APPENDIX 1
ANSWERS TO THE COMMITTEE'S SPECIFIC QUESTIONS
DEFINING WHAT
CHOICE MEANS
IN THE
PUBLIC SECTOR
1. How is choice in public services to be
defined?
Choice is a complex concept. A practical working
definition of choice is:
The delegation to service users, of decision-making
powers about where, when, by whom and how, public services are
provided.
The definition of service users can include:
clients; customers; carers; patients; residents; pupils; students;
parents. It includes individuals, groups exercising collective
choice (such as parents of pupils at one school, residents in
one street or members of a particular care group), and society
at large, which exercises community choice on a wider scale at
local and national levels through the democratic process.
"Public Services" are not clearly
defined. The public still has a tendency to consider railways
to be a public service even though privately owned, and many publicly-funded
services are provided by private businesses or non-for profit
organisations.
2. Will the nature of choice vary depending
on the type of provision or service?
Yes, inevitably. Some services can only be provided
in one geographic locality (street sweeping) where as others can
be provided elsewhere (elective surgery). Many services lend themselves
to a variety of choice about the precise nature of services to
be provided (maternity, social care).
3. Is "choice" simply a euphemism
for competition and market mechanisms?
No, competition, like choice, is one of the
elements that make markets work effectively.
The concept of consumer choice comes from the
private sector. Generally, in the private sector, individuals
exercise choice through decisions on whether or not to spend their
own money. If products and services are not seen as competitive,
they are unlikely to succeed, and thus competition in the private
sector drives improved quality and value for money. Choice acts
as a powerful spur for quality and value for money.
It is possible to transfer some aspects of choice
as it is understood in the private sector, to the public sector.
However, the nature of the public sector makes it impossible to
transfer all elements of private sector choice. The key issue
for government is identifying how best to develop choice as a
force for improving public services.
The choice exercised by a few citizens can create
a more general pressure to improve service delivery, although
only in some aspects. [45]
THE CONCEPT
OF CUSTOMERS
OF PUBLIC
SERVICES
4. Is it possible to have customers of public
services as well as active citizens and democratic accountability
or are they mutually exclusive?
The concepts are not mutually exclusive. Active
citizens will be a subset of "customers" of public services.
Democratic accountability is the mechanism by which citizens can
hold those responsible for the nature, scope and quality of public
services to account.
5. Is it necessary to devise a more precise
and generally acceptable definition of who the user or customer
for each service is? For example is it the pupil who is the user
of the school system when it is the parent who exercises the choice?
There are multiple users (or "customers")
for many public services. Pupils and parents are customers for
education, but so is society at large which needs a skilled workforce.
Public services need to understand the needs
of all the customers for their services and balance their interests
appropriately.
6. Is it possible to identify a customer
for the entire range of government functions or is it limited
to public facing activities as envisaged, for example, in the
Next Steps approach of the late 1980s?
No, it is difficult to apply the concept of
the "customer" to some government functions. For example,
who is the customer for defence? What choices do they have? Voting
may change governments, without changing defence priorities.
See also answer to Q5 above.
MECHANISMS FOR
EXPRESSING CHOICE
7. Are targets and league tables, customer
surveys and complaints systems sufficient for ensuring adequate
responsiveness to consumer preferences?
Noother mechanisms are also required.
Targets and league tables perform different
functions from those of customer surveys and complaints systems.
They all have a part to play in improving public services. Currently,
however, these elements do not operate as one integrated system
for ensuring quality and responsiveness in public services.
The published products generally have little
relevance or applicability to individual consumers, except where
it is possible to translate them into timely and relevant information
that will help the consumer in making choices.
Most league tables are produced at a high level
of aggregation. Aggregated scores, such as the NHS star ratings,
have little relevance for individual users. [46]Education
scores are highly controversial, but they do have some credibility
with the general public and relevance for parents.
Provided they are well-designed, customer surveys
and other consultations can be important ways of gathering citizen
and customer views. Currently, few public sector organisations
make good use of such information to help them improve their services,
or to increase choice.
Targets can be used to reflect collective choices
(arguably, the waiting times target is a collective choice for
the NHS. Also, it would help if the targets and league tables
reinforced customer responsiveness: A & E is not really a
"choice" service, but the 4 hour wait target could be
better developed as a customer satisfaction survey and reflected
in the targets and league tables. Thus, how one responded to customer
preferences where choice wasn't really an option, would become
important.
Complaints are a vital source of information,
but few public sector organisations use them well. It will be
interesting to see if including an intermediate complaints function
in the new Healthcare Commission helps encourage better use of
this source of intelligence in the NHS.
There is a danger in using the volume of complaints
as a measure of performance, rather than as a source of information
about performance. The aim should be to encourage feedback, rather
than to stifle it.
8. Is contestability a further requirement
to make choice fully responsive? If so, to what degree?
Where new suppliers are likely to enter a market,
the threat of potential entry constrains the existing suppliers
and prevents them from raising pricesin other words the
market is "contestable". In theory, in contestable markets,
existing suppliers charge low prices, even if they have very high
market shares.
Attempts to introduce competition to the public
sector have sometimes failed because of the absence of viable
alternatives to existing provision (as experienced in local government
during Compulsory Competitive Tendering). This suggests that in
order to promote a competitive environment and secure the cost
and choice benefits afforded by competition, a necessary first
step would be to promote contestability; even where, for the time
being, other constraints (eg statute) prevent full competition
from operating; ie we must create the conditions for competition.
But this then raises questions about the amount of surplus capacity
that the market can bear. [47]
9. Can individual choice, collective choice
and choice on behalf of the citizen (by Government or Local Authorities
for example) operate successfully alongside each other?
Yes, but it is important to be clear who exercises
choice over what.
In the private sector, individual choice tends
to be restricted mostly by the ability of suppliers to meet consumers'
wishes and by consumers' ability to pay for them. Even so, society
exercises some community choices to enable the market economy
to operate. These community choices are enshrined through a variety
of legal and regulatory mechanisms such as the activities of the
Financial Services Authority; rules about pollution; and legal
restrictions on the availability of alcohol, in order to minimise
the anti-social effects and the costs of alcoholism.
By their nature, public services involve more
significant community choices: about entitlements; obligations;
taxes; charges; forms of provision; and value for money. Community
choices therefore constrain individual choice in the wider public
interest. There is always some degree of trade off between the
extent of individual and of collective choice. It may be desirable
to constrain individual choice in the interests of economies of
scale or to maximise overall value for money, as seen in the guidance
issued by the National Institute for Clinical Excellence. Our
report on Primary Care Prescribing[48]
highlighted the costs of prescribing drugs of limited clinical
value or of over-prescription, often influenced by patient pressure.
We need a more sophisticated understanding of
the actors exercising choice. At the individual level, people
exercise choice both on their own behalf and on behalf of others
for whom they have responsibility or duties of care, for example
parents on behalf of children. At the collective level there are,
for example:
Communities of special interest,
eg RNID campaign for digital hearing aids.
Communities of diverse but related
interests, eg local businesses in business improvement districts
opting and paying for more frequent refuse collection.
Communities based around geography,
eg residents in a particular street campaigning for the introduction
(or removal) of traffic calming measures.
10. Are all these forms of choice equally
effective in ensuring (a) efficiency and responsiveness and (b)
equity and fairness?
No, they have different roles. Within a framework
created collectively, individual choice can bring a range of benefits:
A pressure for better quality and individually
tailored services, leading to improved outcomes and satisfaction;
A better balance between rights and responsibilities;
Increased engagement of citizens with their
public services and a consequent increase of active citizenship;
Opportunities to develop more varied forms of
service, for examplegiving greater access to services 24/7,
through e-government initiatives.
Individual choices may work against efficiency
or equity; and therefore society may need to constrain individual
choice through community choice in a ballot box. Because collective
choices constrain the nature and extent of individual choices,
as well as determine how public services will be paid for, people
need to have the opportunity to influence them. Citizens exercise
voice through voting at local and national elections, and in a
range of other ways, including though consultation, [49]lobbying
and a variety of forms of "Active Citizenship". There
is some evidence that the more people are actively involved in
the process of procuring or providing services, the more they
understand the difficulties, choices and trade-offs involved.
Users of services have other ways to exercise voice, including
direct discussions with providers and through complaints.
CHOICE AND
EQUITY
11. Is there a generally understood definition
of what equity means in respect of public services?
No; the term means different things to different
people. There is confusion around the use of the terms "equity",
"equality" and "equality of opportunity".[50]
Most public sector workers would understand what "equality"
means in terms of fair access to employment; some understand the
implications for service delivery.
Does equity currently exist in public service
provision? If not who have been the main beneficiaries and why?
No, equity does not truly exist in public service
provision at present. "Equity" is not absolute; it can
only ever exist in part. [51]At
present, there is a "postcode lottery" for some services,
where some providers in one geographical area operate differently
from those in other areas, perhaps due to different resources.
A crude, profit-driven market will tend to militate against equity,
for example in the provision of affordable and reliable public
transport in rural areas. Also, those people who are better resourced
(in terms of their education, income, ability to choose etc),
are often able to obtain better services and outcomes. The key
issue here is how best to reduce the inequalities.
12. Must there necessarily be losers in a
system involving choice and contestability?
No, there should be no "losers", always
provided that the system contains appropriate safeguards. There
will, however, be greater variety of services provided if they
are better tailored to the needs of individuals. This will require
a tolerance of variation. Some variations will be chosen by communities
(local priorities) and some by individual preferences (to tailor
services to their needs).
See paragraphs 33-38 above.
A crude, profit-driven market will tend to militate
against equity, for example in the provision of affordable and
reliable public transport in rural areas.
The main issue for providers is what happens
to poor performers, who need support to improve. The Audit Commission
has been keen to share the learning from its CPA work as quickly
as possible. [52]
13. How can a choice-based provision of public
services avoid providers "cream-skimming" the less difficult
or resource intensive users of the service?
There is a need for minimum standards and entitlements
and mechanisms to ensure they are provided. There is also a need
to provide some form of help for those who are less able to exercise
choice by themselves.
INFORMATION FOR
USERS
14. To what degree is the ability to evaluate
different providers necessary for consumer choice?
The ability to do this is critical. But that
ability is absolutely dependant upon the provision of robust,
timely and accessible information. It should be local; timely
appropriate to the options available; and sufficiently detailed.
Studies show that this is rarely the case in public services.
This also begs the question of what is meant
by "different providers"?Different hospitals?
Or different doctors in one hospital? This can make a vital difference
to individual patients, but enabling them to make informed choices
where service delivery touches on professional competence, is
very difficult. It may be very hard for public service users to
make sensible choices, especially if there is uncertainty over
the consequences of different choices. [53]
It should be noted that the possibility of having
one's preferences met within a service may be just as important
to the user as a choice of service provider, for example, the
choice of a general or spinal anaesthetic for certain medical
procedures and the choices available in childbirth.
15. How should those users less able to make
informed choices because of their income or situation be empowered
to do so? What form should the provision of information take?
There may be institutional and professional
barriers to the exercise of choice by some user groups, such as
people with learning disabilities, older people and children with
disabilities. [54]
There is a need to empower such people. At its
most basic level this could be providing assistance by way of
translation into a minority ethnic language, but other situations
may require providing the individual with advice on different
options or even advocacy in decision making. Their situation is
not an adequate reason for failing to provide as much choice as
possible; rather it is a pressing reason to provide help, so that
they can exercise their right to choose. Question 14 outlines
the need for good informationthis will support not only
the individual but also their advisors and advocates.
16. How is satisfaction with and the performance
of services to be measured, by whom and how is that information
to be made available?
Measuring customer satisfaction should be a
function of service managers. At their best, service providers
actively seek feedback from customers and other stakeholders and
use this information to inform decision making and thereby drive
continuous improvement. Regulators have an important role to play
in validating this information and providing reassurance to a
variety of stakeholders about its reliability.
Comparing public services adds value and can
partly compensate for the lack of competition in most public services.
Information about user satisfaction should be comparable, to show
users the performance of various service providers.
VOICE AND
PUBLIC SERVICES
17. What mechanisms (complaints, feedback)
exist or should be created for exerting influence on providers?
Are they available to all?
A number of mechanisms exist and are used to
a greater or lesser degree, depending upon the type of service:
[55]
Performance management from top management;
Pressure groups of service users;
The Audit Commission report Listen Up!
contains a wealth of advice for public sector organisations on
effective consultation. The key issue is whether provider organisations
respond to the news they receive.
18. Does the complaint system operate effectively
and equitably in the public sector? If not what should be done
to improve this?
No because complaints systems operate in favour
of the most articulate and resourceful. In health services, the
introduction of Patient Advice and Liaison Services (PALs) is
helping to resolve problems for some of the people who would not
naturally be inclined to pursue a complaint to achieve a resolution.
19. Is decentralised decision making and
"direct user engagement" an expression of "new
localism" or will it lead back to a Victorian-style future
of education, health or sanitation boards of the local great and
good?
There is a need to achieve a judicious balance
between loose/tight, between the national framework and local
flexibility. Local services for local people should mean a greater
variety of services provided that are better tailored to the needs
of individuals.
It is important to recognise the democratic
role of local authorities here. In addition to national priorities,
local Councils will have included local and regional priorities
in their performance plans, following consultation with residents
on local spending priorities and charges for services, in advance
of setting the annual council tax. [56]
The new Foundation Trusts will provide an interesting
experiment with a different form of accountability and engagement
with the local population. It is too early to judge the level
of interest in this opportunity for people to stand as representatives
for the trust boards. However, there is a risk that in creating
a multiplicity of arrangements, there is a loss of co-ordination
and costs may rise as economies of scale are lost.
DEVOLUTION AND
DIVERSITY
20. At what levels can choice and voice operate
within public service provision? Do they reinforce greater localism
and devolution?
Choice and voice can operate at local, regional
and national levels within public sector provision; they can reinforce
greater localism and devolution.
21. Is diversity a prerequisite for choice?
If so does diversity refer to good and bad performers or to the
requirement for some unique selling point from the provider such
as faith or specialist schools?
Diversity of requirements means that there is
a need for diversity in provision, before choice can be available.
Choice is simply one mechanism for helping to
ensure that there is the right provision to meet citizens' diverse
needs.
22. Does choice risk reinforcing the so-called
"postcode lottery"?
No. The term "postcode lottery" refers
to current differences in basic entitlements and the quality of
provision, across the UK. Some degree of local variation is inevitableand,
if intentional, it can be desirable (for example to reflect particular
local circumstances). Community and individual choice can provide
legitimate reasons for local variations.
There is a problem where variability is unintended
or where it undermines equity, for example differences in the
availability of particular prescription drugs or treatments, between
different health regions of England.
CHOICE AND
THE PUBLIC
GOOD
23. Can the consumer be "sovereign"
in the public services? If not, why not?
No, because of availability of services, budgetary
constraints, the need to consider the interests of the wider community,
etc. However, it is possible to create cultures and systems which
enable users to be "queens" rather the "pawns"
in the provision of public services. [57]This
could be done by empowering users with information on service
quality and the availability of options, training staff to provide
a supportive service for users, exercising choice and introducing
financial incentives for services, which ensure that money follows
users.
The consumer could and should have a great deal
more choice than at present, in terms of what they have, when
they have it, and added services. For example, access to routine
GP appointments outside of normal working hours and at weekends,
as well as for emergencies; more options on waste collections
for recycling; levels of community policing.
24. Is there a risk that a consumerist approach
to public services will undermine the public service ethos?
There is no reason why it should; the public
service ethos should motivate staff to provide high quality services.
Giving people as much choice as possible is one element of quality
service.
25. Does the creation of individual consumers
for public services put social cohesion and the idea of the public
good at risk? If so what alternatives are there to the consumer
choice agenda for public service reform?
This should not be an issue if the choice is
exercised within a clear framework which ensures equity and supports
social cohesion. For example, people may be obliged to use public
services in the wider interests of society (offenders, mental
health problems; people with infectious diseases). Whilst they
have to lose some freedoms, they remain citizens of society with
rights and therefore some choices. It is important to enable them
to exercise those choices.
CAPACITY IN
THE PUBLIC
SERVICES
26. Will the extension of choice create unmanageable
demands on the capacity of public services to provide? If so is
some degree of excess capacity necessary for choice to operate
effectively?
Public services will need some excess capacity
in order for some (but not all) choices to be meaningful. There
is a need to balance choice and efficiency. [58]Politicians
however, at both local and national level will need to take a
view about the quantum of surplus capacity that can be sustained
and if it is affordable, recognising that without at least some
surplus, some choices may be denied. Choice can also help to manage
or divert demand, for exampleGPs exercise a gatekeeper
role in the health service, for example in their prescribing decisions.
[59]In
some cases exercising choice can reduce the drain on the public
purse. For example, people whose property has been stolen may
prefer to report it by telephone than have to wait at home for
one or more police officers to visit. [60]
27. What are the cost implications of this?
Should it lead to an extension of Private Finance Initiatives?
The extension of choice does not necessarily
imply the need for substantial new capital investment. It is often
the availability of choice in relatively simple matters that influences
user perception of service delivery and the level of satisfaction
with public services.
Giving people more choice will not always be
costly. It would cost virtually nothing to allow people to choose
different GPs when it suited them, for example to attend near
the workplace in some circumstances and near home in others, rather
than be confined to one practice; provided that the information
and financial infrastructure was capable of supporting such choices.
However, it is a major challenge to create the conditions in which
citizens can exercise more choice.
In some instances, there is a risk of increased
costs caused by the loss of economies of scale[61]
or the diversion of resources to supporting unused surplus capacity.
PFI is a mechanism for funding public services;
it does not have a specific impact on choice.
28. Are user charges an inevitable outcome
of greater choice? Might user charges help widen choice?
Charges play a part in expanding choice and
rationing demand. It may be useful to extend choice beyond a basic
minimum. In some instances people's willingness to pay can be
an indicator of the real value that they place on a particular
choice. [62]
The growth of private education and healthcare
are examples of individuals with money exercising choices at local
level. Other examples are: the increasing availability of over
the counter medicines; car parking; music lessons in schools;
arrangements between local authorities and their residents, to
share the cost of additional street cleaning at the residents'
request and the introduction of pay-TV in hospitals. The latter
is an interesting case where providing more individual choice
can have negative side-effects. Patients have complained that
they cannot turn off the continual advertising on pay-TV screens
even if they choose not to use the facilities; TV in wards can
be intrusive and distressing for seriously ill patients and their
relatives.
There is scope to use changes more creatively.
In private hospitals, patients pay for better hotel services,
such as meals and alcohol (if medically acceptable). Since paying
for car parking and TV is common in the NHS, why not extend the
choice and charge for them?
29. Would enforcing equity in a co-funded,
choice-driven system imply a proliferation of regulators on the
model of the Office of Fair Access for the universities?
Equity in service delivery is as much a matter
of winning hearts and minds as it is of legislation and service
standards. Therefore, it may prove difficult to attempt to enforce
equity through regulation. It is too early to say whether the
OfFA will prove effective.
The Audit Commission is committed to strategic
regulation that is proportionate to risk. Government may find
this model of regulation useful here.
RAISING STANDARDS
30. What is the nature of choice within a
framework of uniform standards?
There need to be uniform minimum standards for
service delivery which ensure an acceptable level of service and
safety.
Clearly, these standards cannot cover everything
comprehensively; they cannot take account of individual circumstances
and preferences, for example, whether someone is willing and able
to travel to a hospital outside their own region, in order to
reduce the waiting time for an operation.
Uniform standards do not have to preclude choicethey
merely specify the choices that can be offered to users.
31. How can an individual's choice enhance
national standards and accountability?
People define what they value by the way that
they vote. However, "public value" also includes intangibles
such as perceptions of fairness, choices that will affect for
future generations, etc. These voting choices are then translated
into expectations of basic entitlement; and government sometimes
further translates these into national minimum standards against
which public sector providers may be held to account.
EVIDENCE BASE
32. Is there already sufficient evidence,
research and experience to judge the effect of greater choice
on equity in public services?
Research evidence is available, including studies
by Perri 6; [63]the
Local Government Association; [64]The
New Local Government Network; [65]and
The European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working
Conditions. [66]
There has been relatively little work looking
at the issue of choice across services, or exploring the implications
for collective decision-making processes. Most policy analysis
and evaluation has been service specific, for exampleParental
choice in schools; Patient choice in the NHS; Choice based lettings
in social housing; and Choice in social care.
There is research in progress, which may have
a bearing on equity, including an Audit Commission study on choice;
[67]the
London Patient Choice Project; [68]The
Open University study; [69]and
the Social Market Foundation study. [70]
33. Does the functioning so far of parental
and patient choice support the argument that it promotes equity?
It is possible to find champions for each side
of the argument. Several academics,[71]
,[72]
[73]and
many of the leading think tanks in the policy community have published
material that deals with the arguments for and against choice.
For example the Fabian Society; [74]The
Kings' Fund; [75][76]
and the Social Market Foundation. [77]
34. Are there lessons that can be learned
from other countries and if so are they readily applicable here?
Over the last 25 years there has been a strong
focus on public sector reform in Australia, with improvements
in service delivery being an important part of this reform. Drivers
of improved service delivery include a better informed, better
educated and more demanding public, and improvements in technology,
which have increased the capacity to provide more immediate and
responsive services. Competitive pressures have also demanded
increased productivity, and facilitated higher quality and effectiveness.
The increased focus on improving service delivery is reflected
in the approaches of a number of agencies.
One example is the Job Network, a system of
non-government organisations, both profit and non-profit, which
have won tenders to provide employment-related services to unemployed
people on behalf of DEWR. The Job Network seeks to tailor services
more to individual needs, and provides an element of choice for
individuals over their service provider. Evaluations of the Network
have concluded that the new system is substantially more cost-effective
than the former employment services arrangements, and that the
quality of service has improved.
Another example is the Australian User Choice
policy. This is a national policy governing the flow of public
funds to training providers that works in conjunction with the
New Apprenticeships System. The objective of the User Choice policy
is to make the vocational education and training system more responsive
to the needs of industry and employers and therefore of more benefit
to people receiving training. In principle, the flow of public
funds to individual training organisations reflects the client's
choice of provider. The User Choice policy was endorsed by the
Ministers for vocational education and training in May 1997 and
amended in November 2000.
Under the User Choice policy, the "client"
is the employer and employee identified in the training contract,
acting jointly. This definition reinforces the ideal that vocational
education should benefit both the people being trained and the
companies that employ them. Each state and territory is responsible
for implementing User Choice in its jurisdiction. The User Choice
policy sets out guidelines that the states and territories follow.
45 Audit Commission [2003] Trust in the Public Sector,
MORI report for the Audit Commission. Back
46
Audit Commission [2003] Achieving the NHS Plan. Back
47
Koen, Vincent [2000] Public Expenditure Reform: the Health Care
Sector in the UK, OECD: Economics Department Working Papers No.256. Back
48
Audit Commission [2003] Primary Care Prescribing: a bulletin
for primary care trusts. Back
49
Audit Commission [1999] Listen Up! Back
50
Audit Commission [2002] Equality and Diversity. Back
51
Holmes, C [2003] Housing, equality and choice, Institute of Public
Policy Research. Back
52
Audit Commission [ 2002 ] A picture of performance: early lessons
from Comprehensive Performance Assessment. Back
53
Patients judge doctors more on their "bedside manner"
than on their clinical ability. They may need GPs to help them
understand options and the consequences. Marshall, M. and others
[2000]; Dying to Know: public release of information about quality
of healthcare, Nuffield Trust. Back
54
See Appendix 3 and Hasler F [2003] Clarifying the evidence on
direct payments into practice, National Centre for Independent
Living. Back
55
Audit Commission [1999] Listen Up! Back
56
Audit Commission [2003] Council tax increases 2003/04 Why were
they so high? Back
57
Le Grand, J [2004] Motivation, Agency and Public Policy: of Knights,
Knaves, Pawns and Kings. Back
58
Audit Commission [2002] Trading Places Update; [1996] The Supply
and Allocation of School Places. Back
59
Audit Commission [2003] Primary care prescribing. Back
60
Audit Commission [1993] Helping with Enquiries: tackling crime
effectively. Back
61
Financial Times 16 February 2004 Feature on the (Gershon)
Efficiency Review: the leaked report. Back
62
Audit Commission [1999] The price is right: charges for council
services. Back
63
Perri 6 [2002] Giving consumers of British public services more
choice: what can be learned from recent history? Institute for
Applied Health and Social Policy, King's College, London. http://www.hsmc.bham.ac.uk/staff/staffdetails/6p/pdfs/P6%20Consumer%20choice%20in%20British%20public%20services.pdf Back
64
Local Government Association [2004] Enabling Choice: research
on choice in public services. Back
65
New Local Government Network Making choices. Back
66
European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working
Conditions [2000]. Social Public Services: Quality of Working
Life and Quality of Service: Summary of the Danish National Report. Back
67
Audit Commission research in progress 2004: study on choice in
public services. Back
68
http://www.london.nhs.uk/patientchoice/overview.htm. Back
69
Open University: research in progress 2004: Creating Citizen-consumers:
changing relationships and identifications. Back
70
Social Market Foundation: research in progress 2004 Choice and
Voice in Public Services. Back
71
Gorad and Sitz [1998a] The more things change . . . the missing
impact of marketization, British Journal of the Sociology of Education,
Vol.19, p 363 to 367. Back
72
Bradley, S and Taylor, J [2002] The report card on competition
in schools, Adam Smith Institute. Back
73
Brigham, H. [2000] School choice and social justice, OUP. Back
74
Levett, Roger and others [2003] "A better choice of choice:
quality of life, consumption and economic growth", Fabian
Society. Back
75
King's Fund [2003] Can market forces be used for good? Shaping
the new NHS. Back
76
King's Fund [2003] What is the Real Cost of More Patient Choice. Back
77
Pollard, Stephen and Raymond, Katherine [1999] A Question of
Choice: Public Priorities for Health Care. Back
|