mr Savidge has described as the "Barclays' Blueprint", that "The agreement on a common per capita allowance in 2062 represents a `fair' ultimate allocation of allowances," which sounds to me like you are moving towards a Contraction and Convergence model, as put forward by the Global Commons Institute; I do not know if you are familiar with that?

  Mr Redshaw: Yes.

  Q436 Mr Challen: Does that represent the corporate view of Barclays Capital or the corporate view of the Barclays' group of companies? To what extent has that view been accepted within the organisation?

  Mr Dawson: I think we were using that as an example of an approach that might be used as opposed to proposing it as a Barclays' view. Clearly it is one way in which you could envisage reaching some form of consensus on who should ultimately get the rights on that carbon dioxide. I think in trying to propose an international scheme we were looking for a benchmark that might prove acceptable, and at some future date, obviously.

  Q437 Mr Challen: From your knowledge of Barclays as a whole do you think that such views would be welcome or acceptable?

  Mr Dawson: I think Barclays is very committed to its environmental responsibilities. I cannot say that that position is Barclays' position but I know that Barclays has a strong commitment to environmental matters.

  Mr Redshaw: In terms of efficiency of trading there will be minor impacts on the cost of metals production in Europe and on the cost of refining oil products. To the extent that there is a truly level playing field for international commodity trading, certainly from the commodities desks' perspective the fewer distortions the better.

  Q438 Chairman: Can I pursue that a little further? We have a document here, Barclays Capital Memorandum, with Barclays' logo on every page. Are we to assume that these are some personal opinions from you two and not an official document submitted by Barclays?

  Mr Redshaw: The way we approached this is we were asked to submit evidence and we sat down—Paul is an economist and I am a trader—and we attempted to determine what would iron out the problems as we see them with the current EU ETS and the Kyoto mechanisms, and if you want to satisfy the requirements of, say, the United States, who insist on developing countries being included in the trading scheme, and the developing countries saying, "Why should we be in it if the US are not in it?" and if you want to satisfy what we would perceive as just fairness, you come out with the solution that we have.

  Q439 Chairman: You make a very compelling case and your document is extremely helpful and, if I may say so, extremely well written. I just think it might be helpful to all concerned if the whole might of the Barclays machine got behind this agenda and started talking to the government about it and to the EU and to the US. You have that kind of power to do that.

  Mr Dawson: We are here representing Barclays. You have correctly pointed out that the document has Barclays written on it and we have agreed its contents with our colleagues.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 29 March 2005