Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by CBI

1.   In 1997, the Treasury set out in its Statement of Intent on Environmental Taxation that it would seek to shift the burden of taxation from "goods" to "bads" in line with the polluter pays principle. But data from ONS suggests that, in percentage terms, the revenue from environmental taxes has fallen to its lowest level since 1993. In view of the fact that we are now approaching the end of the Government's second term, what overall progress do you think that Government has made against this agenda? What is the scope for further progress in next Parliament?

2.   To what extent do you consider that the Statement of Intent, and the related document Tax and the Environment: Using Economic Instruments (2002), sets out a strategic aim rather than a specific strategy involving regular process of research, target setting and monitoring? How could the Treasury's approach be improved in this respect in order to underpin its environmental PSA objective?

  The CBI welcomed the Treasury's 1997 Statement of Intent on Environmental Taxation and its elaboration in the PBR 2002 paper, "Tax and the Environment: Using Economic Instruments", in particular the emphasis on policy-making supported by rigorous economic analysis and the commitment to well-designed taxes that meet objectives without undesirable side-effects. These documents outlined sound criteria for selecting and designing appropriate policy instruments, including assessment of:

    —  effects on the competitiveness of sectors which are subject to international competition;

    —  effects on competition within industry sectors;

    —  compliance costs of implementing and administering a measure, including cost to government and to business and other groups; and

    —  distributional effects of a policy on different groups within the population as a whole.

  The Treasury also committed itself to reviewing policies over time in consultation with stakeholders. The CBI is aware that some progress has been made in this regard on individual taxes. For example, HMT commitment to flexibility in policy is evident in the:

    —  complete exemptions for electricity generated from CHP or coal mine methane, and certain recycling process, from the CCL introduced in PBR 2002, and

    —  widening of the criteria for access to Climate Change Agreements beyond IPPC sectors in 2004—although this does not eliminate all distortions in the CCL package, it does allow some additional energy-intensive sectors to access the discount on the CCL.

  However, these changes to the CCL are largely in response to business lobbying and fall short of meeting the Treasury's stated aims, that is to review UK experience with environmental taxes and to show "how the Government can meet existing and evolving objectives in the most efficient way". There has been little comparison of what environmental gains have been made through the use of different instruments. Without knowing, for example, how much greenhouse gas emissions have been reduced through the CCL, it is hard to judge whether the levy itself, the negotiated agreements or other initiatives like the Carbon Trust or enhanced capital allowances are the most efficient and effective way of meeting the government's objectives.

  The Treasury should review its overall approach to environmental taxes, in particular its monitoring procedures, to improve the transparency and effectiveness of such taxes and to amend where unintended consequences have occurred. Such a review should include:

    —  assessment of role of environmental tax within the broader policy context eg as move toward establishing a market for carbon under the EU ETS, what is the continuing role of the CCL?

    —  the effectiveness of taxes to-date, against the objectives they were designed to promote and compared with other policy measures;

    —  the lessons which can be transferred from experience of one tax to another;

    —  quantification of the level of environmental taxation in aggregate, within the broader context of UK taxation, now and in future years;

    —  justification of whether the balance of environmental taxes between business and non-business is appropriate;

    —  an assessment of the effectiveness in maintaining the government's commitment to revenue neutrality and how, in the event that revenue generated turns out to be greater or less than expected, it manages that commitment in practice over time.

3.   Is there inconsistency in the way in which the Government is implementing the polluter pays principle? The government is, for example, increasing substantially the rate of Landfill Tax, and yet appears to have rejected a tax on incineration—even though the environmental costs associated with incineration may be higher.

  Following the Cabinet Office's Strategy Unit 2002 report "Waste not, want not", Government commissioned two independent studies on the environmental and health impacts and costs of municipal solid waste disposal (a science study by Enviros and Birmingham University and an economic study by Enviros). The findings of these two studies were summarised by HM Customs & Excise in an attempt to value the impacts of different disposal options.

  While the HM Customs & Excise summary valuation of costs shows that in the central case, environmental costs of incineration may be higher than the environmental costs of disposal to landfill, we believe that the Treasury's rejection of a tax on incineration is the correct one for the following reasons:

    —  the HM Customs & Excise study emphasised that there are significant uncertainties involved in measuring and valuing the environmental effects of different waste management options and that the estimates of the external costs of landfill and incineration have wide margins of error attached to them—sensitivity analysis shows that the external costs of landfill could be higher than that of incineration if alter assumptions with regard to fugitive releases of methane gases from landfill or to the benefits of displaced power generation;

    —  incineration is currently a relatively small component of waste management in the UK; and

    —  the increase in the rate of landfill tax aims to incentivise producers to minimise waste arisings and divert waste from landfill, helping Government to achieve its legal commitment under the landfill directive to reduce reliance on landfill—incineration has a role to play in achieving this commitment and a tax on incineration could confuse the economic signal to producers to divert waste from landfill.

4.   Should the level of environmental taxes be determined by the need to achieve policy goals rather than simply by the scale of environmental costs (as indeed is the case with the Landfill Tax, where the rate will increase far above the environmental costs associated with it)?

  The aim of environmental taxes is to internalise the environmental externalities, thereby encouraging an appropriate market response. Theoretically, therefore, the rate of environmental tax should reflect the scale of environmental costs, rather than policy goals. Where policy goals are not directly guided by environmental costing, the Government's criteria for assessing different policy options (outlined in point 2) are particularly relevant.

5.   Do you consider that, as in the case of fuel duty, there is greater scope to use environmental taxes as major revenue earners? What should the balance be here between environmental taxes and taxes on labour and corporate profits?

  CBI supports the Government's commitment to recycle revenue raised from some environmental taxes (eg CCL, landfill tax and aggregates levy) as a way of ensuring broad revenue neutrality, in keeping with the Treasury's intention to shift the burden of taxation from "goods" to "bads".

  However, the rise in employers National Insurance Contributions, the primary means of recycling revenue from the CCL and the landfill tax, has knocked business confidence in future claims regarding revenue neutrality.

  We recognise that there are practical and political difficulties in demonstrating revenue neutrality, but to gain business trust, Government must:

    —  elaborate how it aims to maintain revenue neutrality over time; and

    —  improve data and transparency of how revenue is being recycled to business.

6.   Do you accept that there will need to be large increases in the price of fossil fuel energy in order to address climate change, and that the significant fall in the real price of road transport and petrol over the last five years will therefore need to be addressed?

  There are a number of elements to the cost of road use, including vehicle, petrol and insurance. When dealing with environmental costs, Government needs to look at the effectiveness of the range of policy measures in place, and determine the aggregate costs to the motorist of these measures. The range of measures include:

    —  incentivising change of behaviour through price (for example, increase real price of petrol), however, road use emissions are sensitive to traffic conditions that vary by time and place, yet fuel duty is not particularly effective as a way of encouraging efficient driver responses to such conditions; and

    —  improvements in vehicle efficiency (through changes in company car tax and voluntary agreements)—changes in company car tax appear to be having some positive effect, but the thrust of the government's approach has been to increase the burden of taxation on use (eg fuel duty) rather than vehicle ownership.

  Taxes paid by motorists raise approximately £38 billion per annum, yet only £6 billion of this is spent on transport—better targeted spend could reduce environmental externalities associated with transport.

7.   Evidence suggests that far more stringent national targets will be required for Phase 2 of the EU ETS in order to ensure that the EU meets its Kyoto targets. Would the CBI oppose the setting of more stringent targets in the absence of similar commitments by other industrialised countries outside the EU?

  Comparison of member states progress against their Kyoto targets demonstrates that many EU member states are far from achieving their Kyoto targets. The latest Commission progress report on the European Climate Change Programme identified that EU greenhouse gas emissions were only 2.3% below their 1990 levels, with 10 of the EU-15 "a long way off track from their agreed share of the EU greenhouse gas emissions target."

  The EU emissions trading scheme requires that allocations are at least made in line with the traded sectors contribution to each member states Kyoto obligation. In Phase 1 of the scheme, indications are that allocations have been generous and that little progress has been made towards Kyoto. Far more stringent national targets will, therefore, be required for Phase 2 of the scheme.

  However, in setting targets at the UK level, it is important to note:

    —  the UK is already on track to meet its Kyoto target and the overall cap set for UK business sectors in Phase 1 of the scheme goes significantly beyond the UK's Kyoto target (even with the revised cap);

    —  setting the target for the traded sector in Phase 2, should take into account:

    —  the competitiveness impact of setting targets for the traded sector in the UK beyond those which have been set by other member states—the UK should not be required to significantly undercut its 12.5 per cent Kyoto emissions target in order to help the EU meet their Kyoto target; other member states must play their part in order to minimise competitive distortions; and

    —  in setting the overall allocation for the traded sector, the UK government should also take into account action already undertaken and growth projections in the traded sector; technical and economic potential for further emission reductions by EU ETS sectors within the given timescale, compared with potential in other sectors; comparative cost of achieving reductions in these different sectors; and the impact on UK business competitiveness, including on a sectoral basis.

  February 2005


 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 13 April 2005