Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 107-119)

PROFESSOR JOHN FARRINGTON AND DR CAROLINE DYER

15 SEPTEMBER 2004

  Q107 Chairman: Thank you very much for coming. I am sorry you have been kept waiting. For the record, just tell us a little bit about yourselves so that those of us reading the record will know what weight to give to your evidence and where the problems exist. John, would you like to tell us a bit about yourself?

  Professor Farrington: I am an agricultural economist by training, a PhD in agricultural economics from the University of Reading with which I am still associated. I have been working on India for about 15 years, principally in the states of Andhra Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh. I know a little bit about West Bengal and Orissa as well. It is some time since I did any formal agricultural economics, I have branched much more into broader rural development issues.

  Dr Dyer: My PhD subject was on the implementation of educational policy in India and that was some 12 or 13 years ago now, and since then I have been very interested in questions of implementation policy. I have also worked on adult literacy with Nomads in India for three years doing field work with them, and most recently on a DFID-funded research project working with teacher educators to look at the question of capacity-building around teacher educators and teacher training in particular. I have just moved to a job at the University of Leeds in Development Practice from the Faculty of Education in Manchester.

  Q108 Chairman: Do you think that DFID has got the balance right between governance reform support and direct pro-poor projects, in other words, livelihoods support, on the one hand, and support to health and education, on the other, perhaps?

  Professor Farrington: There are two dimensions to this response, I think. One is the question of where are the people who are poor: 60% are in rural areas. From the figures we have been given in Annex A of DFID's recent response[4], I can only relate 7% directly of expenditure to rural areas. There seems to be something wrong there. That is one point. The second is between, if you like, the broader governance and programmatic support, on the one hand, and project work, on the other hand. I think there is a lot more that can be done on project work, I do not think the balance is right. I am not persuaded that programmatic support of the kind that DFID has been giving has had effects or that effects indeed can be traced and attributed to DFID, or to anybody else, of support given, that aid is such a small part, it is the equivalent of 0.36% of GNP, I think, in India, it is very, very small. It is quite high in specific niches, but even so I think it would be very hard to trace impacts, and I think a lot more can be done at a project or, if you like, something slightly bigger than a project level. That does not mean necessarily that one has to go into the field and start doing rural development projects of the kind that have been done so far, I think there are other interesting and exciting possibilities which have not really been considered yet. I do not accept DFID's view in its recent response that it is hard and virtually impossible to find useful things to do in agriculture. Agriculture is complex because its management is divided between the centre and the states, but then so are almost all subjects, in one way or another. I can think of three or four things that DFID could do quite usefully in agriculture which do not involve big rural development projects, for example.

  Q109 John Barrett: You mentioned DFID support at the central level and state level, they also work through civil society. What is the most effective way for DFID to tackle sectoral policies?

  Professor Farrington: As far as agriculture and rural development are concerned, which are my specialist areas, I think, if one is going to work with government, it has to be a combination of central government and state government. What I have been somewhat disappointed not to find any evidence of so far is the promotion of lesson-learning among states. Though there is quite a bit of individual work with the states there is no mechanism in India, as far as I am aware, for the chief ministers of states to sit together and learn from each other, and I think some effort from DFID to promote learning across states could have been undertaken quite effectively. On top of that, the very big gap that I perceive is that nothing has been done with the private sector. The private sector actually is very big in agricultural development in India, it is doing a good job in many ways. It could do a better job in other ways, and I think some DFID support and DFID working with the private sector could help to correct some of the things that are going wrong. I can give a couple of examples very quickly if you like. One is that, as you have probably heard, there have been a huge number of farmer suicides in Andhra Pradesh; it is a very hot political issue, linked with cotton farming largely but going beyond cotton, something like 3,000 or so recently. A lot of that is associated with the wrong kind of agricultural inputs, inputs that do not actually work, they do not do the job that farmers purchase them to do and so they are being mis-sold or they are being misrepresented or mislabelled or wrongly formulated or adulterated, or whatever, and it is a massive problem. It sounds very prosaic but it is a huge problem and it is resulting in suicide, to some extent. One thing that happens in other countries is that the producers and manufacturers of those kinds of products form an association and they self-monitor, they self-police their own industry. They try to set up mechanisms to ensure that products are correctly labelled, that they are not adulterated, that they contain what they are supposed to contain and that they are not sold to do something that they are incapable of doing. I would have thought that DFID working with a Chamber of Commerce of agricultural, insecticide producers, for example, or seeds producers, would help to build up that kind of capability and move something forward in that industry. That is one example.

  Dr Dyer: I would like to endorse very much the question raised earlier about the lesson-learning across states and how DFID could be involved in that kind of thing. If you look at how the District Primary Education Programmes (DPEP) moved into the Sarva Shiksa Abhiyan, there are plenty of opportunities to learn lessons about how the DPEP had worked in different states, and perhaps not enough of that happens. I think, in the forthcoming policy dialogues, DFID might well look at lesson-learning across states and at how they could promote platforms for interstate comparisons of progress and how it has been made. There is an enormous amount to be learned from Madhya Pradesh and decentralisation of education, for example.

  Q110 John Barrett: Equally, is that one of the disadvantages of centrally-sponsored schemes, in that there is such a wide variety between states that working from the centre can be appropriate in one area but inappropriate in another area?

  Dr Dyer: Indeed. During the enforced recess we were all discussing this question of centrally-sponsored schemes and there are several things that I would like to draw to your attention to, about centrally-sponsored schemes in education. Scheme design traditionally has been very, very centralised with little contribution from the states and there has been a `one size fits all' design in terms of scheme parameters. That can act as a constraint on creative uptake of the ideas reflected in the scheme. There has often been quite poor stake holding at the state level in the centrally-sponsored schemes and they are not necessarily integrated properly into state-level policy. I think there is a need to think more about the sharing and the lesson-learning that can be done about different states' take-up of centrally-sponsored schemes and whether the central allocations make it easier for states to do the things that they want to do or whether they are constrained by the schemes' parameters.

  Professor Farrington: I think DFID has a huge amount of homework to do on centrally-sponsored schemes. The Government of India set up its own review of that four years ago by its own Comptroller and Auditor General on centrally-sponsored schemes, a very, very hard-hitting review and I think well worth your while to take a look at, if you have the opportunity[5]. It brought up all the problems of corruption, it brought up the problems of uniformity, the kind of `one size fits all' approach, which does not work. What it did not really bring up are the differences between different kinds of schemes in terms of robustness in the face of endemic corruption; some are quite robust, some are very, very prone to corruption. I noted a question earlier on that and with some schemes one might expect 10 or 15% of rake-off, with others 40 or 50%, depending on the characteristics of the scheme. That has been documented quite clearly in more recent work, and again I can provide the reference for that[6]. I think there is a lot out there. We know a lot about how centrally-sponsored schemes perform. I think DFID would be ill-advised simply to put money into those in general, it needs to be really quite selective and perhaps use leverage to get the implementation mechanisms of some of those schemes changed to make them more robust in the face of what we know about how corruption works at local level. I think centrally-sponsored schemes offer potentially a very interesting mechanism for working in states where there is a lot of poverty where DFID does not yet work, such as Bihar. This might be an unusual example but, if I may, let me for a minute give one example. There is a disproportionately high concentration of poverty among the very elderly, widows and the disabled, and all of those under centrally-sponsored schemes are entitled to pensions of various kinds. The pensions are very seriously underfunded. They are supposed to be funded partly by the centre and partly by the states but only about a quarter, or even less than that, of the total potential amount is funded, certainly for things like old-age pensions. That offers an opportunity for topping-up that, if you like, in financial terms, and DFID could quite easily put in £30 million, £40 million or £50 million a year to fill that gap. The really interesting thing about something like the pension scheme is that it can be, and is in many states, administered through central government instruments, such as the Post Office, one gets one's old-age pension cheque from the Post Office, or whatever, or the banks, and that avoids the need to go through state-level mechanisms that do not work in some of the poorly-performing states. To strengthen those delivery methods and to flesh those out to develop models of getting things out that way, I think, potentially is quite interesting.


  Q111 Mr Battle: DFID makes a virtue out of the fact that it deals directly at state level and that this could have an impact on service delivery. Do you think DFID does have an impact on reform and improving service delivery?

  Dr Dyer: In terms of education delivery, the largest work that has been done has been one of the District Primary Education Programmes perhaps. In terms of DPEP, I think it would be very difficult to attribute anything directly to DFID because there have been a lot of excellent donors working together, so whether one could say something has been specifically down to DFID would be really very difficult.

  Professor Farrington: I cannot think of examples in agriculture and rural development where service delivery has been much improved by DFID.

  Q112 Mr Davies: I think it would be a mistake to pass over a couple of things that Professor Farrington just said which seemed to me very significant and certainly very germane to our agenda. I think you said that the aid flows tend to get lost in the large volumes of public expenditure in India so it is very difficult to determine what the outcomes of those expenditures have been and how effective they have been. The implication was that budgetary support perhaps is not the right way forward in India; then you said it would be better to adopt a more project-based approach. That is an interesting criticism of the whole of DFID's strategy in India. I have understood you correctly, have I?

  Professor Farrington: Yes.

  Q113 Mr Davies: Then you said that you actually had some interesting ideas as to what might be done in the project field, so I think you had better tell us what they are?

  Professor Farrington: I think there is difficulty in providing sectoral support in the way in which sectors are defined in India, which are very rigidly defined. If you provide support to agriculture, for example, as it is defined in India, and you are interested in reducing risk and vulnerability as poor people face it in agricultural enterprises, you might get an improved crop insurance scheme, you might get a livestock insurance scheme, probably you will not get insurance for any other productive assets because it is outside the remit of agriculture.

  Q114 Mr Davies: And you will line the pockets of a lot of people along the way. You can take that message too?

  Professor Farrington: You might do. There are interesting models, I think. What I am getting round to saying is this. There are interesting models of reducing risk and vulnerability for poor people and the agriculture component is one. What we know is that money is fungible and so if there is a crisis in the household, if someone is sick or dies, the money flows out of agriculture to cover that need. The implication is that you need to handle domestic risk and vulnerability coherently with agricultural risk and vulnerability. Also you need personal insurance schemes, for example, health insurance, life insurance and that kind of thing. It might sound rather high-flown but there are a few examples on the ground in which women's groups have been putting their money, instead of buying a new sewing-machine for a market that is already flooded with handicrafts, into buying personal insurance, health insurance and life insurance, which is, I think, terribly interesting but it is outside the mandate of any particular sector at the moment you see. If you take a sectoral approach you will not catch that, it kind of falls between the cracks.

  Q115 Mr Davies: I am missing what you are trying to tell us. Are you trying to tell us that DFID, or some other donor, could provide that kind of insurance product which is not being provided currently? Is that what you are saying?

  Professor Farrington: There is hardly anyone providing it. There are one or two isolated examples on the ground and I think it represents an opportunity for someone, such as DFID, to pick up the principles, to work with the private sector or the government banks or government insurance companies who could potentially provide this and work up models of doing it and support them in doing it over a wider scale.

  Q116 Mr Davies: Are there any other ideas? You mentioned you had two or three.

  Professor Farrington: The one on producers' associations I mentioned a moment ago in relation to agricultural inputs. There is another one at the other end of that production scale which is on agricultural marketing. There is a private company, the Indian Tobacco Company, which, despite its name, operates in collecting and marketing a very wide range of agricultural products and it is doing this through electronic information systems. It is getting together a group of farmers, giving them a little computer terminal, connecting it through e-mail to their own office and they can e-mail and find the price of the product delivered by ten o'clock next morning to such and such a market, and that price is guaranteed. To begin to pick up that kind of thing and expand it, again, I think is something that DFID could give some support to in working with the private sector.

  Q117 Mr Davies: The private sector is doing it?

  Professor Farrington: No, it is a very isolated example.

  Q118 Mr Davies: You think it cannot be replicated or expanded on the basis purely of private sector incentives?

  Professor Farrington: I think it needs a bit of help on the way.

  Q119 Mr Davies: Another aspect of DFID's policy in the agricultural area is a focus on these rural livelihood projects. Can you tell me what you think of rural livelihood projects and how the programme is working?

  Professor Farrington: I think they have been very successful in a narrowly-defined mandate, which is to improve the livelihoods of the people within that geographical perimeter in which they operate. I think they have been less successful in generating wider lessons or, let us say, having wider lessons taken from them and disseminated into the Indian public service so that then they can be incorporated into agricultural extension services or credit services, or whatever the case may be. I think that wider promise has not really been fulfilled.


4   Ev 73 Back

5   Government of India (1999), Report of the Comptroller and Auditor General, New Delhi. Back

6   ODI Natural Resources Perspectives Paper, Number 87, June 2003, Post Offices, Pensions and Computers: New Opportunities for Combining Growth and Social Protection in Weakly Integrated Rural Areas?, John Farrington, NC Saxena, Tamsyn Barton and Radhika Nayak, http://www.odi.org.uk/nrp/87.pdf. ODI Working Paper 175, September 2002, Reaching the Poor: The Influence of Policy and Administrative Processes on the Implementation of Government Poverty Schemes in India, Radhika Nayak, NC Saxena and John Farrington, http://www.odi.org.uk/publications/working_papers/wp175.pdf. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 17 March 2005