Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 160-179)

8 FEBRUARY 2005

DR MARK AVERY, JIM DENSHAM, LORD PETER MELCHETT AND MICHAEL GREEN

  Q160 Chairman: We will continue with evidence from the Royal Society for the Protection of Birds and the Soil Association and I would like to welcome Dr Mark Avery, the Conservation Director from the RSPB, Jim Densham, the Agricultural Policy Officer, and from the Soil Association Lord Peter Melchett, the Policy Director, and Michael Green, the Policy Officer. Thank you all very much for coming and for your written evidence. Unlike the previous witnesses, I think both of your organisations have had a lot to say about the positive results of the Voluntary Initiative, such as being successful in uniting the agrochemical industry in a common aid and developing a sense of responsibility, which is what the RSPB said. The Soil Association said that they succeeded in raising awareness, generating some management plans, getting the farmers to inspect their sprayers, and so on and so forth. So you have seen some very positive elements. I want to begin by asking you just how successful you think that the Voluntary Initiative has been in achieving the targets that were set for it?

  Dr Avery: If we could kick off? We would not want to be churlish. We think that the Voluntary Initiative has achieved some things and, as you say, we think it has helped to bring the agrochemical and farming industries together and concentrated their minds. We are disappointed with progress though, and can I just clear up the 75% figure that has been mentioned in the last few minutes? 75% of the arable area in this country is sprayed by operators who are on the National Register of Sprayer Operators. That does not mean that those operators have actually gone through the sprayer-testing scheme; it does not mean that there are Crop Protection Management Plans for all of that area. If there are Crop Protection Management Plans it does not mean that they are actually being implemented over the whole of that area, and even if they were they would not necessarily be good enough to reduce the pesticide impacts that we are all worried about. So I would not want the Committee to think that we are 75% of the way there—wherever there is—because we are a long way away from that. We think VI has been useful, but I would say that we are losing patience with it because we do not think it has been as good as it should have been.

  Q161 Chairman: Can you pinpoint the main successes?

  Dr Avery: I think the main successes are that it has concentrated the mind, that people have worked together.

  Q162 Chairman: Does that matter if they are not achieving? That is the question, is it not?

  Dr Avery: It is a start. As I said, we would not wish to be churlish; we think it is a start towards the right direction. But the end point of all of this policy work, Voluntary Initiatives and everything else, ought to be a National Pesticide Strategy which has clear end objectives of where we want to be, which sets objective for pesticide residues in food, pesticide levels in water courses and the impacts of pesticides on wildlife. Voluntary Initiative is a useful first step towards that end point, but it is quite a long journey and it is only a small step so far, we would say.

  Q163 Chairman: As you have the floor, before I bring in the Soil Association, do you want to say what the major weaknesses are—you have just referred to some—so that we have a clear picture of the successes and major weaknesses, before we look elsewhere?

  Mr Densham: I think the major weakness is that it was put as a VI or a tax and it was not fitting in to any sort of strategy, any sort of formalised National Pesticide Strategy, which we have been waiting for for two years, from Defra. Without those targets and those clearly set out ideals, end results set out in a strategy, it has been quite hard, I think, for the VI to know where it is really aiming at and to have a good steer. That is what we feel has been a problem and a weakness. So there have been positive points; we really think that it has—as Dr Avery said—helped awareness raising and that is a positive point. However, another weakness is that some of the projects that have been put in place, have been relatively unambitious in their targets. For example, we have heard about the coverage of 75% of arable area under the sprayer operators. However, one of our major criticisms relates to the Crop Protection Management Plans. Even though they are a positive thing and they potentially could do really good work and get farmers to really see what they are doing on their farms—and that is included in the Entry Level Scheme—the target is only there to cover 30% of arable land and that is only arable land at this stage. So we would really like to see that covering a much larger percentage of arable land as well as non-arable land.

  Q164 Chairman: Do you also have the view that a farmer could tick all the boxes but actually be performing very poorly, but would be credited with having the plan and that is a positive?

  Mr Densham: That is true. I myself sit on the VI Steering Group and we are working in a sub-group to look at Crop Protection Management Plans, and it is true that some farmers could say they have done it and they could just keep it on their shelf and not really refer to it throughout the year. However, we are trying to create ways that they can have feedback. So they fill them in, they have them analysed—we analyse them and send the results out—and they can judge themselves and they can try to see where they fit into the rest of their industry and their peers. So those things are positive and, like I say, there have been positives from the VI and good techniques and tools come out, but we would like to see the targets to be more ambitious in the future.

  Q165 Chairman: If I turn to the Soil Association and ask you the same questions really—the successes and the weaknesses?

  Lord Melchett: I agree with what the RSPB have said about what has been achieved, but I do not think it has been of great significance. I think the Voluntary Initiative has some major inherent flaws, inherent in the Initiative, and that there should be a tax, definitely. So that is our position, and quite unambiguous. The inherent flaws seem to us to be twofold: first, that inevitably a voluntary scheme of any sort will attract those who are most enthusiastic about its objectives and be least good covering those who are least enthusiastic. In other words, people who are most irresponsible in their use of sprays are the people who it is going to be most difficult, if not impossible, to get into a Voluntary Initiative, and they are effectively free riders. The irresponsible users of sprays benefit most from the Voluntary Initiative and that is an inherent flaw in a voluntary scheme. I do not see any way it can be addressed, and it is one of the reasons why a tax is required. Secondly, the Voluntary Initiative does nothing to address the current market distortion in food, whereby people buying organic food effectively subsidise the use of pesticides because they pay as taxpayers the costs which fall on society as a whole from the use of pesticides. Cleaning up drinking water they pay for through their water bills, but all the other regulation and so on of pesticides, which taxpayers pay for, organic consumers are paying, and then they pay slightly more for food produced without pesticides. That market distortion is grossly unfair to the organic farmers and could only be addressed through a tax; it cannot be addressed through a Voluntary Initiative. So the Voluntary Initiative has had some impact in generating plans and inspection of sprayers—not something I think is a matter of public policy but a factor of good practice in any event—but it has inherent flaws which a tax would address and only a tax would address.

  Q166 Chairman: Can I ask RSPB, do you think that there are ways in which the Voluntary Initiative can be improved, or do you think that it is necessary to go to compulsion in order to raise this from what is a positive but small contribution to a more comprehensive programme covering everybody who is a user, et cetera, which could either be done by a tax or by other fiscal incentives? Where do you stand on compulsion and improving the Voluntary Initiative as it is?

  Dr Avery: We believe in both. We believe that there is a place for voluntary action and that that could be done much better, but that ought to be seen as part of the package for regulation. A pesticide tax would be one option which we would still support. And it really is putting too much of a burden on the voluntary approach to think that it can do everything. It can do some things but it cannot do everything. So government needs a package of measures which deal across the board with the types of issues that there are, and it is unfair to think that the Voluntary Initiative can do all of it.

  Q167 Chairman: You probably know that the Farmers Union and the other witnesses that we saw on our previous occasion would all consider it entirely unfair to impose a pesticides tax. How can you justify that compulsion and the cost?

  Dr Avery: I think part of the deal for the Voluntary Initiative is that the industry is going to show great strides and progress without having a tax imposed on them, which we do not think they have done, in order to escape the tax. In fact if you look at the website for the Voluntary Initiative it says, "Voluntary Initiative helping biodiversity and making sure we do not get a pesticides tax." So I am not surprised that the industry is not keen on the tax, and I think that there are real difficulties about designing a tax which would work well to reduce the impacts and which would be a fair tax and not have perverse impacts. But we do think that a tax, if properly designed and implemented, ought to be part of a whole package of measures. Or at least it ought to be looked at. We should not discount it at the moment; it is there as an option and it is a real option and clearly it is an option that has been used in other countries in Europe who have already gone that far.

  Q168 Chairman: Soil Association?

  Lord Melchett: I agree with what Mark has said. You could argue that it is a little unfair for British farmers to be exempt from the tax when a number of other European countries, who are competing with our farmers in the market place, are already subject to a tax and a tax which, at least in some countries, there is good evidence it is having the desired effect of impacting on the use of pesticides, which is not what you were told in evidence in earlier session. But the report to Defra makes that quite clear.

  Q169 Mr Drew: If we can look at the issue of how you are working with the VI at the moment. Are you both represented on the Steering Board?

  Lord Melchett: The Soil Association does not have any great expertise in the use of pesticides as we do not use them! So it maybe for that reason we have not been invited.

  Q170 Mr Drew: There is always opportunity of education, Peter, on both sides. Obviously RSPB have been, as you have just mentioned. We heard quite a robust defence of the VI, both from the industry and farmers' representatives when we met them in the first session. Are you saying what you are saying to us to them and they have not quite got the message yet, or is there a complete and utter divide over this and they have a mindset now which is, VI good, tax bad?

  Mr Densham: I think the industry is more forward thinking than that, that it is starting to not really think about it as a pure tax versus the VI—one or the other. We have been there since the beginning and I hope our attendance has been helpful. I have not been on it from the beginning, which is why I say that. So we have been there as advisors. We are not signatories to the VI, we are there advising those who are the signatories to give them the best of our advice, with the Environment Agency on water, with English Nature, with ourselves on birds and wildlife so that we can help them to steer and try to achieve their biodiversity targets. So we are very keen to try to help them because we want to see the best for farmland and farmland birds.

  Q171 Mr Drew: So are you taking part in some of the evaluations when you are literally going out and doing some measurement? You may be doing that anyway because you would be looking at the impact on birds' species. But there is cooperation, there is engagement there, that you could not criticise them for trying to shut you out—that is actually going on?

  Mr Densham: Absolutely, yes. We think that our working relationships are quite productive and we are always open about what we think, and I hope that they understand what we say. And we do try not to be very critical but try to work with them.

  Lord Melchett: Can I just say something about the relationship between different sectors of the farming industry? If you had been reading Farmers' Weekly the last couple of months I think you would have a pretty clear indication that there was not much coming together between organic and non-organic on the question of pesticides—there has been a vigorous correspondence. And it is not surprising. If you were a non-organic farmer and the taxpayers were effectively paying some of the costs associated with your use of pesticides you would fight very hard to continue to see taxpayers pay those costs because it gives you a competitive advantage—we think an unfair one. But you are not going to have them come along—either them or the industry—and say voluntarily, "No, no, the taxpayers should not be paying for this, we will cough up. Please tax us," that would be a pretty unique occurrence. But, frankly, that surely is the job of the Committee and the government to decide where these costs should fall? Should the costs fall on society as a whole or on industry producing the costs? We would say that they should fall on industry and that that is fair and normal practice outside agriculture.

  Q172 Mr Drew: Let us touch on this idea which obviously the Soil Association is firmly committed to, which is that there has to be a pesticides tax and you are equivocal that you are not happy with progress on the VI. It does seem that there is some questioning going on about the validity of that tax, and the whole point about taxation is that it has to be very clear what it is trying to achieve. In the previous session—and you all sat in on it—there were some mixed metaphors going on about is it really there to change attitudes or is it to do with raising some money which you could then put into ways of doing things differently, which may include making the Voluntary Initiative more effective? Can you help me get clear in my mind where you are at with the advantage of a tax?

  Dr Avery: We believe that a tax, if properly designed, could reduce the impacts of pesticides on the environment, and that is what we are interested in. That is not quite the same as the amount of pesticides used, as you have heard already, but we would want to reduce pesticide impacts. To do that the tax has to be carefully designed, and unfortunately because life is complicated those pesticides which are most potentially damaging to human health are not always the same pesticides that would have the biggest impacts on wildlife, and they are not always the pesticides that most easily find their way into watercourses. So you have a complicated system where different pesticides are good and bad along different axes, so that makes designing a tax where ideally you would just be able to say, "Here is a good pesticide, here is a bad pesticide, we will slap a big tax on the bad pesticide" rather more complicated. I would not say we are equivocal, we think the pesticides tax has a role to play, but it would have to be a pesticides tax that took that complexity into account in the real world because otherwise, as you have heard before, a pesticides tax could have perverse impacts and that would not suit us and it would not suit society. The other thing we would say about the design of the pesticides tax is that we would wish to see the revenues hypothecated back into the farming industry, ideally back into paying for other means to deal with the impacts of pesticides. We would not support a tax that just took money out and gave it to the Treasury. That would just clobber the farming industry. If it were badly designed it would not reduce pesticide impacts and that would be a bad tax, we would say. So we are not equivocal. I am afraid the RSPB does see the real difficulties of designing a tax, and we think work should be done on that. We think the Treasury ought to be doing that work, and if we had a proposed tax in front of us it would be easy for us to say that, yes, that is a good tax or no, it is a bad one, and I think just talking about the pesticides tax in the abstract probably is not helpful because everybody has a slightly different idea of what it should do and what it might look like.

  Lord Melchett: May I just say that our position is slightly different? Our priority would be to see a tax to level the playing field between organic and non-organic farming. That would be our first priority and that could be a simple tax. I agree with the position that the RSPB and others have taken, that you have with this tax the added potential benefit of banding the tax to achieve environmental objectives as well as simply raising money. So that would be a second, desirable objective which we would certainly support. But in the first instance, you could have a tax which would level the playing field and give the market a chance to work properly, which we would welcome.

  Q173 Mr Wiggin: So can I just clarify that? You would like to see the tax levied and then given to the water companies?

  Lord Melchett: No, I did not mention the water companies, I just said levy the tax.

  Q174 Mr Wiggin: But earlier you said that organic customers were penalised because they paid a premium for their organic products and then they paid their water bills. So when the money is levied from the pesticide users surely that means you want to give it back to the water companies?

  Lord Melchett: No, because that was not the only cost I mentioned. There are a number of costs which fall on taxpayers as a whole and the public purse as a whole, the cost of enforcement, of running the Environment Agency, and a number of other costs of that sort, most of the pesticide regulation—although some is already covered by a very modest pesticide tax, that is true. So that already exists. We are interested in seeing the market work properly, and you mentioned that earlier and that is something that we would support. And we do not think that organic farming should be disadvantaged by allowing those who use pesticides to call on the public purse to pay some of the costs, or on people as a whole through water bills.

  Q175 Mr Wiggin: How would you then level the playing field?

  Lord Melchett: By imposing a tax on the use of pesticides, and ideally then achieve additional and environmental benefits in the way that the RSPB have outlined.

  Q176 Mr Wiggin: That would not necessarily level the playing field, would it? That would change the pricing structure but it would not effectively do what you wanted to do.

  Lord Melchett: Yes, I think it would. It would go a long way. None of these economic instruments are going to be perfect and they are always fairly imprecise in their impact. That is true of all taxation and this would not be any different from that, just as it would not be any different if people were trying to stockpile pesticides as they try and stockpile cigarettes. I think those are arguments either against all taxation or they are not valid arguments.

  Q177 Mr Wiggin: What I am worried about is that the Chancellor would leap on the fact that it is not actually possible to level the playing field because of the reasons you have just given, and then keep the tax and we would all be at a disadvantage. That is why I am pressing you on this one.

  Lord Melchett: I do not think that farmers who do not use pesticides or who minimise their use of pesticides would be disadvantaged in the circumstances you outlined; they would be advantaged competitively and that would be good for them, and it would be good in terms of achieving the government's new objectives for agriculture which are to see agriculture produce food that the customers want. We know that they want to avoid pesticide residues—that is the Food Standards Agency's advice—and we know that the government want agriculture to be more sustainable.

  Dr Avery: Could I just chip in that if there were a pesticide tax that reduced pesticides going into water then clearly the water consumer would benefit because we are paying as a whole in England and Wales £122 million a year in our water rates as the cost of removing pesticides from water, and the water companies have invested something like £3.6 million in capital investment to have the kit to take the pesticides out. So if you had a tax which solved that problem some farmers would lose out—unless the tax were hypothecated—organic farmers would benefit because the playing field would be adjusted in their favour, and the water consumers would benefit in that case. So exactly how—

  Q178 Mr Wiggin: I am sorry, the Chancellor is going to keep the money for the Met Office because we clearly heard that the problem with pesticides is that when it rains they go into the water! We have to face up to the fact that it is going to be very difficult to get the level playing field that the Soil Association is talking about, all the benefits from taxation that you want. I am sympathetic but I do think that we are up against it.

  Lord Melchett: There are three separate issues being confused, I think: the level playing field; the banding, which achieves the objectives we both want; hypothecation, which will put the money back into farmers' pockets in some way, hopefully organic as well as non-organic farmers, which is the thing you are raising objections to. I think our objectives are met by the first two things, the existence of a tax and a banding system which impacts on those that do most environmental damage. I am not insisting on hypothecation because I know the Treasury do not like it.

  Q179 Chairman: We do need to move on, we are getting behind, but Dr Avery said that if we had a draft tax before us we could make a comment. I just want to ask if you have studied at all the Norwegian example, and if so what you have made of that? Does it work?

  Dr Avery: We have had a look at that and I will pass over to my colleague in just a moment. We have also done some work ourselves to look at the whole issue of whether banding is feasible in this country. We think it is but we think it is difficult, so we have done some work which convinces us that this is still a live issue and a practical way forward, but, as I say, we would want it to be banded and we would want hypothecation before we would be in favour of the tax.

  Chairman: I think I will leave it there without getting your colleague in because we need to pass on. Paddy Tipping.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 5 April 2005