UNCORRECTED TRANSCRIPT OF ORAL EVIDENCE To
be published as HC 49 - v
House of COMMONS
MINUTES OF EVIDENCE
TAKEN BEFORE
PUBLIC administration SELECT COMMITTEE
CHOICE, VOICE AND PUBLIC SERVICES
THURSday 27 JANUARY 2005
MR STEPHEN TWIGG MP and RT HON NICK
RAYNSFORD MP
Evidence heard in Public Questions 479 - 541
USE OF THE TRANSCRIPT
1.
|
This is an uncorrected transcript of
evidence taken in public and reported to the House. The transcript has been
placed on the internet on the authority of the Committee, and copies have
been made available by the Vote Office for the use of Members and others.
|
2.
|
Any public use of, or reference to, the
contents should make clear that neither witnesses nor Members have had the
opportunity to correct the record. The transcript is not yet an approved
formal record of these proceedings.
|
3.
|
Members who receive this for the purpose of correcting questions
addressed by them to witnesses are asked to send corrections to the Committee
Assistant.
|
4.
|
Prospective
witnesses may receive this in preparation for any
written or oral evidence they may in due course give to the Committee.
|
Oral Evidence
Taken
before the Public Administration Select Committee
on
Thursday 27 January 2005
Members present
Tony Wright, in the Chair
Mrs Anne Campbell
Mr David Heyes
Mr Kelvin Hopkins
Mr Gordon Prentice
________________
Memoranda submitted by Department for Education and
Skills
and the Office of the Deputy Prime Minister
Examination of Witnesses
Witnesses:
Mr Stephen Twigg a Member of the House, Minister of State,
Department for Education and Skills, and the Rt Hon Nick
Raynsford a Member of the House, Minister of State, Office of the Deputy
Prime Minister, examined.
Q479 Chairman: I welcome our
witnesses this morning and call the Committee to order. This is the last evidence session in our
inquiry into what we have been calling Choice and Voice in Public Services
so we like to think that by now we know some of these issues. We wanted very much to hear from Ministers
in key departments that have an interest in choice and voice issues; so it is
appropriate that we should end with Nick Raynsford, Minister of State, ODPM,
and Stephen Twigg, Minister of State at DfES.
Thank you for coming along and the memoranda. Nick, can I ask you to start, to get a way in to thinking about
choice and voice and the relationship between them. You are the Minister for Local Government. The old theory of voice goes that local
government provides services; if people are not happy about them, they remove
the people who provide them and put someone else in. That does not work in practice, does it - or does it?
Mr Raynsford: It works to a degree, but we have appreciated that the voice alone
is probably not sufficient if you want to achieve really responsive public services. Let me give an illustration. The ability to vote out councillors if you
are not satisfied with them has not been a motor to transform services such as
the lettings service for council housing, which, probably for several decades,
continued on an assumption that it was possible to operate an administrative
system that would achieve fairness and would therefore meet the main objectives
for which the council felt it was responsible.
In reality, it created a framework where the public felt alienated. They did not understand the process and felt
that they were largely left at the mercy of bureaucrats or others who would
take decisions that they did not understand; and you and most other MPs will
have had lots of experience of constituents coming to your surgery - and they
certainly come to mine - expressing deep unhappiness about the way that system
operated. It seemed to me, when I was
Minister for Housing, that the logical answer was to try and work towards a
system where individual applicants had more say in the process and were able to
exercise a degree of choice, and in doing so would come to understand the
constraints that inevitably apply in this kind of process. The experience of choice-based lettings is
that it has made a remarkable change in the relationship both between
applicants and the council and the council staff. It has helped improve the workings of the lettings system. In places like Newham we have seen the
letting time halve since they have brought a choice-based system in, because
people are more committed to properties if they have a say in the process, and
are less likely to refuse an unpopular one if they know they might be there for
only a short period of time because they can then exercise a further choice. There are all sorts of benefits that have
come as a result of introducing a choice element, which did not come through
the traditional process. I am not
saying that it would not eventually have come, but I believe that simply relying
on voice alone is not enough.
Q480 Chairman: I am sure we
will come to examples as we go along, but I am trying to tease out what it is
about the way in which we have accountability for services now which make them
not very responsive to these performance factors. You have done some work on it, have you not, with the
comprehensive performance assessment system that has been introduced, trying to
make some connection between what happens when people vote and the published
performance of local authorities? What
does that reveal?
Mr Raynsford: The comprehensive performance assessment has been an attempt to
provide detailed and objective evidence about the performance of local
authorities, both their corporate performance - how they run their affairs and
manage their finances, and how their resource management decisions are taken -
and also looking at the performance of individual services. Together, from an aggregate of those
assessments, an overall judgment is formed as to the performance of that local
authority; but that is also used to drive improvement, whether in terms of
corporate performance or individual services.
This has informed decision-making, and it is noticeable that in some
cases authorities that have been significantly worse than average, or those
that are significantly better than average, have tended to buck the trend at
elections. In 2003, for example, at the
local elections, the Conservatives were generally doing well and getting
significant gains in most parts of the country, but I take the south-west as an
illustration. Two particular councils
spectacularly bucked the trend.
Plymouth went from Conservative to Labour control; and Torbay went from
Conservative to Liberal Democrat control.
I do not think it is coincidental that both of those councils received
poor ratings in the comprehensive performance assessment, and there were clear
problems associated with the authority.
I believe that the assessment has helped - not everywhere, because it
will not happen everywhere - but it has helped to inform the public, and that
may give added force to the voice element.
Q481 Chairman: Therefore, would
you urge a sensible consumer of local public services to vote for an authority
in terms of their performance, as opposed to any existing political
predilection?
Mr Raynsford: It is an interesting and difficult question for anyone who stands
on a party ticket, but let me just say that I do not think local government has
been well served in the past by a tendency to vote the party ticket
irrespective of performance. It has
been particularly depressing for councillors who have run their council well to
find that they have been voted out of office because their party has been
unpopular at a national level. I think
it is right that people should be able to differentiate more, and processes
like the comprehensive performance assessment do give information that enable
the public to differentiate more.
Q482 Chairman: I am sorry to
press you, but are you saying, as the Minister, "vote for performance not the
party ticket"?
Mr Raynsford: Of course, it would be difficult to say that overtly for reasons
you will fully understand, but you heard me say, and I will repeat it, that it
is right that the electorate should be informed about performance and it is
right that they should be able to form a judgment on performance.
Mr Twigg: For many local authorities education will be their biggest area of
spend, and it is fair to say that it would be highly unusual for education
performance, the performance of local schools or indeed the performance of the
LEA to be the main, or even a major issue in a local election campaign. That demonstrates that that voice element
which consists of the election of the local education authority can only be one
of the ways in which we can secure improvement in schools.
Q483 Chairman: One of the
things that everyone agrees on in the conversation about choice is that unless
we have substantial capacity in systems, then choice in all kinds of ways will
not exist, or at least it would be severely limited; and yet is it not the case
that in relation to both social housing, which is your responsibility, Nick,
and schools, this is precisely the problem?
There is too little supply of the commodity that people want and too
much demand for that commodity; so unless we do something pretty dramatic on
the capacity side in these areas, we are not going to get hold of choice in a
way that is going to bite, are we?
Mr Raynsford: Capacity is important, but it is not a block to the use of
choice. Let me give two illustrations
of that. When I was developing the idea
of choice-based lettings, an awful lot of people said to me, "you are wasting
your time; this is simply a non-starter, and in areas of high demand there is
no way that you can have a choice-based system because the demand is far
greater than the supply". I persevered, and I am pleased to say that one of the
first successful pilots was in Camden, an area of very high demand. It revealed that there are certain
efficiencies that come from a choice-based system, because if you can speed up
lettings because there is a greater degree of willingness to move in to a
property if you are committed to it - which is the case with a choice-based
scheme, as against a traditional allocation scheme - then that in turn will
help to tackle the problem of supply.
While it will not overcome the problems, it will help. The other thing is that if you begin to look
more widely than the immediate area and give people opportunities to consider
options elsewhere that they may previously not have considered, then that too
can help to relieve the pressure, because not everyone automatically feels they
want to live in Camden. Very many
people will, but there may be some who are willing to consider options
elsewhere if there are opportunities to move, and particularly if they can get
help with finding employment in the other area and so on. Information about a wider choice may help to
achieve efficiency gains and make better use of the resources; and that is
particularly relevant in a country where we have a mismatch between very high
demand in relation to supply in the south, and quite low demand in relation to
available supply in other parts of the country. Making better use of unused resources as part of a choice-based
can improve the overall supply/demand equation. I accept that capacity is an issue, but I do not accept that it
is a block to a choice-based system.
Q484 Chairman: We heard from
the Director of Housing in Newham, who told us for example that popular
properties might receive over 400 bids.
Does that not make the case acutely that unless we get the supply side
right, we can tell people how we have moved over to a choice system, but for
them their chance of getting the properties they want does not seem better than
it was before.
Mr Raynsford: But there are two other aspects to it. I have talked about greater efficiency. He may or may not have given you the evidence, but we certainly
have the figures, that the average void time between lettings in Newham has
fallen from 50 to 25 days as a result of the introduction of a choice-based
letting scheme, so that is creating greater efficiency. The second point is that when people realise
that the most popular properties have a very, very long waiting time, they may
well themselves decide, rather than hanging on in the hope they might get that,
to go for a second-best option where they can have a prospect of getting it
sooner. In a situation where they have
made that choice themselves, they may be a lot happier to go into it than if
they are simply told, "you are not going to get the property of your choice;
this is all we can offer you" in a traditional letting system. It can help both to extend the public's
understanding of constraints and it can also help achieve efficiency gains along
the lines I have described.
Q485 Chairman: This looks
sometimes as though we are saying, "we cannot give you the choice that you
want, but we are going to interest you in a different kind of choice that you
do not particularly want but which we would like you to have". The DfES website advising parents says, "you
should not risk wasting your first choice by choosing a school where you stand
little chance of getting a place". We
know that the volume of admissions appeals has gone up enormously in the last
ten years. We are saying, "while we
talk about choice, we cannot actually give you your choice, but be sensible and
choose something else".
Mr Twigg: For choice to be a reality for parents, it is important that they
have got information. Our website,
along with a number of other vehicles, is a vital way of achieving that. Clearly, capacity is a constraint in terms
of school choice, although I would make the point that at the moment we have
about 700,000 surplus school places, so this is a picture that varies
enormously from one part of the country to another. We allow therefore those schools that are successful and popular
and want to expand, to expand. Another
way is to put a lot of emphasis on our programmes on improving the other
schools so that they can attract genuine support and can become first-choice
schools. The other thing is to use the
opportunity of the falling rolls that we have in many parts of the country to
say that when an area is facing those falling rolls we do not necessarily want
to see schools close down; it may be an opportunity to provide a wider range of
choices in that area.
Q486 Chairman: We have asked
this of other people, so let us take our town with two secondary schools. One is at the rough end of town, which
people are not terribly keen to go to and does not perform very well, and one
at the well-heeled end of town, which does very well and is top of the league
tables, which everyone wants to go to and is over-subscribed. If I am in the rough end of town and hear
about choice, and I think that it is a good idea and want to exercise choice, I
would want to go to the other school.
However, I apply and am told that I am outside the catchment area. How does choice connect with people in
circumstances like that?
Mr Twigg: Let me say two things about that, Tony. Choice on its own, clearly, is not a sufficient mechanism to
secure improvement in the school that is not doing as well, and that is why we
have programmes like Excellence in Cities, the Academies Programme, et cetera, to focus on those
schools. The other is to say that it
will depend on what is decided locally should be the admissions criteria. Typically, the policy will be one that says
it is siblings and then distance from school, but there are admissions policies
that are allowable under our code that might well mean the person who lives at
the rough end of town can still get in to the other school - for example the
banding system that is still used in a number of London boroughs to ensure a
comprehensive intake into schools. As
we said in our evidence, most people live within a reasonable range of more
than two secondary schools. We live in
a very urban country, and whilst there is a set of issues for rural schools,
which of course we need to face, from memory 70 per cent of secondary schools
are within two miles of two other secondary schools; in other words, for most
people they are within two miles of three different secondary schools, so
choice is not necessarily the kind of relevance it is presented as being, even
in those areas.
Chairman: I am sure we will want to explore some of those ideas shortly.
Q487 Mrs Campbell: Stephen, to follow up on that, one of the
problems with choice is, is it not, that schools that are over-subscribed are
able to select pupils, and they often select those pupils who are the least
difficult, leaving the schools that people do not choose with the pupils that
nobody wants. How are you going to
overcome that problem?
Mr Twigg: We want to do all that we can to prevent schools from doing what
you have described, and in particular undertaking covert forms of social and
academic selection. That is why over
the years we have made a number of changes to the code of practice under which
school selection operates. My
experience of these things is that they vary enormously from one locality to
another. It depends on the
relationships that exist between schools, between schools and the local
education authority, as well as depending on the particular admissions policy
that is adopted in that local area.
Q488 Mrs Campbell: That is all
very well, but over a period of time that choice mechanism can lead to some
schools doing extremely well and other schools doing worse than they would
otherwise do. I have that situation in
my own constituency of an increasingly diverse secondary sector. In addition, we observed that in Birmingham
there is a multiplicity of choice - grammar schools, faith schools, specialist
schools, single-sex schools, and academies coming along - but in reality a lot
of parents do not have a choice because if their child does not pass the
11-plus or happens to be the wrong sex or of the wrong faith, then they are
allocated to a school that does not have particularly good exam results. How do you overcome that? I thought that the system in Birmingham was
a total mess, quite frankly.
Mr Twigg: What I would say about that is that we want to have admissions
policies that are objective and fair.
Those are the two key tests for any admissions policy. The typical policy will be one that is based
on a sibling, special needs, and then distance from the school. That is the typical policy for pretty good
reasons; there is something in terms of objectivity and also fairness that can
be well justified with respect to those policies. The reason that we do not impose a national approach but allow
these things to be determined locally is that what may be right for Birmingham
may well not be right for rural Northumberland or for an inner or outer London
borough. That is why we allow different
practices to develop in different areas.
I come back to the point that whilst choice is important in itself and
can be a lever for improvement, on its own it is not enough. The school that you and Tony have described
which languishes will often need extra support, be that in resources, be that a
change of status or be that a change of leadership. Some of our most impressive programmes that have worked have been
ones that recognise that alongside choice, and if they succeed they become
schools that a lot of parents want to send their children to.
Q489 Mrs Campbell: Professor Brighouse suggested to us that
difficult pupils should have a 300 per cent funding allocation awarded to
them. Have you considered those kinds
of schemes? Perhaps I can explain the
other problem that I have first. In my
area the schools that do well are the ones in middle-class areas, where there
is a premium on the house prices in order to get your child into a particular
school. It looks like a very fair and
balanced admissions system, but because they are taking children from around the
school what is happening is that parents who have sufficient money are paying a
premium on their house prices in order to get their child into a particular
school. That does not seem to me to be
very fair; it is giving choice to those who are well off and not those who are
not.
Mr Twigg: Let me address both points.
I read Harry Brighouse's written evidence and his oral evidence here in
the Committee. Actually, I took a look
earlier on at the different per-pupil funding for different authorities. Whilst there is certainly not a 300 per cent
uplift, there is a very significant difference between the per-pupil funding of
Tower Hamlets, in the deprived East End of London, which has the highest
per-pupil funding in the country, and per-pupil funding in some parts of the
country. It is almost double, if you
compare Tower Hamlets with other parts of the country. We therefore do already, within the funding
system we have, recognise that pupils from deprived backgrounds and pupils
where in the early years English is an additional language, for example, should
carry a greater cost because that is something the school will require in order
to educate them properly.
Q490 Mrs Campbell: Can I stop
you there because actually people do not choose a local authority; they choose
a school within a local authority.
Therefore you have to have a system of allocation within local
authorities that allocates more money to those pupils that have a deprived
background or some special need.
Mr Twigg: You raise a really interesting issue about the balance of the
responsibility of central government and local government with respect to
funding of schools. As you will be
aware, Anne, we have taken greater control centrally about the amount that has
to be spent on schools at the local level, but the local authority still has
the decision on the formula for dividing that money up. There is some evidence from IPPR which was
published 18 months ago that whilst our formula is pretty re-distributive, the
local formula often reverses the re‑distributive effect of the national
formula, so that sometimes the better-off school is being funded just as well
as the school in the poorer part of the area.
We do have a responsibility in our discussions, as a department, with
local authorities to correct that so that the needy school within the authority
is benefiting, not just the local authority as a whole. On your second point about the impact of
good schools on property prices and therefore who can afford to live near good
schools, I have exactly the same experience in my own constituency with higher
property prices close to popular schools.
It is undeniably a feature of the system. There is clearly a range of different options to deal with
that. One option, which is not
exclusive but an option that we are pursuing, is to do everything we can to
improve the other schools. You can have
an impact in that way. However, in
terms of a policy to deal with that, there are two different routes we can
take. I mentioned banding, which is the
system that the Inner London Education Authority used to use, and which quite a
lot of London boroughs kept after ILEA was abolished, which says "we want X
number of children in each ability band".
The result of that is that if a school happens to be located in a very
prosperous area, nevertheless children from further afield who may be in lower
bands and in poorer areas of that borough or a neighbouring borough can get
in. That is one policy that is adopted
in some places. The other one, which I
know the Committee has considered and discussed with Harry Brighouse and
others, is to have a lottery to determine the over-subscribed places. Actually, there is nothing in our law or
even in our code that says you cannot have a lottery. There is a school in Burnley that operates a lottery. It was challenged in the courts about ten
years ago successfully, so it is still in place. One of the new academies in London, the Lewisham Academy, which brings
together the Haberdasher's CTC with Mallory School, a struggling school, will
have a policy where 50 per cent of its places on over-subscription are
allocated by lottery within a wide catchment area. A lottery is a possible option within the code and law as it
stands.
Q491 Mrs Campbell: I accept that it may be a possible option; I
do not accept that there is any real incentive at the moment for particularly a
good school, an over-subscribed school, to adopt a lottery system because the
school will want to select its pupils as far as it can, and in handing it over
to a lottery the school is then relinquishing control over the pupils it
accepts. From the point of view of the
parents who are trying to get their children into the school that they want, a
lottery would be a much better system than the one we have at the moment.
Mr Twigg: There are some strengths in a lottery, but there are some very
serious drawbacks as well, which Philip Hunter, when he gave evidence, set out
very clearly, in terms of predictability for parents when they are
applying. In some respects, clearly, a
lottery system could be said to be fair because it removes covert selection or
biases and discrimination within the system.
On the other hand, a family that lives opposite a school that does not
get its child into that school, and the family four miles away does, would
probably not feel that it is a very fair system. There are arguments in terms of justice and fairness on both
sides.
Mr Raynsford: Can I broaden this, because education is obviously not my field but
there are wider philosophic issues here that are terribly important. The strength of feeling that leads so many
parents to go to such extraordinary lengths, including moving house, in order
to get the school of their choice, is a pretty clear indication of the
importance that many members of the public attach to a degree of choice in that
service, and that of course applies in others.
Philosophically, we have to decide whether we are going to work with the
grain of those instincts and find ways as far as possible to meet them while at
the same time meeting other principles of equity, which are hugely important to
us, or whether we try and stop any expression of that wish for choice. My own view, very strongly, is that you will
always fail if you try to stop the process, because the wish for a degree of
choice is so powerful that people will try and find other ways of achieving
it. It is much better to try and work
with the grain and find ways in which people can exercise a degree of choice,
but at the same time combine it with safeguards but prevent it from producing
the undesirable and inequitable outcomes that you have rightly highlighted.
Q492 Chairman: Surely,
lotteries go with the grain? People
love lotteries.
Mr Raynsford: I do not think there is any question of a lottery going with the
grain in terms of school places because the reason people move their home is to
get into a specific school, not in order to be in exactly the same position as
anyone else.
Q493 Mr Prentice: What about
where the exercise of choice conflicts with other public policy objectives? A couple of weeks ago we had the case of the
Muslim girls' school in Bradford with the greatest added value of any secondary
school in the United Kingdom. Should we
be explicitly encouraging the establishment of single-sex Muslim schools?
Mr Twigg: There is a very important principle here about equity. For decades we have had publicly-funded
Christian schools. They form a very
substantial proportion of the schools in our country, and I do not think we
could possibly say to the Muslim community or Sikh, Jewish or other
communities, that what is okay for Christians is not okay for them. Absolutely in terms of equity, we need to
give those schools that support.
Q494 Mr Prentice: We have had
all these reports talking about community cohesion.
Mr Twigg: Absolutely.
Q495 Mr Prentice: We do not
want a balkanised school system where children of a particular faith and a
particular race are isolated from their peers of a different religion. Do we really want to go down that road?
Mr Twigg: No, we do not want to go down that road. What is quite interesting, looking at those reports - and my
understanding of the situation in some of the northern towns where there were
disturbances - is that typically the major factors that resulted in segregation
were to do with housing policy rather than education policy. These were not necessarily places that had
Muslim schools, certainly not state Muslim schools. I think we should respect the fact that many parents want
faith-based education, but at the same time place responsibilities on all
schools, including faith schools, to promote race equality, community cohesion
and inter-faith dialogue. I am very
keen not to say "no" to the Muslim girls' school being a state school, but to
say to them, "yes, you can be a state school, but we want you working with the
local Catholic school, the local non-faith school". I think that is more realistic and fairer. We have to remember there is always the
choice of going private, and many of these state Muslim schools that have grown
up in recent years are not newly created from kids that previously went to
secular state schools; they were previously private Muslim schools. I would much rather have those schools in
the state system and part of the local family of schools, with regulation and
having to teach the National Curriculum, than existing independently of the
state system.
Q496 Mr Prentice: I understand
that, but the Government is actively promoting faith schools. Given that we are talking about a choice
agenda, should the Government be encouraging Muslim parents to exercise that
choice?
Mr Twigg: I need to be clear that we are not saying that there is the active
promotion by Government of new faith schools; that is not the policy. We are saying that we recognise that there
is the desire in some places either for existing independent faith schools,
particularly in the Muslim community, to come into the state system, or in some
cases for new schools, and we want to ensure that those communities have a
level playing-field and access to resources so that they can create those
schools. I do not go out into
communities I visit and say, "why do you not think about setting up a new
school" or "why does your independent school not become a state school?" It very much depends on local circumstances
and local discussion and the desire for that to happen.
Q497 Mr Heyes: Stephen has talked about secondary school
segregation deriving from housing policy.
I can give you a very powerful example of where I think you are wrong
about that. My home town is Oldham and
there are two secondary schools within a quarter of a mile or less, very close
to the town centre, in fact one on each side of where the riots took
place. One school is almost an
exclusively white Church of England school, and the other school is 98 per cent
Bangladeshi/Asian. Those schools are
surrounded by mixes and pockets of population, but they derive from
choice. It is selection masquerading as
choice through the existing system. The
hands-off approach, or encouragement of further choice is digging those
community tensions in even deeper. The
inquiry we had into Oldham talked about the need to generate community cohesion
through breaking down those educational divides. What Government policy currently does is replicate and reinforce
that segregation. Nothing has been done
to address that core problem. The root
of the problems in Oldham persists and nothing has been done about it.
Mr Twigg: What we say to those who wish to set up and provide a new faith
school is that we want to see what their plans are with respect to race
equality and community cohesion, which was not said before but which was part
of our response to the Cantle report and other reports. I would have to look into the specific
instance of the two schools in Oldham, but in my broader experience the Church
of England has been willing to consider a number of places being open to those
not of the Anglican faith.
Q498 Mr Heyes: There is some tokenism.
Mr Twigg: That is important if we are going to have the potential to open
those schools up to people from different faiths. In other parts of the country, there is not necessarily that
relationship between the faith and the ethnic origin. Many London Anglican and Catholic schools are hugely multi-faith
because a lot of black kids get in because they are Catholic or Anglican.
Q499 Chairman: Does this not
test the whole faith school issue and the issue of individual choice against
what you might call collective choice?
A group or individual may want a single-faith education for their child,
but collectively we may want our children to grow up in a society where faiths
connect and there is no segregation in the school system. You have two objectives here that are
incompatible. Somebody has to decide
where to cut this. One way would be to
say that we are stuck with faith schools because we have always had them and it
would be unfair to deny them to other groups, but we could at least make sure
that they could only take a certain percentage of people from that faith, and
therefore they had to become multi-faith schools.
Mr Twigg: Our task is to balance those two objectives. I accept that there can be a tension between
the two objectives. Clearly, the vast
bulk of faith schools are those provided by the Catholic church and the
Anglican Church, both of which have shown themselves amenable to taking
sometimes significant number of children who are not from that faith. I do not think it is necessarily tokenism on
their part. It would be very difficult
to say to new schools, whether they be Muslim or Jewish schools, "we expect you
to set up a new school and then require that the majority of places do not go
to children from your faith." I do not
think that would be seen as us taking seriously the desire in those communities
to have faith-based education.
Q500 Chairman: You could change
the rules for all faith schools so that a faith can set up a school, as any
provider can set up a school. We want
all kinds of groups to set up schools, but we could say that because we want to
be a certain kind of society, you have to take a certain percentage of people
who are not from your faith. Would that
not be a way of getting the balance better?
Mr Twigg: I think that would be very difficult in practice to implement, and
a much better way of achieving what you have described, with which I agree as
an objective, is to say that we want schools to work together. We want to break down barriers between
schools and promote opportunities for joint activity between schools. The whole area of 14-19 educational reform
gives us an incredible opportunity to do this.
That, by the way, is another element of choice. A lot of the discussion about choice is
choice between institutions. There is
also, just as importantly, choice within education for the learner.
Q501 Mr Hopkins: Britain is characterised by deep social
divisions, in contrast with several other continental European countries; and
these are most marked in education. Is
that not the result of the fact that we have had choice in education for a long
time? We have had a fragmented,
disparate, hierarchical education system, with some private, some public, some
independent and some not, and we have allowed this system to develop, and the
social divisions that have gone along with it.
Society has effectively allowed the middle-class, who are very energetic
about schools, to have what they want, and said "the Devil take the
hindmost". Society has said, "we do not
really care much about the bottom 30 per cent."
Mr Twigg: I do not think it is primarily.
I agree that clearly our education system has a major role to play in
bringing about a more just society and has played a part in the injustice you
have rightly described, but the factors that lead to the wide gap in terms of
outcomes between the richest and the poorest are far more deep-rooted and
widespread than simply being about education itself. One of your other witnesses went into this very eloquently - it
might have been Harry Brighouse - and put a very powerful case about child
poverty and the impact that has before kids are even at school. What is striking, and I suppose quite
depressing, is that some of these social divisions have been there, whether we
had the 11+ or comprehensives, whether we had kids going to their local school
or the kind of open enrolment and choice that we have had over the last 20-25
years. That says to me that we have to
have a focused government approach locally and nationally to those schools that
are failing. That is why Excellence in
Cities, the Academy Programme, and support for schools facing challenging
circumstances and the funding policies matter.
I do not think choice undermines that, but I accept that choice on its
own will not deliver the improvements in schools in inner-city Manchester or
inner-city London that is needed; we need those other programmes as well.
Q502 Mr Hopkins: I am pleased
to say that precisely that approach, taking failing schools, giving them extra
resources and boosting them has worked in my constituency. Poor schools out of special measures are
doing well. However, that is an
entirely different approach. That is a
planning approach; it is the Government deciding what needs to be done and
doing it to help the least well-off. It
is not simply a market in education. It
is not, as some people suggest, allowing the effective schools to grow and the
other schools to close. It is the
opposite of the market; it is intervening in the market place to even things
up.
Mr Twigg: I certainly do not favour a free market in the schools system. I do not think that that would be a sensible
policy approach to take at all. I do
think that you can combine elements of a market approach with the kind of
planned approach that you have described, Kelvin. That is what we are seeking to do. If we succeed, as you think we are on track in doing in your
constituency, then we get to the position where far more parents have a real
choice and far more parents have faith in the local school. That, for me, is what all of these different
policy programmes seek to achieve.
Choice can be a position lever for achieving that, or it can be
neutral. I do not think that choice
itself undermines the achievement of good quality schools in every
neighbourhood.
Q503 Mr Hopkins: In relation to
faith schools, in my constituency there is a large Catholic school but there
are more Catholics than can possibly go to that school and effectively that
becomes selective. The pressure on that
school is also to perform well at GCSE and A-Level, and therefore the
temptation to exclude less able pupils at 11 and to take in middle-class pupils
is very great; and the faith schools effectively become selective schools. If you had banding as well, insisting there
was a balanced population in those schools, it would be very different, but
that is not what the faith schools want.
Mr Twigg: To be fair to the Catholic Education Service and the Anglican
Church, when we discussed this a couple of years ago, they were very supportive
of the ways in which we have strengthened the code under which Catholic,
Anglican and other schools have to operate; so that for example the practice of
interviewing that was used by a very small number of schools, was outlawed in
the code, with the support of the Catholic Education Service and the Anglican
Church. I do not in any sense deny that
what you have described to happen. To
be fair, it does not only happen in faith schools, but it can happen with
others as well. What we have sought to
do through the code of practice we operate is to remove those sorts of
practices so that the over-subscription criteria are genuinely fair and sound.
Q504 Mr Hopkins: If, instead of pursuing
the choice agenda, a combination of banding, which I think is a good idea in
urban areas, plus the intervention to bring failing schools and guaranteeing
there is equal performance and equal provision in every school, that would stop
the middle class panicking that their children are going to go to a poor
school, and the thing would settle down and one could have genuinely good
performance throughout the system.
Mr Twigg: I do not disagree with the different elements you have
described. In some areas there is a
case for banding, and that is allowed within the code and the law as it
stands. What I think, though, is that
there is a danger that if you take choice out of the system, then there will be
a loss of faith in that system. There
then is always a choice for those who can afford it, which is to go
private. Some of the work I have been
involved in in the Department over the last two years is working specifically
with London secondary schools. There is
a particular set of issues in London, with a larger number of secondary aged
children going to private schools, and a much higher level of parental
dissatisfaction with the schools system.
If we were to say that in London - but this would apply elsewhere - we
are going to remove choice and go to the system that still operates in much of
America, where you are simply told to go to school, then we will see even more
parents sending their kids to private schools.
It is not only affluent middle-class parents in London who do this; a
lot of struggling parents will put all their savings into escaping the state
system in London. We have to change
that. How you change it is with a
variety of things, including some of those that you have mentioned; but choice
has an important part to play in bringing about that change.
Q505 Mr Hopkins: I think it is
admirable that our new Secretary of State has said she will send her children
to state schools in her borough of London.
On housing, Nick seems to be suggesting that what we are really doing is
managing expectations downwards for those who cannot afford owner-occupation
and saying, "if you cannot get into owner-occupation, do not expect society to
provide decent housing any more; we are going to wind down your expectations,
and we are going to do it under these kinds of choice". It will be like the lottery. The chances of winning the lottery are very,
very small, but if you hold out that hope it gives people a little buzz every
week to see if they have made it to the best house on the block; but it will
not happen for most people. Managing
down expectations contrasts with the post-war Labour government, which decided
to build decent homes for ordinary people.
I remember fifty years ago, when I was a schoolboy, I lived in
owner-occupation - one of the few - but they were housed in decent homes with
three bedrooms and gardens, which now sell for a third of a million pounds in
the Borough of Barnet; but they are no longer available for ordinary
families. Is that not what we are
doing, managing down?
Mr Raynsford: No, it is not, and I think what you do not recognise is the
extraordinary change in society since that period. The response in the immediate post-war period, when there was a
serious shortage of housing as a result of bomb damage and lack of investment
over the war years, plus the legacy of inherited slum housing from the 19th
century, required an enormous programme.
At that stage the assumption was that people would be living in mono-tenure
estates, all tenants in the estate with no variety at all, and people would
accept very little choice. The stories
were rife about how doors were all painted the same colour and so forth. Society has changed since then. At that time, most people on modest means
did not have very much choice in most aspects of their lives. On the whole, they had little choice over
where they worked, and in many communities it was almost inevitable, if you
grew up in a particular community, you would work in the industry that
dominated that communicated, whether it was an agricultural community or an
urban one. You did not have very much
choice about your housing. If the
council did not offer you a house, you would probably have little or no other
alternatives, and choice was not a major player in people's lives. It is now; people expect to have far greater
say over an enormous number of things.
To assume that somehow the public sector can operate in a parallel
universe where choice does not apply seems to me to be delusional. People expect to choose where they work, and
if they do not like the job they will move to another one. People expect to choose where they go on
holiday and do not expect to be regimented and told there is only one option -
"you can go to one particular holiday resort and that is the only choice open
to you". People do expect choice in
every other aspect of your lives, and to say you will not have a choice in
housing is entirely fallacious. Of
course, the growth in owner-occupation has reflected the aspirations of people
who wanted a different option. What we
now see is the mistake of having many estates with only people of one economic
grouping living in the same area. There
are obvious advantages in having mixed communities, where you can have options
for people to rent and to buy side by side.
Our overall housing policy is the creation of sustainable communities
through mixed developments, giving greater choice in purchase as against
renting, and crucially opportunities for low-cost home ownership for those
people who aspire to buy but do not have the means to buy outright, which is
why a great deal of focus currently is being put on key-worker housing and
other low-cost home ownership initiatives.
As part of that process we believe very strongly that people should be
able to exercise a degree of choice about where they live, rather than
depending on a bureaucrat to tell them "this is the house we have decided you
ought to live in". That is, frankly,
not compatible with the aspirations of today's society.
Q506 Mr Hopkins: You said that choice depends on having
surplus. If one compares Luton, where I
live, and which I represent now, with its enormous waiting list and many people
living in inadequate circumstances, with the 1970s when I was vice-chair of the
housing committee, we built hundreds of council houses every year and brought
the housing waiting list right down so that one could choose one's estate and
one could almost choose the road and choose to live near one's relatives and friends. That was real choice because there was
plenty of housing. Now the houses have
been sold on, house-building has stopped and there are plans to get rid of a
lot of it into other sectors, where the local authority will have less control
over what happens, and that choice will go.
My impression from what you said earlier still is that what you are
doing is reducing people's expectations, saying "you are not an owner-occupier;
do not expect too much".
Mr Raynsford: It is quite the opposite,
as I stressed. We are trying to promote
mixed developments where people will have an opportunity to rent or to buy and
there would be mixed tenure options for part ownership for those who cannot
afford outright a house purchase. Do
let us remember that people are not condemned to a particular economic status
throughout their lives. People's
economic circumstances change, and people who may for a period of time have
been renting a home may well, as their circumstances improve want to move into
owner-occupation. We should give them
that choice. We should not say, "you
will always live in one particular tenure".
Conversely, older people may well require a lot more support and
assistance, and it may be entirely appropriate for them to move out of outright
owner-occupation using some of the equity in their home perhaps to purchase
services, which is far better arranged through some kind of intermediate
tenure, shared-ownership tenure.
Q507 Mr Hopkins: You are not suggesting an alternative to
what I am suggesting, I am suggesting that mine should be as well. You are suggesting that having varied
estates and not having mono-designed houses, but we can do all that in a
planned way. Local authorities can be
given their head, and with a bit of inspiration and guidance from Government
could do that. They could do all the
things you say, and it is absolutely right; but there are still not enough
decent homes for people. They do not
have space and gardens, and there are families with children in tower blocks
who cannot go out because it is not safe.
That is what we are moving towards, and instead of building the houses
that people really want, which are houses with gardens, or low-rise flats or
whatever.
Mr Raynsford: I would agree with you that there is still a real problem of shortage
in many parts of the country; and that is why we are addressing the needs
particularly of the growth areas in the south-east to ensure that there is an
additional supply of housing; but that has to be a range of different housing
types and tenures and sizes to deal with people's needs, and it has to allow
flexibility. In my view it would be a
great mistake to say that the council should determine outcomes because,
frankly, we now know that about 70 per cent are currently living in
owner-occupation nationally, and the aspirations of about 80 per cent of the
public are to be owner-occupiers. It
would be quite wrong to say the whole housing process should be driven by local
authority housing, which will represent only 15-20 per cent of the total broadly
nationally. I know in some areas it
will be different. That is why a
strategic view of overall housing need, recognising the different roles that
different providers can play, and ensuring that there is a wider choice for
people between different types of housing and different tenures, must be part
of the pattern in the future.
Q508 Mr Hopkins: This very year, because of the increase in
house prices, we have had the lowest level of first-time buyers for
generations, because they cannot afford to get into owner-occupation. They need decent homes to live in. The private market cannot provide it. Private renting is expensive and may not be
appropriate. Is it not really the case
that some day government has to think about providing decent homes, perhaps with
a national housing initiative, rather than a local initiative, for those for
whom owner-occupation and decent housing cannot be provided in any other way?
Mr Raynsford: I agree with you that government has responsibility to ensure that
the framework is in place for the supply of an appropriate range of housing,
but I do not believe that it is right that government should be providing all
this, or local government. We live in a
pluralist society. The private sector
provides for about 75 per cent of people's housing needs and will continue to
play a major role. It would be
delusional to pretend that is not part of the scene, so we need to work with
the private sector on mixed developments to ensure that there are opportunities
for low-cost home ownership; and as far as your illustrations of key-workers
and others wanting to buy and not being able to do so because of adverse market
circumstances, that is precisely why we are developing our new schemes for
low-cost home ownership options and key-worker housing.
The Committee suspended
from 3.29 pm to 3.42 pm for a Division in the House of Commons
Chairman: Apologies to everyone for
the interruption. We shall move into
the last period of our session. I think
we had reached a natural break point when we stopped. I think we had completed your answer. Let me bring in David Heyes to continue the questioning.
Q509 Mr Heyes: Can I ask you about housing stock
transfer. You knew you were going to
get that at some point. Is it right
that the present cohorted tenant should be making decisions about the future of
large tranches of public housing in the way that has been happening all over
the country?
Mr Raynsford: It is right that tenants should have a degree
of choice about their future, and it is difficult to see how you can avoid, if
you are giving people a choice, having consequences in the longer term; because
if their choice is to vote for a stock transfer, then that transfer takes place
and that is the new reality. The
important thing is that tenants should have an opportunity to assess the
implications to reach a decision and, above all, that we should be operating in
a more pluralist framework than in the past when the number of choices was very
limited indeed and we essentially had a single monolithic local authority
dominated public sector and owner occupation was the only alternative. What we are moving towards is a much more
pluralist framework where we have not just outright owner occupation but
opportunities for low‑cost home ownership and where the rented sector is
made up of a range of different bodies, including registered social landlords,
local authority directly run properties, local authorities operating through
arms' length management organisations (ALMOs) and tenant cooperatives, which,
sadly, never really expanded in the way that I know a number of us would have
hoped, but they still play a significant role in some areas.
Q510 Mr Heyes: We had evidence from a housing director from
Newham. My question really is why give
the present cohorted tenants that crucial decision about where this large stock
of publicly owned housing goes, how it should be owned and run, how it should
be managed in the future? If that is
government policy, if that is what the decision is, why not just do it? Why not make the decision and announce it?
Mr Raynsford: Of course, in the past there was no
choice. The previous cohorts were
simply told, "You either stay in slum housing or you move into council
housing." Those were the options. I think it is much better that there is
degree of choice.
Q511 Mr Heyes: Except we are in a different age. People's housing needs have changed,
expectations have changed. We are in a
different world.
Mr Raynsford: I agree, and that is why I believe that
people should have a choice, but it is difficult, going back to your first
question, to see how that choice can be exercised without having long‑term
consequences. If the property does
transfer, then there is a new landlord and you cannot simply unscramble that
because the next generation wants to take a different view.
Q512 Mr Heyes: Forgive me, that does not really address my
point. Why give that choice to the
people who currently happen to occupy that block of public sector housing if
the Government decide that public policy is that it should no longer be managed
to run in that way? Why give the
decision away to the people who currently live there? As you said yourself, there should be much more flexibility in the
housing market. People can move in and
out of the rented sector, in and out of the unoccupied sector?
Mr Raynsford: The Government policy is to give greater
choice, and that is exactly why we are doing this, and, as part of that, what
we are doing is helping to develop a more pluralist framework where in future
there will be a greater range and variety of providers. I think that will help to drive up
standards, and I think it will satisfy the aspirations of the public to have a
greater choice about tenures available to them.
Q513 Mr Heyes: The pluralist framework that excludes local authority
ownership?
Mr Raynsford: Do remember that there has been a very
significant transfer from local authority ownership into owner occupation over
the last 20 years as a result of the right to buy. That has had one very beneficial effect in
terms of creating more diverse estates instead of single tenure estates. You now have owner occupiers living side by
side the tenants. It has had a
disadvantageous impact in that throughout the lifetime of the previous
Government local authorities were not free to reinvest the proceeds in the
provision of new housing. As I said
earlier in response to Kelvin's question, we do recognise the need for more
housing, but we want that to be provided in a more pluralist way rather than
the creation of single tenure estates in the future.
Q514 Mr Heyes: The people at Birmingham that we spoke to,
the housing professionals, but, more particularly and more relevantly, the
representatives of the tenants, felt that they had been denied a real choice in
that they had made their decision through a popular ballot and overwhelmingly
their preference was not to go for any of the new directions for managing
public sector stock but to stay with the local authority. If a single reason came out of that from
them, and we pressed them for their thinking on it, it was about trust, trust
in the way that the local authority had done it, and they understood arguments
about less available resources as a result of that choice, but they said
nonetheless, "We want to stay with the local authority. We trust them." They also went on to say, "We now feel we are being denied the
ability to carry through that decision that we made through our collective
popular choice."
Mr Raynsford: Bearing mind it is one of the largest local
authority housing stocks in the country, if not the largest, inevitably you
will have a greater variety of opinion within that number of tenants. My understanding is that the current
approach in Birmingham, which is very consistent with its local authority
policy to devolve power to 11 area committees, is to work with the tenants'
groups in the different areas exploring the best options for improving the
standard of homes in those areas. That,
I suspect, may well lead to a more diverse outcome in that there may be support
for stock transfer in some parts of Birmingham, but not others, and, if I think
by back to my own area, there has been a stock transfer of approximately 1,300
properties in one part of Greenwich, and the tenants are generally very
satisfied with that - it has led to a considerable improvement in the physical
conditions - but the vast majority of 25,000 or so other properties in the
local authority's ownership remain in council ownership. That kind of more pluralist pattern, I
suspect, we may see more of in the future.
Q515 Mr Prentice: Why do you not just be up
front about it and say the Government really wants to remove council house
ownership completely?
Mr Raynsford: We do not.
We believe very strongly in a pluralist framework in which the public
has a choice between a range of providers, local authorities are no longer the
monopoly providers of housing; because I think there are problems with that
monopoly position. We can explore that
if you would like, but you as well as I have had experience of some of the
practical difficulties of insensitive management in the past from local
authority monopoly landlords who did not face any challenge. I think there are clear benefits in that,
and there are also advantages in that a more diverse framework allows us not
just to invest in local authority stock but to lever in additional private
finance through RSLs which make it easier for us to meet our Decent Homes
Standard.
Q516 Mr Prentice: I understand that, but
people would say (and forgive me for using the cliché) that there is not a
level playing field here. We had people
from Defend Council Housing and we spoke to people up in Birmingham who told us
that everything is stacked against those tenants who want to stay with the local
authority in terms of funding, and so on; but you would reject that, would you
not?
Mr Raynsford: I would indeed. I think that the ALMO initiative has been an extraordinarily
successful one which has provided a framework under which a lot of extra
finance has gone into local authority housing with a clear incentive to improve
standards, and that, we think, is important. It remains in local authority
ownership and the tenant's satisfaction ratings are substantially higher. It is a real success story.
Q517 Mr Prentice: What happened to the fourth
option? The Deputy Prime Minister, I
think, mentioned the fourth option at the Labour Party Conference last year and
the largest affiliate to the Labour Party, Unison, has sent out briefing
materials saying, "What has happened to the fourth option?" The fourth option is allowing local
authorities the capital (the finance) to invest in their own housing
stock. What happened to the fourth
option?
Mr Raynsford: There never was a fourth option. Of course, when you describe it in those
terms, it highlights why there is not: because local authorities are public
bodies and it is simply not possible for public bodies to have free access to
private borrowing without that affecting the public sector borrowing
requirement. That is why we have always
said that there must be controls over public levels of borrowing. We have relaxed them with the prudential
regime - there is no question about that - though we have kept some safeguards
in relation to the national finances.
We cannot simply allow unlimited borrowing by local authorities. We therefore provided a framework whereby
authorities that meet the performance standards can secure additional funding
for an ALMO, which enables the property to remain within local authority
ownership but with a more focused management to deliver the higher standards
that we want to see. Those authorities
that want to remain purely traditional landlords in the old style are free to
do so. They have to work within the
existing framework of finance for local government. Those who opt for a stock transfer, the housing association will
be able to lever in additional private finance, and that will probably mean
that they can achieve a faster rate of improvement of the housing stock. There are differences ‑ I accept
that entirely ‑ but it is not the case in any way that the playing
field is stacked against local authorities.
Q518 Mr Prentice: Except we get evidence from
all sorts of people who say that over the years the Treasury has creamed off
money, the rents paid by tenants, and if there was any equity then that money
which has been creamed off by the Treasury over the years would go back into
improving local authority housing stock.
We got that from Defend Council Housing and their allies.
Mr Raynsford: Defend Council Housing have a parti pris, as you know. They do not always have a thorough grasp on
economics, I have to say, but I can tell you that the Treasury has been very
supportive of our initiatives to invest additional funding, substantial additional
funding, in the improvement of the council housing stock. A million council homes have been brought up
already to the Decent Homes Standard.
That has been a transformation of conditions for a very large number of
council tenants. We have the target,
obviously, to extend this throughout the remaining million. There is substantial investment going into
council housing from the Treasury. If I
can pursue this level playing field a little further, when I talk to tenants I
hear different arguments. I hear the
argument that housing association rents are too high and they have not been
given enough subsidy to keep their rent levels down in line with council rent
levels. Whichever side of the field you
are on it always looks a bit greener on the other side.
Q519 Mr Prentice: I understand that. The way to resolve these issues typically is
to have a vote. The issues crystalise,
people think about the issues and they vote and that lays the matter to rest. The tenants in Birmingham had a vote in
2002, and I think they voted 75 per cent to 25 per cent, or something
like that, to stay with the council.
Now you are telling us ‑ and we heard this when we were up in
Birmingham ‑ that there are new formulations emerging, that perhaps
part of the council's housing stock could transfer and other parts could
not. No matter how hard they try, if
they make a decision, the Government is going to be snapping at their heels
saying, "Think again." That is the
reality?
Mr Raynsford: If I can take your figures, and I have not
been Housing Minister since 2001 so I do not have the figures immediately to
hand, but I do have some understanding of the subject.
Q520 Mr Prentice: I know you do.
Mr Raynsford: If I take your figures, a city the size of
Birmingham with a huge population, the
largest housing stock in the country, if 25 per cent of tenants voted
in favour of transfer is it wrong that there should be an option whereby a
proportion of the housing stock should transfer? That is all that has been explored at the moment.
Mr Prentice: That is in an interesting concept, is it
not?
Chairman: Proportional representation!
Q521 Mr Prentice: Yes. The other interesting thing that we found
when we were talking to Birmingham tenants was that, even though they had
rejected housing stock transfer, they were more involved than ever before in
determining housing policy. They had a
say in the cleaning contracts that were awarded and they had a say even in
matters like appointing staff. Is it
not possible to improve public services, in this case council housing, rather
than go down the institutional road, housing associations? Why do we not just open it up and empower
(to use the jargon) tenants to take control and change council housing?
Mr Raynsford: Absolutely.
We very strongly supported that and we are going on supporting
that. There are lots of examples,
particularly the neighbourhood renewal areas that we strongly support and
finance, where tenants are actively involved in the housing management, where
there is considerable evidence of improvement.
It is not just in neighbourhood renewal areas, but those are ones which
we particularly keep a watch on because they are funded directly by our
department. We see it there, we
encourage it elsewhere, but I have to say, if you take my initial overall
analysis that you will tend to have a better outcome in a pluralist framework
where there are a range of providers, there is nothing wrong in having a
mixture of initiatives designed like the ones you have described, the bottom up
approaches, tenant participation to drive up standards, but also the option of
a transfer if people want that.
Q522 Mr Prentice: I understand that. There is a problem in politics, is there
not, that very often people make impossible demands?
Mr Raynsford: Yes.
Q523 Mr Prentice: We, the politicians, have
got to find clever ways of telling them that what they want is
unachievable. In answer to Kelvin, I
think, talking about choice‑based lettings, I jotted down when you were
speaking in your introductory remarks that one of the advantages of this is
that people would understand the constraints.
Is that not very useful from the Government's point of view if you
construct systems where people understand the constraints, learn the
constraints and do not make these demands?
Forget about this public sector borrowing requirement, for God's
sake. Let us put more money directly
into council housing.
Mr Raynsford: We have put a very substantial additional
amount of money into council housing - it is hugely increased - but, to come
down to your point, what we are trying to do is to give people more choice, and
choice does mean looking realistically at the options and deciding which are
the best. If someone is thinking of
buying a house, they cannot go and seek to buy a property which they have no
means of paying for. That is a
constraint they have to be aware of. In
the case of council housing, because the rent profiles on the whole do not
differentiate very much between the most attractive and the least attractive
stock, that kind of constraint is not there to the same degree. It is often the case that people do hold out
for the most attractive properties, understandably. If they are not aware of the implications of that, they may well
stay on the waiting list for a long period of time hoping that they are going
to get their most desirable property and not take a second‑best option
which might be available much more quickly to them. This is not about depressing expectations, it is about telling
people realistically what the prospects are.
The other huge advantage, and it is a huge advantage, is that under the
old system, the old allocation framework, people were very reluctant to take
less desirable properties - you must have come across this frequently - because
people feared that, once they had gone into it and accepted it, they would be
stuck there for life because of the rigidities in the letting system - unless
they could prove exceptional needs, they would be condemned to live there for
ever, so they would not accept a slightly sub‑optimal option - whereas if
there was a choice‑based system and people can accept, even temporarily,
knowing that they have then got the option of looking for somewhere else, they
are much more likely to do so. You can
cynically say this is depressing expectations. I do not think it is that at
all. I think it is helping people to
make realistic choices and giving them a greater opportunity to get something
that more satisfies their needs.
Q524 Mr Prentice: I understand all that. We have touched on the experience in Newham
a number of times, and when the Director of Housing came before us he told us
(and Tony referred to this earlier) that in the popular areas of Newham the
waiting time can be eight or nine years.
Who are the people who opt for the most popular areas if they have to
wait eight or nine years?
Mr Raynsford: That may well be one of the consequences of
the past, that people still hanker after some of the most popular properties
even though the chance of them getting it is going to be terribly limited. What I can say to you in response is the
more you widen up options and choice, the more it is known to people, to
tenants in Newham, that if they opt for either a slightly less popular area of
Newham or if they have the option or looking beyond Newham, to Waltham Forest
or possibly even outside London where there might be much shorter waiting
times, they can meet their housing needs far more quickly and as a result be a
happier tenant.
Q525 Mr Prentice: Why does not the Government
just roll this out nationwide?
Mr Raynsford: We are.
Q526 Mr Prentice: Bringing legislation so that
all local authorities, where the stock is not transferred, will be obliged to
adopt this choice‑based letting scheme?
Mr Raynsford: We have a programme to extend choice‑based
lettings across the country.
Q527 Mr Prentice: This is not a housing
committee, so I can confess ignorance.
Mr Raynsford: There is a programme to extend choice‑based
lettings across the country by 2010, but not just for local authorities,
because it should embrace registered social landlords and, if possible, in
certain circumstances, the private sector as well, because that is just
extending options and making it possible for people to weigh up different
choices.
Q528 Mr Prentice: This will apply to all local
authorities?
Mr Raynsford: Our policy is to extend choice‑based
lettings across the country, yes.
Q529 Mr Hopkins: I cannot get away from the thought that you
really are saying we are managing down expectations.
Mr Raynsford: No, we are not.
Q530 Mr Hopkins: That is the impression I have. I say this, because in the 1970s, compared
with now, in my own local authority we had a transfer list, as we do now, but
in those days it was easy to transfer because we were building new houses all
the time. You talked about the most
attractive properties. If there was a
demand for extra nice houses with gardens, we built nice houses with
gardens. We built hundreds of them
every year, with a nice Labour Government being very supportive, and it
worked. Thousands of people were
rehoused, the waiting list came right down and there was not a problem;
everybody cheered?
Mr Raynsford: My recollection of the 1970s is very
different. I was working for a shelter
agency in the 1970s and there were acute problems, serious problems, so much so
that we had to press for legislation to ensure greater protection for homeless
people and there were serious problems of housing shortage. Therefore I do not accept that rosy view of
life in the seventies. I will say,
however, that we are not about depressing expectations at all; we are about
widening choices and options, but we are also about making it practicable for
people to assess the different options available to them. Going back to the point I made in response to
one of Gordon's questions, if people are nervous about accepting second‑best
because they think they may be trapped there for life, they will hold out for
something that is every desirable, even though it may be a long time before
they will get there, simply because the number of very desirable properties are
limited in whatever framework you have.
Chairman: Before we are all tempted to
give our recollection of the 1970s, are we going to move on to something else?
Mr Prentice: I hope so?
Chairman: Let us move on briefly to
something else.
Mr Hopkins: I have laboured the
point.
Chairman: We have had a good go at it,
and, as Gordon reminded us, we are not the ODPM Committee, or, indeed, the
education committee, so we can feign innocence on all fronts.
Mr Prentice: I am
interested in what should happen to those under‑performing corners of the
public sector in this new era of greater choice. I was reading Alan Milburn's
speech, Power to the People (December 8), and he talks about
greater choice and he talks about the Government's reforms to extend choice
should be driven forward in education and housing as well as hospitals and
surgeries. We had John Hutton in front
of us, was it last week, and he had the look of a true believer. He told us that if there were under‑performing
areas of the National Health Service, and he cited a dermatology department,
and no‑one was going to this dermatology department, it would be closed
down and it would be like putting 20,000 volts through the National Health
Service and all the dermatologists out there would freak out and improve their
game.
Chairman: Gordon is now
paraphrasing. I have read the
transcript and I think it was you that used the words "freak out" and not
John! Anyway, you have the gist of it.
Q531 Mr Prentice: Take the case of
schools. If a school is under‑performing
in this brave new world, should it be closed down?
Mr Twigg: Possibly, and we have closed schools and local authorities have
closed schools. I think school closure
is the ultimate threat. It is the
ultimate lever. It is clearly not ideal
to close down a school unless it is for reasons of falling rolls. What we want to do is to see schools improve
rather than be closed down. For
example, we are trying all sorts of different methods where schools cluster
together, form federations. I gave an
example earlier in the discussion about lotteries of a new academy in Lewisham
that is combining Haberdashers, which is a city technology college, with
Mallory, which was seen as a struggling local school. One option might have been to close Mallory down. That would not have worked in terms of the
demography of the local area - the need for school places - so instead a new
school combining the two schools is being created, and there is a very strong
sense of optimism locally about what that can achieve. So, yes, we can close schools, yes, we do
close schools. Some of the academies
are new schools that are built in place of existing schools that have closed
down, but that is our ultimate weapon.
We have lots other levers we can use to bring about the school
improvement that we want to see.
Q532 Mr Prentice: What about in housing?
Mr Raynsford: It is not the case of closing down a failing
housing department, it is a question of taking action to improve that
department, but it is right, in our view, that tenants should have the option
of transferring to another landlord if they believe that this would deliver
them a better service, and that is why the stock transfer programme provides
that option. Interestingly, in the
course of the last 12 months there have been 17 ballots on stock transfer. One has voted, "No", but 16 have voted,
"Yes", and that is an indication that that is quite a powerful route available
for tenants who are not satisfied with the performance of their local authority
landlord.
Mr Twigg: I answered your question,
Gordon, in term of schools. Of course,
in terms over local education authorities, we did take powers to intervene
where things were breaking down, and I could cite a number of very
positive examples, notably here in London, where education authorities were
failing, intervention has contributed to the success of schools in those areas
to the point in which, in fact, the LEA is able to be restored, and that has
happened already in a couple of places.
Q533 Mr Prentice: I am wondering the extent to
which the choice agenda is just being imposed by the Government rather than any
great demand bubbling up from down below demanding greater choice. Sticking with schools for a second, I wonder
how many people out there were clamouring for more specialist schools. I wonder how schools decided on the
specialisms. We visited a dance and
drama school up in Birmingham. Were the
parents clamouring for a dance and drama specialist school? Is this something that was decided by the
education professionals?
Mr Twigg: It certainly is not something that is just decided by the
education professionals, and it must not be.
The Specialist Schools Programme is a very interesting programme in terms
of school improvement, because it has gone from being something introduced by
the previous government aimed at a small number of schools, in a sense arguably
quite an elitist programme, to one we have taken over and have taken in a
different direction, so that now we are saying every secondary school that
wants to should have the opportunity to be a specialist school. That means there can be an element of local
community planning between schools, involving parents as well as education
professionals, so you have a mix of specialisms in an area that can benefit the
system as a whole.
Q534 Mr Prentice: Has there been a single case
where parents have been balloted on the nature of the specialism?
Mr Twigg: I am not aware of that, but certainly schools will have very
detailed discussions within their school governing body about which specialism
to go for, and parents are typically very well represented on school governing
bodies. I am a governor myself of a
school in my constituency. I remember
when we decided to go for science and there was a real engagement; it was not
just the head deciding or even the LEA or DfES deciding.
Q535 Mr Prentice: Given what Alan has said
about "Power to the People", is this something that should rest with parents
and not the school governing body? It
is a big thing, is it not, if the local school is a language school or a sports
academy or dance and drama, engineering, business, whatever they are. Why as part of the choice agenda has the
Government not said this is something that it would be quite proper to consult
parents on?
Mr Twigg: Philosophically I have no disagreement with what you have
suggested at all, and I would have to look into the history of the programme
and how it was decided to do it in the particular way that we did, and possibly
a helpful note is coming. Parents are,
of course, the largest group on school governing bodies. I think you would need to look at the
practicalities of ways in which different people can be engaged. You have rightly referred to parents. The others, of course, are the pupils themselves. I think finding ways in which pupils,
students, can be more engaged in some of these discussions within our schools
is something we have started to do but where I feel we need to do a great deal
more, and, in particular, with the announcements that we will be making in the
next few weeks about reform of 14‑19 education, a key element of that is
about choice, but it is about choice of programmes, not necessarily choice of
institutions. I made this point briefly
at the beginning. In education, yes, it
is about choosing at different stages which school or college you go to, but it
is crucially also having more choice about what you study, where you study it
and how it is studied, and I think that is vital if we are going to have more
young people staying in education beyond the age of 16, 17.
Mr Raynsford: I was going say, there is a wider slightly
more philosophical point about the extension of choice, why we are supportive
of it, because it does help to concentrate the focus on the user rather than
the provider of the service. One of the
traditional weaknesses in public services in the UK has been a very provider
perspective which sometimes has been resistant to changes, but will meet
people's needs more effectively.
Whether it is the kind of example you gave of tenants' associations and
other initiatives in which tenants themselves can have more of an influence
over the control of services through existing providers, or whether it is
through the kind of initiative that allows people to have a vote on whether or
not they want to stay with one provider or move to another, that does help to
give a greater focus on the user, and I think that is a good thing.
Q536 Mr Prentice: The consumer is King or
Queen?
Mr Raynsford: Not always.
There are always constraints. We
talked about some of those in relation to equity earlier in the discussion, but
we have veered too much in the past towards, I think, the producer/provider
interest rather than the user interest, and I think there is a need to adjust
the balance there.
Q537 Chairman: Just as we end, and we are in the last two or
three minutes, in the two areas that you are responsible for we have mentioned
some instances where these mechanisms work. Can you tell us in a nutshell,
either on the choice side or the voice side, are there new initiatives in the
pipeline? Are there new, I was going to
say wheezes, but that is not the right word to use. Are there any new initiatives coming along to take forward the
choice or the voice agenda either in education or the local government field?
Mr Raynsford: If I can quickly say in relation to local
government, I am not at liberty to say it now because the document will not be
published until next week, but as part of our consultation on the future of
local government we will be putting out a paper on neighbourhood engagement
which will say a great deal about the voice side of this, about how people can
more effectively engage with local government and other institutions through
their local neighbourhood. So, yes, we are
addressing this energetically and we are looking very much at the voice side as
well as the choice. On the choice side,
one aspect we have not touched on, which we attach huge importance to, is how
people access public services. The idea
that you have got to go a council office between nine o'clock and
five o'clock in order to get a response or telephone within those hours is
simply a reflection of past patterns.
If I get home at ten o'clock at night (or eleven o'clock at night after
our vote last night) on a Tuesday evening and find that my dustbin has not been
emptied, I ought to be able to contact the council at that point in time by
internet, or whatever, to leave a message so that it can be dealt with, rather
than having to wait until the following morning to ring up and say, "My dustbin
was not emptied." It is this kind of
wider choice of access which is just as important in terms of improving users'
experience of public service.
Mr Twigg: I think in education we have two big things coming up in the next
month or so. One I have referred to a
couple of times in this afternoon session: the 14‑19 proposals in
response to the Tomlinson Report. I
think that has huge relevance both to the choices that are available through
that crucial phase of education but also to how we can give a bigger voice to
young people in their communities and in their education. Secondly, we are publishing a Green Paper on
youth that is about some of the issues to do with advice and guidance for young
people, which informs the choices they make but is also about the kind of
facilities that are available, places for young people to go, I think giving a
voice to young people about what goes on in communities is an important
challenge that goes way beyond DfES. It
is about the whole of government and Parliament.
Q538 Chairman: Can I ask you, by the way, what happened to
the bit of the bill that we passed in 1998 (The Schools Standards and
Frameworks Act) that was going to put a requirement on all governing bodies to
set up a standard complaints system for schools? Having announced it, we then dropped it and said it was going to
be introduced later on. I ask only
because, taking up Nick's point about the standard you should have in relation
to public services, and it has become standard to think there ought to be a
complaint system for users of public services, there is not one for schools,
as it happens.
Mr Twigg: I am told it has been in force since 2003.
Q539 Chairman: It is in force. There we are. That is the
answer to the question?
Mr Twigg: I have learned something today as well as the committee.
Q540 Chairman: One general final question. As I say, we are at the end of our inquiry
now. The evidence that we have had from
government, and it came out very strongly, I think, in John Hutton's evidence
to us last week, touched on this question of whether we are to talk about voice
and choice together as part of a common strategy for empowering people more in
relation to public services or whether there is really some conflict between
these approaches. We thought that these
things were going to be complementary, but the Government's evidence to us is
pretty dismissive about voice. It talks
about it being a clumsy instrument and goes on to tell us about all the
difficulties with it and is only really interested in talking about the choice
agenda. John Hutton was really
conceding this last week when we asked him about putting members of patient
groups on to the boards of foundation hospitals. He indicated this was kind of yesterday's agenda; we had now
moved on to the heavy high ground of choice.
I wonder really whether you think there is some kind of battle for the
soul of the Government going on here between individual choice mechanisms or instruments
of collective empowerment, whether those things are genuinely complementary in
the areas you know about?
Mr Raynsford: I think they are genuinely complementary, but
there are potential conflicts between them, because there are occasions where
an overall vote can result in a majority taking a view which is quite radically
different to the aspirations of a significant minority within that area. We all know about this problem in relation
to democracy, and there will always be questions about whether you allow
minority groups a greater discretion and scope to pursue their aspirations or
whether you constrain them as a result of a majority decision. It is not the case that the two are always
perfectly complementary, but I am, as I hope I have made clear from the
evidence, quite convinced that there is a role for both choice and voice in
driving up standards of public service and that we need to progress on both
fronts while recognising that there will be times when they may come into
conflict with each other.
Mr Twigg: I absolutely agree with that.
I was certainly very keen in the additional evidence that we provided
from the Department that we gave you good examples of choice mechanisms,
because I think they are vital, but, equally, we were able to provide some
strong examples of some of the voice mechanisms as well, including the one we
have just found out about but also to do with governing bodies, pupil
participation. I think there can be
conflicts between the two - there are times when choice is more effective than
voice - but I certainly believe that voice is important and by and largely
complementary to choice.
Q541 Chairman: Thank you for that. The great advantage of having you along is to give a concrete
feel to some of these general issues that we are grappling with. You have done that admirably. I am sorry for asking you questions outside
our territory, but it is important to our thinking. Thank you very much.
Mr Twigg: Thank you.