Select Committee on Transport Written Evidence


Memorandum by FaberMaunsell (RP 35)

ROAD PRICING

INTRODUCTION

  FaberMaunsell is an international consultancy working at national, regional and local levels in the delivery of transportation solutions across the world.

  Since the passing of new legislation to allow local authorities to introduce road user charging schemes, FaberMaunsell has been at the forefront in providing advice to scheme providers and stakeholders.

  In recent major commissions FaberMaunsell has:

    —  Provided recommendations on the feasibility of road pricing strategies—including the ROCOL feasibility study that underpinned the central London congestion charging scheme.

    —  Provided advice to a private sector consortium bidding for the implementation of the Lorry Road User Charging scheme.

    —  Modelled and measured the traffic effects of the central London congestion charging scheme.

    —  Undertaken system engineering advice for the DfT's DIRECTS project.

    —  Used data derived from satellite tracked vehicles for monitoring the performance of transport networks.

    —  Provided advice to several local authorities on the practicality, effectiveness and acceptability of road pricing policies.

    —  Completed a major policy study for the Commission for Integrated Transport on "Paying for Road Use".

  The company is therefore well qualified to respond, from the perspective of experienced transportation planning professionals, to the road pricing questions posed by the select committee.

Question 1  Should road pricing be introduced for certain sections of the road network in the short term?

  The fundamental economic rationale for road pricing is that charges to the consumer should be designed in accordance with the principles of "fair and efficient" pricing.

  The efficiency argument is underpinned by long-established micro-economic theory indicating that road users should be charged for the additional costs that their use of the road network imposes-the "polluter pays" principle. Typical these marginal road use costs include congestion-related delay, accident costs, local environmental impacts (such as noise and air pollution) and global environmental impacts (climate change).

  Research by the University of Leeds has estimated that congestion-related impacts are by far the largest costs in terms of the overall contribution to external costs. Due to the effectiveness of policies for fuel efficiency and emissions, transports contribution to environmental pollution has been falling. However, the external costs of congestion have continued to grow.

  Therefore, it is logical that road use charges should be introduced for "certain sections" of the network; the "certain sections" being the parts of the network that suffer most from congestion.

  The biggest market failures with respect to current levels of congestion include:

    —  The centres of major combinations.

    —  The centres of major freestanding towns and cities.

    —  Certain parts of the motorway/trunk road system.

    —  Certain other strategic routes that feed traffic into major centres.

Should this market failure be tackled in the short term?

  The central London scheme has illustrated that road pricing policy can be effective in tackling congestion. Arguably other cities could readily follow this example, but the practicality of embarking upon such a strategy will depend upon a number of inter-related factors, including:

    —  the ability of an individual city, when acting alone, to withstand the economic impact (diversion of trade); and

    —  the ability of the local authority to capture sufficient net revenues (from charging) to provide resources for investment in alternatives to the use of private vehicles.

  One other factor is crucial to the consideration of the short-term application of road pricing policies. If a number of different schemes came into operation users could be faced with an immensely complex regime of transport charging. Take the example of a lorry distributing goods in London and Manchester. There could be a requirement to pay; the central London congestion charge, a charge for the use of congested sections of M1, a charge for M6 toll and a further charge for a congestion scheme in Manchester. This could represent a considerable administrative burden for both operators and private users.

  Hence, it appears crucial that any further short term roll out of road pricing should be backed by at least some degree of centralised system for key road pricing functions such as billing, payment, customer care and enforcement.

Question 2  If road pricing is introduced, what factors should determine which roads are priced and what technology should be used?

  A considerable amount of research has been completed over the past five years to address this question. See for example the CfIT report on "Paying for Road Use" and the Leeds University research in "The Economic Efficiency Case for Road User Charging".

  Essentially, there is a need to assess how well current revenues from transport balance against transport costs for each mode, geographic area and time period. The economic efficiency argument suggests that the transport system works optionally when revenues from transport match marginal social costs (congestion, environmental pollution, accidents).

  In this situation, users will adapt their travel behaviour in recognition of the total private plus external cost of motoring. In a heavily congested urban areas for example, prices should be set to reflect the extent of delay costs incurred at different times of day.

  The argument above points to a charging system that needs to be sensitive to:

    —  the relative efficiency of different modes of travel;

    —  the elements of the network subject to delay (or other external costs); and

    —  the time of day when congestion occurs.

  Arguably, the approach taken in central London, with a flat fee across a wide area within the Inner Ring Road, was defensible since severe congestion was widespread across this area during much of the day-time period.

  However, in other towns and cities and on other parts of the strategic road network, congestion effects may be considerably more variable in both space and time. This argues for a greater degree of sophistication in charging technology compared to the area-based system used in central London. Such technology already exists and is relatively commonplace in motorway tolling. However, urban areas would be highly sensitive to imposition of the current short-range communication systems used on motorways. The solution rests with the application of satellite and mobile communication technologies that avoid the use of extensive roadside infrastructure (see Question 3 response below).

Question 3  How hi-tech does road-pricing need to be?

  As noted above in response to Question 2, the big issue here is the necessary sophistication of technology to deliver the levels of sensitivity and locate specific types of vehicle (in both space and time) on congested sections of network.

  Our experience in using data from vehicles equipped with GPS in urban areas for both navigation and network monitoring shows that:

    —  this technology is accurate enough for area pricing—for a town centre for example;

    —  its data can be manipulated to overcome known errors; and

    —  handling such large volumes of data requires care.

  However, such data is not currently accurate enough to enforce pricing on a particular road section without reasonable doubt. There are significant variations in coverage and the lack of knowledge of accuracy at any point in time is an issue, Our work for the European Commission shows that the Galileo system could overcome many of these issues. The key here is to match the granularity of the pricing strategy with the accuracy that is available—100% coverage with 100% accuracy is not possible and a reasonably effective system could be put swiftly into place using existing technology, providing the requirement for positioning vehicles were relaxed to an area wide basis.

  A key issue here is complexity of operation. The charging system may be very high tech but the service provided, and its means of use by drivers, has to be very simple.

Question 4  What role should local highway authorities play in introducing road pricing?

  The local authority role is crucial to the deployment of practical, effective and acceptable local schemes. Whilst elements of a centralised national charging system, such as systems supporting common payment and billings procedures, may be fundamental to the wide roll out of road pricing, local highway authorities have a vital role in developing local transport policies that are "in tune" with local problems and specific socio-economic circumstances.

  It is highly unlikely that local road pricing schemes would emerge in isolation from wider local policy interventions. Local authorities will almost certainly view road pricing as part of a wide-ranging package of measures designed to reduce congestion, improve accessibility and foster more sustainable mobility. Typically a local authority would seek to make significant improvements (as was the case in London) to both the quality and quantity of the public transport services that provide the alternative to car use. To fail to embrace such a strategy exposes the responsible authority to charges of levying punitive taxes without offering suitable transport alternatives.

  Local authority input will also be crucial in developing local stakeholder consensus for transport strategies embracing road pricing. The Local Transport Plan process represents the key mechanism for consulting the local community on transport policy direction. For any local authority contemplating the use of road use charging powers, there will be a need to demonstrate, through the LTP process, that revenues from road pricing are allocated wisely to tackle the most urgent problems and priorities in the local area.

  The local highway authority also has an important role in developing practical road pricing solutions. A congestion-charging scheme could, for example, induce a range of transport impacts including:

    —  diversions away from the charged area;

    —  changes in timing of journeys;

    —  changes in mode of travel; and

    —  changes in travel destinations.

  All of these impacts need to be dealt with through sensitive local "tuning" of transport policy.

Question 5  How easy will it be to move from individual toll roads and local congestion charging schemes in the short term, to national road pricing in the longer term, and what needs to be done to ensure the transition is a success?

  This question is partly addressed in our response to Question 1.

  The first point to note is that charging for the use of individual toll roads arises from fundamentally different rationale to that of marginal social cost pricing (the "polluter pay"). The rationale for true toll roads is to deliver new transport infrastructure that cannot be funded through conventional public funding channels. Toll road schemes are normally built and run by the private sector for a concession period (typically 20 to 30 years) over which the costs of providing the new road are recovered through toll charges. Although most UK tolling schemes are restricted to major estuarial crossings, the recent opening of M6 Toll adds complexity to the roll out of a national road-pricing scheme. It would be possible, although probably very costly, to buy out the existing concessionaire. M6 Toll could then revert to a conventional motorway route. The alternative would be to retain M6 Toll but then exclude the tolled section from any national charging system, thus avoiding users being charged twice for the use of the same section of motorway. It could be argued that drivers should in fact be charged twice, once for an infrastructure charge and once for a national "efficiency" charge. However, this is likely to be unpalatable to a driver that has already chosen to pay a toll to avoid a congested route.

  The transition from local urban congestion charging schemes to national road pricing represents a more straightforward path in terms of the underlying economic rationale. However, the major challenge is inter-operability of potentially a range of different charging systems. The nightmare vision is the one in which a user is forced to engage with numerous individual systems with differing charging technologies and differing payment/billing systems. Setting aside the on-road charging technology for a moment, part of the solution lies in developing a national system for handling charge payments so that a user engages with one central point of contact. Such common payment systems already exist in other fields such as banking and telecoms, so the application to an easy to use and understand national road pricing system should not represent a major challenge.

  The more difficult challenge is that of the on road charging technology that is required to calculate distances travelled by vehicles and communicate charging details between vehicles and central payment systems. The DfT charging trial (DIRECTS) is seeking to address this issue by developing and testing a common specification for interoperable on road charging equipment. There is a wider European and International perspective here, as systems will not be developed solely for the UK and visiting vehicles will need to be charged.

Question 6  How will the Lorry Road User Charge fit into any national road pricing and motorway tolling developments?

  Response withheld pending guidance from HMCE concerning confidentiality.

Question 7  Are there other measures which could reduce congestion more effectively?

  As transportation planning professionals responsible for delivering transport solutions over the past 10-15 years we have been closely involved in the deployment of policies that have sought to tackle rising levels of traffic congestion.

  During the 1990's, transport policy shifted significantly away from road building to focus more on strategies designed to reduce dependence on private vehicle use. Typically local policies included a mix of:

    —  Parking strategies designed to discourage long stay commuters.

    —  Pedestrianisation of sensitive central areas.

    —  Bus priority measures.

    —  Application of urban traffic control techniques.

    —  Improved facilities for walking and cycling.

    —  Travel planning strategies.

    —  Planning controls to restrict parking levels.

  Despite this roll out of such measures, we reached the turn of the century facing ever-growing congestion pressures. In particular:

    —  person car vehicle-kilometres increased by 40 billion between 1989 and 1999;

    —  ownership of two or more cars has risen from one in six households in 1985-86 to one in four households in 1997-99;

    —  education-related car journeys increased threefold over the past 20 years;

    —  the distance travelled by the average car has increased by over 40% since the mid 1980's;

    —  cycle use declined by over 35% since the mid-1980's;

    —  walking trips have reduced by 20% since the mid-1980's; and

    —  outside London, local bus patronage in England has consistently declined during the period 1997-8 to 2003-4.

  Concerted efforts have been made by local authorities during the first five year local transport plan period, but in the face of continuing upward pressures of car ownership and use, trends for car dominance and congestion remain. In the transportation planning profession there is new widespread acceptance that road pricing is a necessary tool for effectively tackling congestion.

  In our view, local road pricing should only be considered as part of a package of integrated measures, carefully designed to tackle local transport problems. This sensitive design should help to ensure that policies are well-targeted and equitable. The hypothecation of charging revenues to support the improvement in both the quantity and quality of alternatives to private vehicle use should help to ensure that users are presented with acceptable options for reducing car use.

  Moving from a local to a national scale, similar issues prevail. The current national road building programme seeks to tackle the most pressing congestion problems through targeted improvements, but again the pressures of continuing car ownership growth suggest that greater lengths of the national network will, over the next 10 years, become subject to congestion stress.

  Other measures, at the national scale, currently focus on the more efficient management of congestion, largely through the provision of better driver information. Measures such as variable message signing can be very effective in dealing with local congestion problems arising from incidents, but depend to a great extent on the availability of increasingly scarce capacity on other parts of the network.

  In conclusion, at both the local and national scale, we consider it unlikely that other measures could be more effective in reducing congestion. Rather, road-pricing strategies need to be integrated with other measures to provide drivers with a combination of appropriate pricing signals, reflecting true external costs at the point of use, and acceptable alternatives to car use.

November 2004





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 2 August 2005