Select Committee on Public Administration Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum by Reform (CVP 16)

1.  ABOUT REFORM

  Reform (www.reform.co.uk) is an independent, non-party think tank whose mission is to set out a better way to deliver public services and economic prosperity.

  We believe that by liberalising the public sector, breaking monopoly and extending choice, high quality services can be made available for everyone.

  Our vision is of a Britain with 21st Century healthcare, high standards in schools, a modern and efficient transport system, safe streets, and a free, dynamic and competitive economy.

2.  OVERVIEW

  The premise of the Committee's questions appears to be that there is something problematic about choice. In fact, the real problem is the current performance of Britain's traditionally structured public services (see Box A). The short answer to the Committee is that it should visit the Netherlands, Sweden or inner city Milwaukee—all of which operate successful school choice programmes—or France, Germany or Switzerland—where patients have choice—and ask people if they want their right to choose taken away from them.

  The fundamental reality is that the 1940s assumption that government production of services such as healthcare and education was necessary to ensure efficiency and equity has been shown to be false. As Alan Milburn has pointed out with respect to the NHS: "In 50 years health inequalities have widened not narrowed. Too often even today the poorest services tend to be in the poorest communities" (11 February 2003). The Wanless report also found "evidence of inequality in access to healthcare resources . . . People living in more deprived areas who died of cancer used fewer healthcare resources than those in middle or affluent areas" (Wanless Interim Report).

  How organisations respond to challenge tells you much about whether they are successful or not. In weak organisations, managers find countless reasons for not embracing change. The more talented and intelligent are the managers, the more such organisations are able to find reasons not to act and to carry on as before. In the private sector, such companies lose sales and eventually go out of business. In the public sector, the organisation suffers no such penalty. Instead the costs of failure are transferred to the users of public sector in the form of higher taxes and levels of service which would simply not be accepted in most other European countries. All too often those most let down are the most disadvantaged in society who neither have the cash nor the voice to obtain something better, the very people for whom these systems were created in the first place.


  In this respect, it is very encouraging that progressive politicians in all three main political parties are moving in the right direction. The Prime Minister often speaks of the importance of "choice and competition" in improving public services and the 1999 Modernising Government White Paper stressed the need to lever up standards "wherever practicable by giving the public the right to choose." This summer, the Conservative Party launched its "Right to Choose" and was followed by some senior Liberal Democrats advocating, in the Orange Book, amongst other things a social insurance system for funding healthcare.

  Real choice is both a social and a moral experience. The ability to choose is intrinsic to human dignity. It turns on free will, the capacity to choose—which is learned—and the expectation of being able to do so as a responsible adult. In addition to these powerful moral properties, it is economically superior than command-and-control systems. In other words, choice combines efficiency and equity.

3. PERSONAL SERVICES AND PUBLIC GOODS

  It cannot be stressed often enough that healthcare and education are not public services. They are personal services. By their nature, they are intensely so—far more so than many products and services currently provided purely by the private sector. Every child is different, with different needs, ambitions and aptitudes. The personal nature of healthcare is even more self-evident; it is necessarily personal, intimate and specific to the individual.

  The public interest, or the public good, is different. In the case of healthcare and schools, it is primarily about ensuring access to quality provision for all. Defining clearly the public interest in the provision of personal service then naturally defines the proper role of government. It is to fund access and provide an unintrusive system of regulation. It therefore requires changing the nature of the government's role from being a producer to being a funder and regulator.


  It is simply wrong in fact as well as theory to suppose that the public interest objective of ensuring access for all can only be secured by the government taking on the role of being a monopoly producer, as was assumed in the immediate post-war period and which today is a relic of an obsolete and discredited ideology. Evidence from school choice programmes abroad demonstrates the complete compatibility of ensuring access for all and private sector provision. In the Netherlands for example, 70% of children attend independent schools. In France, one third of hospitals are non-stated owned and in Germany the proportion is 50%. Both countries deliver higher quality healthcare more equitably than is the case in Britain, not relying on waiting lists to regulate demand (see Box B.)

  Failure to define clearly the exact nature of the public interest in the provision of personal services such as healthcare and education and to recognise that for the most part these are private or merit goods, not public goods, leads to a great deal of muddle and generation of spurious problems, as can be seen from the Committee's own paper (especially the top of page 4). The existence of external benefits from the consumption of private goods and services does not turn them into public goods; if it did, virtually all economic activity could be so classified. An example of a genuinely public good would be public health programmes to prevent mass epidemics. Although very important, it constitutes a small fraction of healthcare activity in this country. The starting point therefore is to recognise the public interest element in the provision of personal services and to focus the government's role on it. Overwhelmingly, it is about ensuring access irrespective of means. The proper role of government therefore is to fund access.

4.  THE EMPOWERED CONSUMER

  In June the Prime Minister said: "Some still argue that people—usually other people—don't want choice. That, for example, they just want a single excellent school and hospital on their doorstep. In reality, I believe people do want choice". We agree. Too many recent opinion poll questions have falsely asked people to choose between good local services and "choice", when the very point of choice is that it can and does lead to better services. More sophisticated opinion research indicates that people do want choice (see Box C). Furthemore the view that ordinary members of the public are incapable of making choices that, for instance, are routinely made by purchasers of private education or healthcare is patronising and offensive.

  Choice is about empowering consumers. It means they make the purchase decision and requires that spending power be put directly in their hands. Cash speaks louder than words. "Voice" is not a substitute for choice. "Collective choice" and "government choice" (questions 9 and 10) are variants of "voice" and deny the individual choice.


  Money—unlike occasional "consultation"' in politics, or infrequent voting, or having a say—empowers all. This includes the poor, the old, the silent, the unorganised, the discreet, the non-politicised; those who do not wish to join a pressure group or be "active citizens". These mechanisms tend to create new opportunities for producer capture and risk further entrenchment of vested interests. The recent referendum result in the North East and low turn-outs for votes on foundation hospitals show what voters think about such political mechanisms which are often, but wrongly, promoted as substitutes for genuine choice.

  Sometimes it is argued, as the Chancellor does, that because of information asymmetries, the consumer is not sovereign in healthcare. But if the consumer is not sovereign, who is? Few people today subscribe to the 1940s view that the man in Whitehall knows best, and the idea that the man or woman in the Town Hall or some other public sector bureaucracy should exercise sovereignty would not win public support if argued for openly.

  The argument about information asymmetry misses the point. There are many areas of life in which consumers require specialised knowledge and advice. In a system where the patient, for example, has the purchasing power, rather than having to act as a supplicant for it, his or her GP or other specialist acts for them on their behalf, guiding them through the choices and helping them decide what is in their best interest. Instead, we have a situation where people feel they can get lost in a system in which no one seems to looking after them and professionals are working to meet government targets rather than directly satisfy the people who are paying them—their patients.

5.  CHOICE AND COMPETITION VS MONOPOLY

  Another argument made against choice is that it is less efficient, because it costs more and requires more capacity (top of page 3 of the issues document). The premise of this argument is that monopoly is better than competition. It is certainly not a view that the Chancellor—or anyone else—accepts when it comes to the private sector, where the Government operates a strong pro-competition regime. Both economic theory and experience show that monopolies produce less, charge more and offer a narrow range of services than firms in competitive markets. Furthermore, monopolies are more vulnerable to producer capture and have weaker incentives to serve their customers. Why the disconnect between being pro-competition when it comes to the private sector and against it when it comes to the public sector? There is no difference in principle between public and private sector monopolies, except that public sector monopolies have a demonstrable tendency to be less efficient.

  It might be that in some hypothetical static world monopolies need less capacity than in competitive markets. But in the real world, change is a fact of life. Innovation changes what is possible and enables more to be offered for less. In the private sector, companies, whether they are airlines, mobile phone companies or hotel chains often have more capacity than they need—but they are rewarded for finding ways of using this capacity; markets grow and consumers get a better deal all round. This is a way of ensuring the focus is where it should be—on the customer.

  The public sector lacks this dynamic. In the NHS, capacity is used to limit demand, rather than "excess" capacity being used to meet demand and provide more. As a result, waiting lists are a fact of life in the NHS and will remain so even as Britain's spending on healthcare approaches and overtakes the EU average. With schools, we have a static pattern of provision where good schools are not encouraged to expand and where bad schools are kept in being, even though they are letting down generation after generation of schoolchildren.

  Effectively liberalising and incentivising the supply side will both cause more capacity to be made available to consumers and improve efficiency. For this reason, supply side reform goes hand in hand with reforming the demand side by placing purchasing power directly in the hands of consumers.

6.  CONCLUSION

  The old way is not working. The costs of failure are borne not only by users of public services, but by the economy more widely. Despite huge increases in public spending, we are not seeing improvements commensurate with the increased inputs. The most recent productivity statistics for the NHS show declining productivity, a reversal of the trend of the early and mid-1990s. The implications are stark: each extra £1 billion of spending is buying less.

  Society has changed almost out of recognition since the 1940s, when our pubic services were designed. Public expectations are rising, fuelled by people's experience of greater choice, innovation, quality and availability of new services in the private sector (see Box D). The days when we could expect people to queue patiently for services or accept substandard provision without question are over.

  A new approach to public services is needed. For too long the debate has been presented as a choice between the status quo of state monopoly or the total absence of government support. This is a false choice. Real reform is not about withdrawing the State. It is about changing the nature of the State's intervention to match its competencies. Other countries demonstrate that it is possible to deliver services with far greater consumer choice yet more equitably than our own. To dwell on the difficulties of injecting choice into a monopolistic system in which consumers have no real power is to miss the real need, which is to break down the barriers between public and private provision and redirect the spending power of the State to consumers, so ensuring that choice and access to the highest quality services is extended to all.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 17 March 2005