Select Committee on Environmental Audit Second Report


To comply, or not to comply?

37. A constant theme throughout this series of inquiries into environmental crime has been the fact that, in many cases, the criminal justice system currently offers no effective deterrent. The likelihood that an offender will be caught is relatively slim. The penalties handed down, in the vast majority of the comparatively very few cases that make it to court, are derisory and in no way reflect the damage caused to the environment or indeed the cost of making good that damage.

The threat of detection and prosecution

38. Time and again over the course of our inquiries into environmental crime, it has been brought home to us that unless there is a real threat of being detected, the offender will continue to offend. We cannot stress strongly enough the importance of the threat of detection as a deterrent.

39. During an oral evidence session, the Federation of Small Businesses (FSB) provided some insight into one of the reasons why the threat of detection and prosecution is an empty one. Mr Holbrow told us,

"…not all cases are prosecuted, and there is a very patchy regime throughout the country from the Environment Agency. What happens in some cases would not occur in another part of the country, and we would like to see a more uniform approach throughout the country so that we do have a more level playing-field. We get members in one part of the country that will get prosecuted for doing the very same thing that occurs in another part of the country, and nothing happens."[39]

Mr Holbrow's comments highlight the fundamental problem that if companies can see that either they, or their competitors in a neighbouring county, are unlikely to be detected and then prosecuted, they may be less inclined to devote time and money to ensuring compliance with environmental laws and regulations. The fact that there is a perceived inconsistency of approach employed by the Environment Agency in prosecuting environmental crime around the country is unhelpful and worrying and must be addressed by the Environment Agency as a matter of urgency.

40. Furthermore, a number of the memoranda provided to the Sub-committee expressed the view that the Agency was focusing on so-called soft targets, those companies which it already regulates and which, it would argue, are more compliant than those in the un-regulated sector. Anglian Water certainly makes this point in its written evidence to the Sub-committee when it describe itself as, "a point of primary focus for the Environment Agency."[40] This was echoed by ESA in its written evidence when they too argued that the Agency was not sufficiently focused on the right sector. We do not agree with the argument that certain sectors are in some way being singled out for harsher treatment than others simply because it is easier to do so; if an environmental regulation is being infringed then the Agency has every right and indeed a duty to act against the offender. Where we do have some concern is with regard to the fact that the majority of incidents are, by the Agency's own reckoning, committed by those in the unregulated sector. This is not adequately policed and this imbalance must be addressed by the Agency and DEFRA

41. Of course, detection and prosecution, even when they work properly, are still only part of the answer, and if there is little chance that the offender will face a punishment which in any way dissuades him or her from committing the offence in the first place, not to mention re-offending, then that enforcement activity is a waste of time and resources. It is a process which requires a linear approach, as Mr Walker of ESA explained well when he said:

"[The crime] needs to be detected, then prosecuted and then you need penalties in place. Key to all of that is having better levels of detection […]You could have much higher penalties, but if there is very little chance of detection, they are not going to act as a deterrent."[41]

Fines as a deterrent

42. The importance of the level of fine becomes even more apparent when applied to a corporate body if, as we have been told, many businesses currently see the payment of fines as the cheaper option to full environmental compliance, and even set aside funds for this purpose. The Agency was clear that this was a problem when it told us that, "the level of fines really is not sufficient to make much of an impact on the companies."[42] This sentiment was echoed by the Environmental Industries Commission in its written evidence when it said,

"Low fines send the wrong message in trying to create a culture where environmental compliance is taken seriously by industry. The experience of EIC members is that companies too often find it more economical to pay a fine than to properly address their environmental performance […] current fines for environmental offences are both too low and inconsistent […] they need to be dramatically raised to have a real economic impact and deter companies from polluting the environment".[43]

43. The disparity between the fines awarded, and the turnover of some of the companies involved, was starkly demonstrated by Thames and Anglian Water. Thames Water told us that in 2003 it accrued fines totalling approximately £70,000 but its turnover was in the region of £1.1 billion. Similarly, Anglian Water estimated that it had received fines of approximately £50,000 in 2003 and had a turn-over of some £750 million.[44] These sums of money are as nothing when compared to the profits made by these companies. They also enjoy a monopoly in that their customers cannot vote with their feet and move to another supplier.

44. As we have already seen, the Ministry of Sound was very clear on the reasons why it no longer used fly-posting to promote its record releases: it was not because of fear of prosecution or a hefty fine. As Mr Holman told us, it was "not because of pressure from local authorities, but because it was not the most effective way of getting the message across to the public".[45] This statement was qualified later in the evidence session when Mr Holman conceded that the company had "cut back on our activity in fly-posting because it has become a sensitive issue with the local authorities."[46] Asked if fines were a deterrent in his company's particular circumstances the answer was unequivocally no. Mr Holman went on to say that, "if there was a penalty regime that was being implemented quite strongly it would be a bigger incentive not to fly-post".[47] Mr Holman was then asked whether, as a company director, he was concerned about the possible use against him or other senior members of the company of the lifestyle provisions of the Proceeds of Crime Act 2002, whereby all of an offender's assets may be regarded as being the benefits of criminal activity. He thought this was a "fairly extreme penalty" and a "heavy reaction…only appropriate in cases of continuous failure to observe a more measured response".[48]

45. The Ministry of Sound is a perfect, but by no means unique, example of why, for certain companies, the current system and level of fines simply do not and will never work. It is sanguine about being contacted by the local council and being asked to remove illegal posters—it will, it says, act within 48 hours to get the offending articles removed. The current level of fine offers no greater threat and is without doubt insignificant to a business of its size. For the Ministry of Sound, and for many other companies, the bottom line is the bottom line, and, unless their profit margin is seriously compromised, then such companies are unlikely to take action to stop their illegal activity. When asked whether the company felt under any pressure to comply with environmental regulations, Mr Holman told us that the pressures were not very great:

"We are not a public company. It is not that Ministry of Sound is not high profile but we do not have quite the sensitivity of large companies with shareholders and there are not any City pressure groups. Clearly, we do not like paying fines and we always try to avoid paying fines if we can. If we are given 48 hours to get the posters down we get them down. Clearly, if we were being hit on the bottom line and our profit was being seriously affected by draconian penalties we might react more rapidly, apart from banning the whole thing, which is presumably where we might end up."[49]

For those companies and organisations who are not dissuaded from their illegal activity by the threat of detection, prosecution and sentencing, whether that be a financial penalty or, in a very few and extreme cases, a custodial sentence, other means have to be found to ensure their compliance with environmental laws and regulations.


39   Ev43 Back

40   EC4-17 para 11 Back

41   Ev23 Back

42   Ev12 Back

43   EC4-06 Back

44   Ev31 Back

45   Ev49 Back

46   Ev50 Back

47   Ev51 Back

48   Ev51-52 Back

49   Ev50 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 8 February 2005