Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Dr Andrew Palfreman (W21)

1.  SUMMARY

  The views expressed here are personal.

  The commercial analysis of the SU report is not as strong as it could be. Insights from collective action theory would have strengthened Annex D (analysing fisheries policies from the fisherman's viewpoint). The important commercial role played by Producer Organisations (POs) for many years is barely mentioned in the SU report.

  Neutrality on the costs and benefits of participation in the CFP issue would have been a more appropriate stance because the costs and benefits of the main positions are not at all clear cut.

  Institutions supportive of social capital are needed to accommodate the widespread unidirectional and mutual externalities in the industry. They exist even in countries which have adopted ITQs (eg Australia and New Zealand).

  ITQs are not a panacea. They have regressive implications for the distribution of wealth and income. This is a very serious issue for, amongst others, the English regions. They are also less suitable for an industry consisting of many small-scale operators.

  The benefit cost ratio from having a viable fishing industry is not necessarily correlated with the fisheries dependency ratio as conventionally measured. It follows that community quotas are important for regions that may not necessarily be "fisheries dependent" as conventionally defined.

  With appropriate support POs might still be a suitable instrument for equitable quota management and capacity reduction, if necessary.

  POs are also likely to be central to the development of the community quota concept, as well as other collective choices in the industry, not least because of the protection they offer against restrictive practices legislation and the fact that their decisions are, in principle, enforceable.

2.  INTRODUCTION

  This paper does not represent the views of Yorkshire Forward, or the fishing industry of Yorkshire and Humber. The views expressed are entirely my own.

  These comments follows the preparation of a report for the Yorkshire and Humber Fisheries Working Group, supported by Yorkshire Forward. [2]The Yorkshire and Humber region has witnessed the disproportionate decline, indeed near collapse in some ports, of the whitefish industry in that region, with dire effects on the major ports. In the order of catastrophe Grimsby tops the list, with Scarborough following close behind. The survival of a significant company has sustained Hull, together with landings from foreign vessels. The implementation of ITQs, as recommended by the SU report, without protection for the regions, can be predicted to result in the continued disproportionate shrinkage of the Yorkshire and Humber white fish subsector and the disappearance of commercial fishing at some ports. (The SU envisages the end of fishing at some ports in Chapter 4.)

3.  THE TERMS OF REFERENCE AND COMMERCIAL ANALYSIS

  The SU report is intended to be a guide for policy development by fisheries departments, but it is also intended to assist the fishing industry in planning. A weakness of the report stems from this double purpose. The recommendations to businesses are not strong partly because they do not seem well grounded in commercial reality and partly because the SU report fails to work through the institutional implications of many of its recommendations. [3]

  The research for the Yorkshire and Humber study showed that the white fish catching sector is in the process of disintegrating, but the response of the individual vessel owners and operators to this has been quite diverse. Under the circumstances of the industry in this region the kind of advice offered in Table 6.1 is really irrelevant when businesses are just struggling to survive. Moreover the report is virtually silent on the institutions, set up on the initiative of producers (Fish Producer Organisations) as required under European law, which have done something to support the regional sector.

  The risk management chapter (Chapter 5) illustrates a similar point. There is no analysis of the institutional arrangements that might enable the industry to adopt more risk management, although the pooling and trade in track record by POs is a form of risk management.

  The report employs an example of a New Zealand commercial fishing business, which has a real say in setting quotas, to illustrate commercial risk management. In New Zealand there is a carefully worked out institutional structure which hands over real fisheries management decisions at a collective level and at an individual company level to the sector—arrangements which might be developed from the PO structure in the UK. Another example: how can the industry aspire to Marine Stewardship Council certification (as recommended in Chapter 6) when the institutional mechanisms under which this might be done do not at present exist? Stocks are shared with other countries. The industry is dispersed and technologically varied. It is probably not impossible in the long run, and subject to many legal and institutional developments, but at present it is impractical. A fishing vessel owner or operator planning his own business would pay little attention to the advice in SU Table 6.1 when looking at his own business—this is what the SU thinks the industry should do, not what a commercial decision maker, or even what a consultant would advise a commercial operator to do. [4]

4.  WITHDRAWAL FROM CFP

  The SU makes an issue of the costs of reaching bilateral agreements if we were not in the CFP, as if these costs are likely to be more than the costs of current arrangements (Chapter 9). Has it been more costly for Norway or Iceland or other countries to reach agreements with countries whose fleets have ambitions to operate in their waters? The appropriate stance for the SU on this issue would have been neutrality. Assume, for the sake of argument, that it is feasible for the UK to leave the CFP and unable to reach agreement on access with other countries. The advantage of being outside is that the fallback position—the worst scenario (the Nash equilibrium) is less costly than the fallback position when in the CFP. Outside the confines of the CFP the UK can always walk away from the negotiation. Inside the CFP the fallback position is a common resource, perhaps fished by agreement, but also, quite probably, overfishing. This is what the evidence shows. Is the SU really saying that if there were no CFP, and the UK had full control over its own extended EEZ, that the UK would vote to create it? There is a reason for remaining in the CFP, and that is the UK's treaty obligations, but to argue that participation is relatively advantageous is implausible and tendentious, especially after the SU's criticisms of the CFP.

5.  THE ABSENCE OF SOCIAL CAPITAL

  The Strategy Unit team travelled the world in search of solutions and has seen examples from Iceland, New Zealand, the USA, Faeroes, Norway and Australia. What they have come up with is essentially a recommendation to move to an ITQ system. What is really surprising, however, is that an essential component of most successful systems, ITQ or otherwise, is left unanalysed, namely implementation arrangements for different interests in the industry to work together.

  There is an economic reason why this is an important point. It is because fishing vessels interact—in the jargon there are mutual as well as uni-directional externalities at work. The demise of the anchor seiner in the North Sea was not because this fishing method was inefficient. It was a very efficient, low cost, high returns fishing method. It disappeared because the institutional mechanisms that might have protected this fishing method did not exist. The structure of the cod stocks changed because of the coexistence of other fishing methods alongside anchor seining, leaving trawling as the main, commercially feasible, fishing method. There was an externality at work. And this is why any system of fisheries management has to include mechanisms for collaboration. The industry needs some glue—social capital—to deal with these problems.

  Another example of the absence of consideration of the collective action issue is the recommendation from the SU encouraging the over 10m shellfish sector to work together to jointly market and sell its products. This cannot be done in the absence of a legitimate structure, which does not dissolve under competitive pressures.

6.  THE ITQ RECOMMENDATION

  The single most important SU recommendation is ITQs. The report agrees that ITQs are not a panacea. There are some negative features—matching inputs with outputs under quota uncertainty, incentives to get round restrictions, high grading, price dumping, concentration of commercial capital, destruction of social capital. They appear to work where there are a relatively small number of big operators. But where there are larger numbers of small-scale fishermen, playing a socially important role, they run into difficulties, even in countries where they are claimed to be a success. Is it really desirable to permit the consequences of concentration of commercial capital to fishing interests in Cornwall or in the North East of England? It is regrettable that the SU report did not really face up to this problem. The SU report does not discuss the regressive implications of its recommended approach for the distribution of income and wealth in the sector.

  ITQ systems are by no means perfect. Fishermen have to be able to match inputs with the outputs they are allowed to catch. They need to know in advance what their share is going to be, and if it changes midstream they may revert to practices the system is designed to avoid. Moreover, ITQs would quite probably worsen the situation of the industry in Yorkshire and Humber. Indeed the SU report expects fishing to end at some ports, although it is not specific on locations.

7.  THE SOCIAL FUNCTION OF THE SECTOR

  Recognition of the need for social and economic development of the sector is included in the SU terms of reference. But the way the SU has interpreted this is disadvantageous to some regions and inconsistent with standard cost benefit analysis.

  One of the conceptual difficulties is the idea of "fisheries dependency". This appears once again in the Cabinet Office report (Chapter 3 passim) and it is also used on the European Commission's website and it has been around for a long time. There is a risk that the employment of numbers within Travel to Work areas as the denominator in dependency calculations introduces a bias against some industrial communities, such as Grimsby and Hull, where the industry plays an important social role. In reality, for certain communities, the potential for the industry to perform a social role, in terms of creating employment and incomes in socially deprived areas, is important, but because they are densely populated the fisheries dependency ratio will be low. Basically I am arguing that in some cases the benefit cost ratio from having an active fishing industry is not correlated with the fisheries dependency ratio—demonstrated by Freeman Street in Grimsby.

8.  EXCESS CAPACITY?

  The SU report claims excess capacity. The industry might concede the notion of excess capacity relative to the current UK quotas available to it. However, given the massive cut backs that have taken place in recent years, many in the industry dispute the idea that there is still excess capacity. They cite the recovery of haddock fishing in 2004, the widespread presence of cod and the speed with which they catch their permitted quotas. This is important from the point of view of the assessment provided in the current report because it implies that, according to skippers, recovery of North Sea stocks is already underway. No view on this is taken here except to point out that the difference of opinion illustrates the difficulties that the RACs may face. Making use of producer organisations to implement an equitable share out of quota, or to reduce capacity, or whatever might be necessary, may be a useful and practical starting point.

9.  COMMUNITY QUOTAS

  According to the SU report, one means of satisfying social objectives is to legitimise "community quotas". The report recognises the legal problems faced by some community schemes, but requests Government to consider the full range of options available, and looks towards some form of "ring-fence" idea. Once again POs are the obvious instrument.

  Community quotas have been established at the initiative of local fishermen in Shetland and Orkney as well as in the south west. In those contexts people have seen ways, quite reasonably, of advancing the interests of their regional sectors. The Yorkshire and Humber report recommends that Yorkshire and Humber fishing interests should do the same thing. In the context of this paper, however, the important point is that all regions throughout the UK will, quite reasonably, want to retain a viable catching sector and they will not want to be fobbed off with what are likely to be, in reality, very limited, and probably largely illusory, inshore development opportunities.

  The UK Government has been permissive and has allowed transferability of quota, and thus a market for track record and quota has developed, with official agreement. The Government has argued in Brussels that track records and quota entitlements should be considered as tradeable assets. It follows that providing support through and to POs to accumulate quota for their members is one means for improving the viability of fishing vessels in membership. This is a lesson which the Department of Agriculture and Rural Development for Northern Ireland and Shetland Islands Council have both evidently appreciated in the design of their own support mechanisms for their regional industries.

  The British Government has argued in defence of the Shetland and Orkney quota purchase schemes that aid given for purchase of quota should be regarded as investment aid, not operating aid. In the same submission the Government argued that the pooling of track record following from the development of the market is a desirable development, as it assures the existence of viable fishing enterprises.

  Although the European Commission has called on the stakeholders in Shetland to end the Shetland scheme in its original form, the scheme as such has not terminated and the beneficiaries have not been required to repay the money. Indeed, as long as a scheme is permitted the SFPO intends to continue with it because it is a means of securing a future for the islands. The Duchy scheme is up and running, with private sector funding, and is seen by stakeholders as a success. The concept of the community quota has been backed by the SU report and the Royal Society of Edinburgh report[5] (albeit loosely).

  The Commission's decision only applies to the original Shetland and Orkney schemes. It may be possible to design community schemes for other regions that meet the Commission's criticisms of the Shetland and Orkney schemes, but I have little doubt that POs will be central to any coherent national strategy.

10.  PRODUCER ORGANISATIONS

  Collaborative action is a common feature of the sector at all levels. The SU report is shot with implicit assumptions of collective action in the sector (eg recommendations for the pelagic, whitefish, over 10 metres shellfish and under 10 metes sectors—6.1.2). Indeed there are institutions within the sector that are already in place, are legally established and are designed to facilitate it, namely POs.

  POs have been around for a long time. There is a reason for this. The UK fishing industry in England as well as in Scotland welcomed them way back in 1973 because they gave vessel owners and operators legal protection from restrictive practices legislation—competition law, most recently embodied in the Enterprise Act. This Act actually explicitly forbids a range of cartel offences, such as price fixing and agreements between companies to restrict supply. That was why The Fish Producers' Organisation was formed in 1973, to permit fish producers, in those days the company sector trawling industry, to engage in restrictive practices. No one has explained to me why that argument has become invalid.

  The fish industry abounds in situations where the strategic choice for individual businesses is to compete or collaborate, or a mixture of the two.

What are the key ingredients of successful collective action?

  (1)  The operating rules have to be known by the participants if the collective action is going to be sustainable. This point is implicitly recognised in European Community legislation because it requires producers (ie catchers or fish farmers) who wish to have their PO recognised to conform to quite detailed requirements in their rules. [6]

  (2)  Because mutual gains can arise in a variety of different ways the economics of collective action requires the benefit delivery mechanism to be explicit. Fishermen will not participate on the strength of vague promises of some gains in the future which might (or might not) accrue to them if they follow this or that path. They want to know with some precision how the PO is going to set about delivering benefits to them as individual businesses.

  (3)  The third key element is the magnitude of the expected benefits. Paltry gains are not likely to induce much enthusiasm among potential participants, hence the substantial interest in mechanisms for compensation for fish failing to attract buyers at the minimum price among the fishermen of applicant countries to the EU.

  (4)  The fourth issue concerns risk and uncertainty. Expected gains from collective action may be substantial but if outcomes are uncertain they lose their value to participants, especially if the time horizons of participants are short.

  None of these criteria are met by the RACs initiative. The industry is encouraged to seize the opportunity presented by the RACs. The danger, however, is that the RACs will become another layer of bureaucracy—another talking shop. They will just breed cynicism unless decisions taken by them actually feed back into real commercial outcomes for individual fishermen.

  POs are one of the success stories of the EU's Common Fisheries Policy. By and large they meet the criteria needed for sustainability: rules-based for appropriations and contributions, visible benefits to members, clear evidence of the benefit delivery systems, exclusion mechanisms. Moreover there is no obligation on them to operate in the commercial areas where there are no visible collective benefits from collaboration. The regulations governing them have been redesigned to give them the powers to undertake quota management. Shetland has shown how they can be used to strengthen the architecture of fisheries management through various positive initiatives. Strengthening the PO structure would provide a mechanism for securing regional interests, such as Yorkshire and Humber, as well as meeting many of the other objectives of the SU report.

16 November 2004











2   Palfreman, Andrew. Steps towards the recovery of the fishing industry in Yorkshire and Humber. A Report Prepared for the Yorkshire and Humber Fisheries Working Group Funded by Yorkshire Forward. June 2004. Back

3   This point appears to be acknowledged by Departments insofar as they have put on the DEFRA website a number of consultation papers seeking stakeholder views on the various issues raised in the SU report. Back

4   In practice he (or she) would exercise his judgement on the business environment as it evolves, and ask himself how he can best use what is going on for the survival of his own company. He tries to predict what government and other stakeholders are going to do and how that might influence his own enterprise. He works out the benefits to his own business of following this or that course of action in the light of this. He asks himself about the advantages and disadvantages of participating in larger, collective activities such as trade associations and producer organisations. He asks himself how, in practice, the flow of profits to his own business is going to be delivered. He looks at the context of his business, and evaluates how it is changing over time. Perhaps he can contribute to that change by pushing his trade association one way or the other. Back

5   The Royal Society of Edinburgh. Inquiry into The Future of the Scottish Fishing Industry. March 2004. Back

6   Article 5 of Regulation 104/2000. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 24 March 2005