Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Sea Anglers' Conservation Network (W02)

1.  THE NEED FOR CHANGE

  1.1  For a considerable period of time technological advances have considerably increased mankind's ability to extract the creatures of the sea leaving no hiding place, whilst causing irreparable damage to the marine environment that supports the ecological web that generates and regenerates future stocks.

  1.2  If the marine environment were to be fully restored and sympathetically harvested, in many cases the annual sustainable harvest would greatly exceed the remnant stocks that are now available.

  1.3  We have now reached the stage where decline in fish catching is inevitably leading to a slow collapse in the fishing industry, with an attendant loss of value and employment, not just for this generation, but for numerically increasing populations yet to come.

  1.4  Rather than focusing efforts in cushioning the effects of collapse upon the fish catching industry, there is a need to refocus efforts into halting and reversing the decline in the marine ecosystems, so that maximum value can be made available for sustainable benefit into the distant future.

  1.5  To achieve this will require a new mindset and culture to be adopted by fishery managers and responsible politicians, with previous unhelpful "baggage" abandoned.

  1.6  To bring about necessary change, things in the future must be done differently to how things have been managed in the past. There is a need to confront the unthinkable and boldly face reality.

  1.7  The report by the strategy unit is to be congratulated in its appreciation that the problems to be addressed go much wider than simply addressing the needs of the netting and shellfish sectors, but there is little evidence that those who are charged with implementing the report's recommendations have realised that there needs to be a fundamental reappraisal of the use that we make of our marine resources, if the netting and shellfish sectors, along with all other stakeholders, are to have a secure and sustainable future.

2.   DELIVERING "BEST VALUE"

  2.1  The marine resources are the heritage of all mankind, for all generations, and should not be regarded as the sole property of any one stakeholder for a single purpose.

  2.2  Management of the common resource must be directed at obtaining the best socio-economic value available by considering all potential uses of the stock, whether by species or by location, for the greater benefit of the population of the UK as a whole, and particularly of those rural coastal communities who are most dependent upon the appropriate management of "local" stocks and marine areas.

  2.3  Evidence contained both within the Strategy Unit's report, and the report recently produced by Drew Associates for Defra confirm similar information that has emerged from overseas that in some cases the value to be obtained by managing stocks and areas for the development of the recreational sea angling sector, and its attendant leisure and tourism potential, will greatly exceed that obtainable from simply allowing the netting sector to remove fish.

  2.4  The Drew study reports that 1.1 million households in England and Wales have at least one member who has been sea angling in the past 12 months (so the number of anglers will be much greater), directly spending £538 million (mostly subject to VAT), and with an overall value between £600 million and £1,300 million. There is considerable scope to develop the sector significantly; several fold according to evidence from overseas.

  2.5  Defra statistics value the UK catch by commercial fishermen (including shellfish, crustaceans etc) at £521 million, continuing a decline in line with declining fish stocks.

  2.6  Although there is a tendency to view such information as a source of contention between the inshore netting and shellfish sectors with the recreational sea angling sector, the needs of the differing sectors are often both non-competitive (much of the value of the other sectors is made up of species of no great interest to the recreational angling sector and vice versa) and complementary (for instance, men who know the area and its resources well can supplement a living made from shellfish during the week, by taking out angling charter boats, and providing angling guiding services etc, at the weekend).

  2.7  Where there is little possibility of developing an economy based on visitors, then it is sensible to concentrate on developing netting etc. Where an area is dependent upon visitors, it is criminal to allow the destruction of a great natural resource for the sake of benefit to just a few individual netsmen who could be better employed in the development of the recreational angling sector, increasing job opportunities for many local people, not just a few.

  2.8  It should be borne in mind that many species were almost exclusively regarded as recreational species until recently. Bass, mullet, conger, wrasse, flounder, tope are all valuable recreational species which have received considerable commercial pressure, either directly or through bycatch, as netsmen scrape around following scarcity of other species and faced with temporary closure of traditional commercial fisheries. Recreational angling is not taking away the livelihoods of netsmen, rather the reverse applies as angling declines because of pressure from netsmen and many livelihoods (charter skippers, bait suppliers, tackle shops, boat and tackle manufacturers etc) are lost from the recreational sector.

3.  STAKEHOLDER REPRESENTATION

  3.1  A failure of the current system is the practical exclusiveness of representation for those who represent the netting and shellfish sectors.

  3.2  Where representation is accorded to other stakeholder interests this is always engineered so that other stakeholders are very much in the minority, and therefore powerless to influence policy and management.

  3.3  Many a fine word has been spoken and written about according recognition of other stakeholder interests, but until such time as other stakeholders are given a real opportunity to press their case, then it will always be difficult to identify other stakeholder representatives willing to take on the considerable amount of work involved in representing their sector.

  3.4  This need of "effective" rather than symbolic representation needs to be addressed within the review, particularly if the right people with the right skills are to be motivated to make an effective contribution.

4.  THE "USER PAYS" PRINCIPLE

  4.1  The suggestion that Recreational Sea Anglers should be licensed is noted.

  4.2  Where resources have been managed principally or wholly for the benefit of recreational sea angling overseas, these schemes have sometimes involved angler contribution to the management of the resources by the way of licences.

  4.3  These schemes have often been successful and welcomed by anglers, the difficulties of enforcement and cost of collection etc being much the same as would be encountered in a UK context, yet not proving to be that difficult when applied to a scheme that has invited acceptance because of the obvious benefits delivered.

  4.4  However, the experience of UK anglers has been one of a diminishing resource caused by the (mis)management of the netting sector, and there would be a great deal of opposition to any licensing scheme that might be introduced on a "jam tomorrow" basis, especially if that licence fee were to be collected by the same authorities that many recreational anglers believe to be responsible for the decline they have experienced.

  4.5  It is evident that there is a failure to properly manage the ecology of inshore waters, and to rigorously enforce management measures.

  4.6  This, we believe is largely because of the domination of Sea Fishery Committees by commercial fishing interests and an unwillingness to take action against "brother" fishermen.

  4.7  With the Environment Agency already becoming responsible for management of estuaries and the first mile from the shore, under the Water Framework Directive, and having experience of operating as the Sea Fisheries Committee in some areas, and with experience of gathering and using biological and ecological data to manage fisheries, we feel that the EA is the best placed organisation to take inshore management of inshore resources for the benefit of all stakeholders into the 21st Century.

  4.8  The EA are already responsible for licensing angling for coarse fish, migratory salmon and trout and eels up to six nautical miles, and have developed sophisticated systems for angling licence collection and enforcement. It would be ridiculous and costly not to directly use their expertise to deliver and enforce a sea angling licensing system for marine species.

  4.9  Before a licensing scheme would be accepted by many recreational sea anglers, a development plan that was aimed at improving the angling "product" (more and bigger fish of certain species and access to good fishing) would need to be formulated and delivered and, when there was an apparent and measurable improvement in the "product", a licensing scheme would become much more acceptable.

  4.10  If licensing was to be introduced before there was an improvement, on the basis of management plans that had not yet been shown to be effective, then there would need to be measurable and timely objectives set out, with those charged with delivering the benefits being held to account should targets not be achieved within the stated timescales.

5.  ENFORCEMENT

  5.1  "Black" fish landings are a major problem. Whilst there is a market for "black" fish, enforcement will remain difficult and costly.

  5.2  Much more emphasis should be placed on sharing/transferring the risk from illegal landings from fishermen to buyers of "black" fish, with audit trails and traceability systems (such as carcass tagging) being adopted on a "buyer beware" principle.

  5.3  Removing the market for "black" fish would obviate the need for enforcement and enhance the effectiveness of stock recovery measures and availability of scientific data.

6.  TIMESCALES

  6.1  Many suspect that when civil servants are unsure of what their real objectives should be, or are not fully motivated by what they are expected to deliver, some foot-dragging takes place.

  6.2  SACN representatives have largely been impressed with the commitment of those with whom we have met, charged with taking forward the recommendations of the Strategy Unit.

  6.3  However, we sense an uncomfortableness with some of the proposals, and look toward the Committee to ensure that there is an atmosphere where it is recognised that delivering real change is fundamental to the success of the work in hand.

  6.4  We have been a little disappointed with the speed of progress so far. It is important that enthusiasm for delivering change and a sense of direction is not lost.

  6.5  It should also be borne in mind that the world does not stand still, and no time can afford to be lost when we are dealing with a situation where our marine resources continue to decline, even as technology advances to enable ever more efficient extraction of the remaining living resources from the marine environment, regardless of attendant consequential damage to that environment.

7.  ORAL EVIDENCE

  7.1  Undoubtedly there will be many questions not dealt with here, or not dealt with fully, that the Committee will require further details of from those with particular experience of the Recreational Sea Angling sector.

  7.2  SACN are eager to supply oral evidence to the Committee and we respectfully advise the Committee to also consider obtaining oral evidence from the National Federation of Sea Anglers, and from the Bass Anglers Sportfishing Society, along with any other angling organisations that the Committee deem appropriate to take evidence from.

8.  EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  8.1  Focus should be on the recovery and development of marine resources, rather than the cushioning of the effects of decline on the netting and shellfish sectors.

  8.2  The overarching aim should be to deliver best value to the country from the management of marine resources rather than concentrating on the needs of any particular stakeholders.

  8.3   Stakeholder representation is currently skewed to favour some stakeholders over others. To obtain best value, representation of all stakeholders needs to be effective representation if the right people are to become available to represent their sectors.

  8.4  There first needs to be discernable benefits delivered to the recreational sea angling sector before a sea angling licence is likely to be acceptable to the majority of sea anglers.

  8.5  SACN believes that the Environment Agency would be the most appropriate agency to manage any scheme licensing anglers and managing the ecology of inshore waters.

  8.6  Onshore enforcement, with purchaser liability, will help to remove the market for "black" fish.

  8.7  The Committee needs to play its part in creating the right environment for delivery of the Strategy Unit recommendations within envisaged timescales. The situation can only get worse if timescales slip.

  8.8  The Committee should seek further oral evidence from angling organisations.

14 September 2004





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 24 March 2005