Select Committee on Transport Written Evidence


Memorandum by Dr David Metz (RP 23)

ROAD PRICING

  This memorandum is concerned with the possibility of moving to national road pricing in the longer term, in particular issues of equity and acceptability.

THE LOW INCOME MOTORIST

  Many car users have relatively modest incomes. The extra cost of road user charges could be substantial in relation to overall household income. Some low income travellers, excluded from using the roads by the charge, might be able to take advantage of improved public transport, financed from the congestion charge revenue. However, the extent to which this would be helpful would depend on the extent to which public transport could substitute for the car-based trips no longer affordable. This substitution would generally be most effective on routes serving city centres where congestion charging had been adopted, but less effective on suburban and extra-urban routes. Thus road pricing, as usually envisaged, may prove more acceptable in city centres than in other locations. Beyond city centres, the option of not owning a car may be incompatible with the spatial pattern of work and residence into which household members may be locked.

  The scale of the problem of the low income motorist is indicated in the Figure which shows Office for National Statistics data for average weekly household expenditure on vehicle purchase and the operation of personal transport for 2002-03 by household income decile. Not all households own cars, of course, and the "adjusted" data show expenditure divided by the proportion of households in the decile that own at least one car or van, to give an estimate of motoring expenditure by car-owning households. It will be seen that motoring expenditure for households with cars falls in the range £30-£50 per week for the lower half of the income distribution. This expenditure may be compared with current road charges in Britain: £25 for weekly entry into the London congestion charging zone and £30 for the weekly use (five days) in both directions of the M6 toll road. Arguably, most motorists in the lowest half of the income distribution are likely to experience difficulty in affording charges of this magnitude, even if there were to be partial relief of vehicle excise duty. (More offsetting relief could be provided by reducing fuel duty but this would run counter to policies aimed at reducing carbon dioxide emissions.)

  London congestion charging does not seem to have been a problem for low income motorists because of the extensive availability of public transport. Nor has the M6 toll road proved problematical since the untolled M6 can be used by those unwilling to pay. However, neither extensive public transport nor untolled options would accompany generalised road pricing. This suggests that problems of equity and political acceptability may hinder the implementation of any scheme for generalised congestion charging.

DISCRIMINATORY PRICING

  One possible answer to the problem of the low income motorist is suggested by the charging system, based on "yield management", used by budget airlines. The typical mode of seat booking for a budget airline is that seat prices are lowest the further ahead the reservation is made, prices always rise with time and are not discounted at the last minute. Thus the matching of demand for seats to their supply is managed through a dynamic pricing structure, the operation of which is evidently acceptable to travellers.

  The pricing system for inter-urban rail travel also typically incorporates substantial discounts related to the early booking of precise and inflexible journeys. Both the rail tariff structure and the budget airlines' arrangements amount to "discriminatory pricing" whereby high income travellers are induced to pay more than a market clearing price, while low income travellers are permitted to pay less. Discriminatory pricing maximises revenues to the operator (and minimises average seat prices for a given return on investment) if the last available seat is filled by the last passenger willing to pay the highest quoted price. Discriminatory pricing of this kind does not require means testing of travellers. Rather, it takes advantage of the willingness of travellers to trade off the inconvenience of early commitment and inflexibility for a price discount, a trade off whose appeal decreases as disposable income increases.

  Discriminatory pricing on the road system would have attractions as a means for matching demand to capacity more precisely than would be possible with a single price for any particular vehicle class at a given time of day in a particular location—the conventional approach to road pricing. This would be especially the case if it were feasible to adopt dynamic pricing (as opposed to a preset tariff) for those not electing to pay in advance of the day of travel.

  Moreover, discriminatory road pricing would be a means to reconcile a charging mechanism aimed at regulating demand with the social objective of avoiding exclusion of low income motorists from access to employment, shops and other facilities. Discriminatory pricing, along the lines adopted by the railways and budget airlines, would have attractions as the basis of road pricing since it would allow low income motorists whose car use is unavoidable, for instance for their journey to work, to take advantage of discounts for early reservation or "season ticket" type prepayment. Given that less than 20% of all road trips are for the purposes of travelling to work, it should be feasible to arrange for low income motorists to be substantially less disadvantaged by road pricing than would be the case be with conventional charging arrangements.

FIGURE

  UK average weekly household expenditure on vehicle purchase and the operation of personal transport ("motoring expenditure") by household income decile (2002-03 data from Office for National Statistics, Family Spending—a report on the 2002-03 Expenditure and Food Survey, (2004). "Motoring expenditure adjusted" shows expenditure by households owning at least one car.

Dr David Metz

formerly Chief Scientist, Department of Transport (1992-97)

November 2004


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 2 August 2005