Select Committee on Transport Written Evidence


Memorandum by PACTS (RP 28)

ROAD PRICING

  1.  The Parliamentary Advisory Council for Transport Safety (PACTS) welcomes the opportunity to respond to this inquiry. PACTS is an associate parliamentary group and registered charity advising and informing Members of Parliament on road, rail and air safety issues. It brings together technical expertise from the public, private, academic and professional sectors to promote research-based solutions to transport safety problems. Its charitable objective is to promote transport safety legislation to protect human life. This memorandum will therefore consider the safety implications of road pricing, particularly relating to the first three of the Committee's questions:

    —  Should road pricing be introduced for certain sections of the road network in the short term?

    —  If road pricing is introduced, what factors should determine which roads are priced and what technology should be used?

    —  How "hi-tech" does road pricing need to be?

  2.  Innovative schemes for road pricing, applied at a national level, have significant scope for reducing congestion and changing patterns of road use. While there may be positive road safety implications in the longer term if road pricing leads to a modal shift from motorised traffic to other transport modes that cause less risk, road pricing is not in itself a road safety proposal. Road pricing may also be of benefit in that it may allow the negative externalities of motoring (including safety, health and environmental implications) to be reflected by the costs of motoring in a far more direct and immediate fashion than at present. However, these two aims of roads pricing may lead to different practical considerations, and a balance between them may need to be struck. In short, the objective of road pricing must be determined before a scheme can be designed.

  3.  PACTS has no opposition to road pricing in principle, but it must be implemented in a manner that does not increase road risk, particularly to vulnerable road users. This will require careful consideration and appropriate modelling of all possible impacts of road user charging.

  4.  The relationship between congestion and crash risk is a complex one, and reducing congestion can have variable effects on casualty reduction. Although a connection between traffic growth and an increase in road casualties is often assumed, recent research commissioned by the Department for Transport found:

    Despite this presumption . . . is the reality of the situation was that, with the exception of motorway sites, accident rates during periods of recurrent congestion are lower than those in uncongested conditions. (Brownfield et al 2004: 5)

  The study found that while for motorway sites the accident rate in congested conditions was nearly twice the rate in uncongested conditions, in urban and "peri-urban" sites the accident rate in congested conditions was less than half the rate in uncongested conditions. Rate was calculated by road length rather than "per vehicle kilometre", which suggests that crash rates per vehicle are significantly lower in congested conditions, as traffic flows are higher in congested conditions. For vulnerable road users, congested conditions lower crash risk even further. Crash risk for cyclists and pedestrians are dramatically lower in congested conditions: in urban sites the accident rate for pedestrians in congested conditions was a quarter of the rate for uncongested conditions; this falls to a seventh in peri-urban sites (Brownfield et al 2004: 6).

  5. TRL modelling of motorway tolling has also indicated that motorway tolling could increase crashes due to the diversion of traffic from motorways (which tend to have good collision records) to alternative untolled roads (which may be less safe and less appropriate for high vehicle flows). A study based on motorways in Kent suggested that a toll of 2.5p per mile (at 1994 prices) would produce a 10% diversion level (Gower et al 1998). A linked study suggested that "a 10% diversion of motorway traffic from the motorways in Kent would increase the number of injury accidents in the entire county by about 3½%" (Broughton and Gower 1998: 7). The cost of these crashes represents 29% of the revenue that would be raised from the tolls, considerably undermining the tolls' effectiveness. If these conclusions were to apply nationally, it would be an extremely unwelcome result.

  6.  However, depending on the nature of the scheme, road user charging does not necessarily lead to an increase in casualties—as the experience of congestion charging in London has demonstrated. Casualties in the congestion charge zone fell at a quicker rate than elsewhere in London after the charge was introduced, and the sharp reductions in road casualties across London does not suggest that crashes have been displaced as drivers alter their routes (TfL 2004: 94). Further analysis into the long-term effects of congestion charging in London on road casualties would be welcome.

  7.  The potential negative safety implications of road pricing is recognised in the DfT Feasibility Study of Road Pricing in the UK, published in July 2004:

    The impact of re-routing, if it were to occur, could in certain places and at certain times result in an increase in accident levels. This is due to the increased number of vehicles using smaller roads, not built for a high level demand, which could lead to higher accident rates. However, a well-informed charging structure could minimise the incentives to re-route. (DfT 2004a: 143)

  This is an important consideration and needs to be integral to the design of road pricing schemes.

  8.  A "well-informed charging structure" would be one that seeks to take into account crash risk and associated costs as well as congestion and emissions. This could have positive benefits for road safety as drivers are encouraged to use safer routes. However, research suggests that a complex charging structure could inhibit the effectiveness of road pricing schemes. A recent report on pricing structures for road user charging concluded:

    The clarity of the pricing signal is fundamental to the success of congestion charging. The prime requirement is that the logic of the charge structure, and the necessity of a degree of complexity, is capable of being communicated and is seen to reflect the objectives of the scheme. The logic should be capable of being summed up in a relatively simple expression such as "Charges will be highest when and where traffic is expected to be busiest". (Bonsall et al 2004: iv-v).

  Introducing variables beyond congestion, such as road risk and environmental considerations, could lead to pricing structures that are nearly impossible for ordinary drivers to understand, and would therefore be ineffective in achieving behavioural shift.

  9.  The Feasibility Study of Road Pricing in the UK also raises the issue of a potentially negative form of modal shift:

    If motorcycles are exempted from road pricing they could become more popular, which would have implications on road safety. This is because motorcyclists have been found to be eight times more likely than car drivers to be involved in an injury accident, over 20 times more likely to be injured themselves, and over 35 times more likely to be killed or seriously injured (DfT 2004a: 143).

  The study notes that in the London Congestion Charge scheme an increase in the number of motorcycles has not led to increases in casualties. However, this may not be representative: motorcycle speeds within London are likely to be significantly lower than outside the Capital, and in recent years an increase in motorcycling nationally has led to a sharp increase in motorcyclist deaths and serious injuries (DfT 2004b). PACTS therefore recommends that motorcycles should not be exempt from road pricing.

  10.  Speed and casualty severity is another important issue. The Feasibility Study of Road Pricing in the UK notes: "the improved free flow of traffic could also lead to an increase in the severity of accidents ie from shunts to fatalities" (DfT 2004a: 144). The study suggests that a proportion of revenue from road pricing could be devoted to speed management measures to mitigate against this effect. This is a welcome suggestion. It will also be important to integrate road pricing into existing speed and traffic management systems as a whole.

  11.  "Hi-tech" versions of road pricing could improve road safety through sharing a technology platform with Intelligent Speed Adaptation (ISA). Both road pricing and ISA have similar technological requirements: accurate vehicle location technology and digital maps containing local road information. As the Transport Committee has noted on a number of occasions, ISA has a major potential for reducing road casualties and could reduce fatal collisions by up to 59% (Transport Committee 2004; Transport, Local Government and the Regions Committee 2002). Further consideration into how road pricing could link to ISA and other innovations such as Norwich Union's pay-as-you-drive insurance would be desirable.

  12.  In conclusion, while road pricing may be welcomed in principle, significant attention will need to be given to the practicalities of road pricing scheme to ensure that there is no deleterious effect on road safety. Based on the findings of TRL research on motorway tolling, PACTS does not believe that road pricing should be introduced on trunk roads in the short term as an intermediate step to national road pricing. However, urban area-based schemes such as London's congestion charge may be more effective at introducing a form of road pricing without compromising safety. In the longer-term, consideration needs to be given to whether and how safety variables can be integrated within pricing structures and to whether any negative safety implications of road pricing can be mitigated through other measures. Integrating Intelligent Speed Adaptation with road pricing technologies may be one very positive method of achieving this.

REFERENCES AND FURTHER READING

Bonsall, P, Shires, J, Matthews, B, Maule, J and Beale, J 2004. Road User Charging—Pricing Structures. Final report for the Department for Transport on PPAD 09/159/002. The Institute for Transport Studies, University of Leeds: Leeds.

Broughton, J, and Gower, P 1998. The likely effects of motorway tolling on accident risk—phase 2. TRL Report TRL352. Transport Research Laboratory: Crowthorne, Berks.

Brownfield, J, Graham, A, Eveleigh, H, Ward, H, Robertson, S, and Allsop, R. 2003. Road Safety Research Report No 44: Congestion and accident risk. Department for Transport: London.

Gower, P, Shearn, S, and Mitchell, J. 1998. Motorway tolling: Modelling the impact of diversion. TRL Report TRL349. Transport Research Laboratory: Crowthorne, Berks.

Department for Transport. 2004a. Feasibility Study of Road Pricing in the UK. DfT: London.

Department for Transport. 2004b. Tomorrow's Roads-safer for everyone: The first three year review: The Government's road safety strategy and casualty reduction targets for 2010. DfT: London.

House of Commons Transport Committee. 2004. Cars of the Future. Seventeenth Report of Session 2003-4, Volume 1. HC 319-I. House of Commons/TSO: London.

House of Commons Transport, Local Government and the Regions Committee. 2002. Road Traffic Speed. Ninth Report of Session 2001-2, Volume 1. HC 557-I. House of Commons/TSO: London.

Transport for London. 2004. Congestion charging—Central London—Impacts Monitoring: Second Annual Report. TfL: London.

PACTS

November 2004





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 2 August 2005