Select Committee on Transport Written Evidence


Memorandum by Dr Denvil Coombe (RP 49)

ROAD PRICING

CREDENTIALS

  Led the South and West Yorkshire and London Orbital Multi-Modal Studies, both of which recommended that area-wide road pricing should be introduced as soon as practical as the only effective means of tackling congestion in the medium to longer term. The teams also recommended that limited motorway widening should be undertaken and that, in the meantime, the benefits from this widening should be "locked in" by means of management measures integral to the widening schemes.

  Led the A3 Hindhead Roads-based Study in which the case for tolling the proposed tunnel under Hindhead Common was investigated. The study team recommended against charging for the use of the tunnel alone because too much traffic would avoid payment of the tolls by diverting to alternative untolled routes and advised that tolls should be reconsidered only when the technology for free-flow tolling became available and only in the context of an area-wide road pricing scheme.

  Contributed to the Department for Transport's Feasibility Study of Road Pricing in the UK by (a) preparing a review of the Multi-Modal Study and Roads-based Study evidence on road pricing; (b) assisting the South and West Yorkshire Multi-Modal Study consultants in the conduct of tests of alternative road pricing strategies; and (c) preparing a Composite Report of the tests of alternative road pricing strategies conducted using models covering the areas studied in the South and West Yorkshire, London Orbital and Cambridge to Huntingdon Multi-Modal Studies.

  Member of the Standing Advisory Committee on Trunk Road Assessment for the 1994 Report on Trunk Roads and the Generation of Traffic and the 1999 Report on Transport and the Economy.

SOME COMMENTS ABOUT THE PROPOSED M6 EXPRESSWAY

  The Department for Transport set out their proposal for a new dual two-lane, tolled, motorway alongside the existing M6, from Junction 11a to Junction 19, in their document M6: giving motorists the choice, dated July 2004. The main intention is to provide more road capacity in the corridor, at a lower cost compared with widening the existing M6. Applying tolls on the new road would enable traffic levels on the new road to be controlled so that an attractive level of service can be maintained, as well providing a revenue stream to assist with its funding.

  In the short term, the main response from drivers is that some of them would re-route to take advantage of the new capacity. Leaving all other responses on one side, I expect average traffic speeds would rise as a result of re-routeing alone.

  Another short-term response is likely to be that some drivers would re-time their journeys to take advantage of the reduced congestion at peak times. This would result in higher speeds in the periods outside the peaks and would depress speeds somewhat in the peak periods back towards the pre-improvement levels.

  In the longer term, but not necessarily very long term, I would expect some drivers to adjust their destinations to take advantage of the fact that they can travel further in any given period of time than they could before the new road was open. Some changes of this nature—for example, changes in trips for discretionary purposes, such as leisure and shopping-may occur in the shorter term, while other changes in destination, such as changes in workplaces, may take longer to mature.

  In the somewhat longer term, I would expect some people to respond by moving home, again to take advantage of the fact that they can travel further in any given period of time.

  There may also be some transfer from public transport and some generation of wholly new motorised trips, although the evidence available suggests that, in general, these effects will be smaller than the trip-lengthening effect caused by changing where people live, work and undertake other activities.

  Also in the longer term, but again not necessarily in the very long term, I would expect pressures to arise for development at locations close to either the junctions on the new Expressway or junctions on the existing M6 which would be substantially relieved by the new road. These developments would, of course, give rise to extra traffic.

  The net effect of all these factors could well be an increase in traffic in the corridor, over and above the increase that would have occurred without the new road. Without seeing the traffic model output, the scale of the extra traffic which would be induced by the new capacity is hard to judge. Experience suggests that the scale would be higher where congestion in the pre-improvement case is high. An increase in the road capacity in the M6 corridor is being seen as a priority simply because it is congested. In general terms, the greater the degree of congestion prior to an improvement, the greater will be the amount of extra traffic induced by the improvement. I would therefore expect the level of induced traffic to be relatively high in this case.

  The answer to the problems caused by induced traffic is to implement measures on the existing M6, and possibly on other major roads in the corridor as well, to "lock-in" the benefits of the extra capacity.

  The best way of achieving this, in the absence of an area-wide road pricing scheme, would be to introduce tolls on the existing M6 as well as on the new Expressway. The idea is that the tolls on the existing M6 would be set at a low level, just sufficient to deter induced traffic and thereby maintain total traffic in the corridor at the pre-improvement levels. Thus, all drivers using the existing M6 and the new M6 Expressway would pay, but those wishing to pay for the higher level of service offered by the M6 Expressway would pay more. If this is not feasible, then a combination of ramp metering and high occupancy vehicle lanes may be deployed in an attempt to contain total traffic levels in the corridor as nearly as possible to their pre-improvement levels.

  M6: giving motorists a choice says in paragraph 13: "In July 2003, the Secretary of State for Transport published the discussion paper Managing Our Roads, which outlined the key issues involved in tackling congestion on the strategic road network. These include getting the right balance between additional capacity and measures which ensure benefits are `locked in', whether through physical measures or pricing.". While this acknowledges the point about the need to implement demand management in conjunction with providing new capacity, there is no discussion of what this might mean in the context of the proposed M6 Expressway.

  The recommendation from the West Midlands to North West Multi-Modal Study was for an additional lane in each direction on the existing M6. The proposal for an M6 Expressway effectively doubles the extra capacity that is to be provided. Thus, if the additional one lane in each direction was an appropriate level of increase, the new M6 Expressway must represent an over-provision of capacity. If this is the case, the new M6 Expressway would tend to undermine rather than support the case for a national road pricing scheme in that the justification for a road pricing scheme is dependent on congestion levels being sufficiently high and, if congestion has been reduced unduly by the over-provision of road capacity, the justification for road pricing would be reduced.

SOME OBSERVATIONS ABOUT AREA-WIDE ROAD PRICING

  The basic principle of efficient road user charging is that users should, in theory, be charged for all the additional costs they impose by their use of the road system—road wear and tear, delays to other users, increased accident risk and environmental cost. The term used to refer to these additional costs is "Marginal External Cost". When these are added to those costs borne directly by the user (such as fuel and their own time), the result is called "Marginal Social Cost".

  In the Feasibility Study of Road Pricing in the UK, published by the Department for Transport in July 2004, patterns and levels of charges were sought, using the Department's National Transport Model, which closely matched Marginal Social Costs. The result was a set of charge rates which varied by area type, road type and volume to capacity ratio and which ranged from small negative to large positive charges per kilometre.

  This set of charges was considered as being both additional to fuel duty and a replacement for part of fuel duty such that the total revenue remained the same as in the case without charging. The comments which now follow relate to the case where road user charges are additional to existing fuel duty and other motoring taxes.

  While the approach of applying charge rates which closely match Marginal Social Costs is theoretically correct, it can be problematic in practice. In reality, Marginal Social Costs will vary from link to link and finding a charging structure which (a) matches closely the pattern of actual Marginal Social Costs, (b) is comprehensible to road users, and (c) does not cause unwanted re-routeing effects, can be very difficult at least and impossible in some circumstances.

  The pattern of 80 charge rates developed by the Department for its recent study was aimed at matching Marginal Social Costs reasonably closely but actually yielded unwanted re-routeing effects. When the charge rates devised using the National Transport Model were passed down to the Multi-Modal Study models it was found that the high degree of variability in charge rates from link to link caused circuitous routeing, to the extent that the average trip length increased rather than decreased as expected. The result was that, whereas the National Transport Model appraisal showed a net benefit from Marginal Social Cost pricing, the Multi-Modal Study model in which the trip-lengthening effect was most clearly evident showed a net disbenefit because the effects of the extra traffic outweighed the gains from fewer trips using the road system.

  A much more approximate approach was used in the South and West Yorkshire and London Orbital Multi-Modal Studies in which a single figure area-wide distance-based charge was sought which maximised user benefits. Simple charging systems of this kind are quite distant from true Marginal Social Cost pricing in which charges may well vary markedly from link to link.

  In practice, a system which balances the aims of matching Marginal Social Cost, maintaining comprehensibility for users, and avoiding perverse and/or unwanted effects is likely to lie somewhere between a true Marginal Social Cost pricing system (in which charge rates are likely to be highly variable from link to link) and a single figure area-wide distance-based charge.

  The following distinction may be made between Short Run and Long Run Marginal Social Costs. Short Run Marginal Social Cost is defined as the social cost of an additional vehicle kilometre at the current level of infrastructure provision. Long Run Marginal Social Cost is defined as the social cost of an additional vehicle kilometre when infrastructure provision is optimally adjusted to the level of demand.

  For simplicity, I consider now the components of Short Run Marginal Social Cost only: road maintenance and renewal costs (borne by infrastructure providers); congestion and accidents (borne by infrastructure users); and noise and local air pollution and global warming (borne by non-infrastructure users). Again, for simplicity, I consider only congestion, which has been at the heart of the case for road pricing since first conceived in the 1920s.

  When charges are levied for the use of congested road infrastructure, the two main groups of response will be as follows: some road users will elect not to pay the charge but will instead either not travel at all or will travel by another mode; and other road users (usually the majority) will decide to pay the charge and continue to travel by road, although some may change their destination to one nearer their origin and many may change their route. By "road users" here, I mean those that use private vehicles of some kind (cars, motorcycles and goods vehicles) and I exclude public transport passengers. These two groups of response will occur with all charging systems, no matter how closely the charging system replicates the actual pattern of Marginal Social Costs.

  The people in the first group will all suffer a disbenefit. Those who do not travel at all will lose the utility of the journey they made before the pricing was introduced. Those who travel by an alternative mode will also suffer a disbenefit because, as far as they are concerned, their total generalised cost, without the charge but including their valuation of travel quality and convenience, will have been less by private vehicle than it will be by the alternative mode.

  Leaving aside for the moment the impacts of the charges (which I deal with later), most of the people in the second group will experience a benefit from reduced congestion and reduced vehicle operating costs (especially if their routes are less circuitous because of the reduced congestion) caused by fewer vehicle-kilometres being travelled on the road system. However, those who respond by travelling to a closer destination (as a result of the charge) will lose the utility derived from travelling to their previous destination further away. It is not possible to disentangle these effects but, for a road pricing scheme to be justified, the net time and vehicle operating cost benefits to this group of travellers as a whole will usually be positive.

  For road pricing to be justified as a congestion reducing measure, the net benefits to the second group should outweigh the disbenefits to the first group, to yield an overall net benefit in these terms. This will not happen where: congestion is low and the benefits from reductions in vehicle-kilometres travelled on the road system are small; and/or charges are set so high as to deter too many people from travelling by private vehicle thereby generating high disbenefits; and/or the alternative modes are very poor compared with the private vehicle, again thereby generating high disbenefits. So the conditions have to be right and it is not the case that road pricing can be justified in all cases.

  A further factor to consider now is the charges. Note that I am only considering the case where the charges are additional to existing motoring taxes. These are a disbenefit to those who pay them—the continuing road users—and a benefit to the charging authority. In very broad terms, these two terms cancel out in the cost/benefit analysis, but not precisely because of the way the calculations are done. There will also be changes in tax revenues to Government but these are not usually so large as to distort the simplified story I am setting out here. The other key element of the cost/benefit analysis will be the costs of collecting the revenues, including the costs of setting up the system and operating, maintaining and enforcing it.

  It is generally the case that the charges paid by continuing road users will outweigh the net benefits to travellers as a whole. So leaving aside taxation changes, and the complications of the way that the calculations are performed for each of the benefits and disbenefits, the general picture can be summarised in the following simple terms:

    —  net benefits (in terms of time and vehicle operating cost savings) to continuing road users (+A);

    —  disbenefits to those deterred from travelling by private vehicle (and who either do not travel or travel by a less suitable mode) (-B);

    —  charges paid by continuing road users (-C);

    —  revenues accruing to the charging authority (+D); and

    —  costs of collecting the charges (-E).

  For a scheme to be justified as a congestion reducing measure, +A-B will be positive. Usually, the magnitude of C will exceed the magnitude of +A-B, so that +A-B-C will be negative. D will broadly cancel out C. And +A-B will exceed E (summed over the appraisal period). Usually, the net revenues (+D-E) will be very large. Substantial further benefits can be gained, in principle, from investing (or recycling) these revenues in other good value for money projects, including schemes to compensate some of the adversely impacted groups.

  Some commentators would argue that, under a good road pricing scheme, it is possible, in theory, to ensure that everyone benefits. This statement is true if +A-B-C+D-E is positive and if, somehow, the net revenues can be used to compensate losers directly. In practice, of course, this is not possible and so there will be some losers among the winners.

  In the simple terms set out above, travellers as a group will usually experience a net loss. Within that generality though, there will be a distribution of impacts, ranging from winners to losers. The winners will be those with high values of time on high value trips (such as business)—their gains from reduced congestion will outweigh the charges they pay. The losers will be those continuing road users with low values of time-the charges they pay will outweigh their gains from reduced congestion—and those who either do not travel or who change mode. Thus, in general, car travellers on business and possibly goods vehicles (depending on whether or not they pay significantly higher charges than cars) will experience a net gain, while other car travellers will experience a net loss. The sections of society too poor to own a car will gain from faster bus speeds as a result of the reduced congestion. They may also gain more substantially if some of the net revenues are used to provide better public transport services and other measures aimed at reducing social exclusion. Those travellers who change mode as a result of the charge may also gain if their new mode can be improved by use of some of the net revenues from the charging. Those most difficult to compensate are the low income car users who continue to travel by car and pay the charge, although the recycling of revenues to improve public transport may, if targeted carefully, partially offset the disbenefits to this group.

  The impacts set out above will change as the charge level increases in different ways. In general terms, the shapes of the relationships between the impacts and the charge levels will be as follows:

    —  the aggregate net time and vehicle operating cost benefits to continuing road users (A above) will increase but the rate of increase will tail off as traffic levels are reduced due to the nature of the flow/delay or speed/flow relationships (or, in other words, the shape of the supply curve), as shown below (the vertical axis is the net time and vehicle operating cost benefit and the horizontal axis is the charge);



    —  the aggregate disbenefits to those deterred from travelling by private vehicle (B above) will increase but the rate of increase will accelerate as the charges impact on those with less attractive alternatives, due to the shape of the demand curve, as shown below (the vertical axis is the disbenefit to deterred travellers (of opposite sign to the benefits in the previous point) and the horizontal axis is the charge);



    —  the disbenefits of the charges to road users (C above) will increase up to a maximum and then decline as the charges reach levels where the levels of deterrence become high (this is a function of the shape of the demand curve), as shown below (the vertical axis is the disbenefit of the charges to continuing users and the horizontal axis is the charge);



    —  the revenues accruing to the charging authority (D above) will increase up to a maximum and then decline to mirror broadly the relationship between the charge disbenefit and the charges shown in the previous point, as shown below (the vertical axis is the benefit of the revenues to the charging authority and the horizontal axis is the charge);



    —  the costs of collecting the charges should be broadly unaffected by changes in charge level.

  As noted above, the charge disbenefits and the revenue benefits broadly cancel out and it should be possible to see that the combination of the first two graphs should give a maximum benefit. It follows that the ease with which a maximum can be determined will depend on:

    —  the shape of the supply curve (that is, the flow/delay or speed/flow relationship) for the network as a whole and the slope of that curve at the level of demand on the network; and

    —  the elasticity of demand or the slope of the demand curve in the vicinity of its intersection point with the supply curve (that is, the point of equilibrium between supply and demand).

  It is not a foregone conclusion that a maximum can be determined in every network. If the demand is too low and the equilibrium point is on the flat part of the supply curve, or the demand curve is too flat, it may be difficult to identify a clear maximum.

  In principle, the single charge level that will yield the maximum economic benefits can generally be identified quite easily, providing the circumstances are right. By "single" charge level, I mean, for example, either a single area-wide distance-based charge or a particular level of a single pattern of cordon crossing charges. While it may be sufficient for some purposes to define the optimum charge in these simple terms, there are, in principle, many variations which could be explored in search of higher maximum economic benefits. In general terms, the variations should be with the aim of matching more closely the distribution of Marginal Social Costs throughout the network, bearing in mind the need to maintain comprehensibility and avoid perverse and/or unwanted effects.

  In the South and West Yorkshire Multi-Modal Study, the economically optimum single figure area-wide distance-based charge was shown to be 4 pence/km (additional to existing motoring taxes). Reducing the charge to 2 pence/km for the links where the volume to capacity ratio was less than 25% and increasing the charge to 7 pence/km where the volume to capacity ratio exceeded 75% increased the benefits by about 40%. While it was clear from this test that the value of the maximum benefits can be affected by the charging structure, no tests were undertaken to assess whether the general charge level at which the maximum benefits occurred would change.

  The flow reductions that would arise with the economically optimum charging level will vary with the circumstances—essentially, with the slopes of the supply and demand curves. Even with a single area-wide optimum charge, flow reductions will vary from link to link as traffic adjusts to the combination of lower traffic levels in combination with the charge. Variations in charge levels from link to link will also cause flow reductions to vary.

  Turning now to the other components of Short Run Marginal Social Cost, I imagine that road maintenance and renewal costs will decrease with reducing traffic. Accidents are related to traffic volumes and accidents per vehicle-km vary by road type. Road user charging may alter the distribution of vehicle-kms by road type and so the relationship between reduced traffic as a result of a road user charging scheme and reduced accidents is not necessarily a direct one although it may well be broadly linear. Noise levels are a function of traffic flow, proportion of heavy vehicles and traffic speed and only matter where sensitive receptors exist. The relationship between traffic reductions arising from road user charging and the numbers of people annoyed by noise is therefore very complex. Air pollutants are a non-linear function of traffic flows, proportion of diesels and traffic speed. The relationship between traffic reductions and changes in local air quality are therefore very hard to pre-judge without actually performing the calculations. Greenhouse gas emissions, however, are directly related to vehicle-kilometres and are thus likely to decrease in line with reductions in traffic.

  From this simplistic analysis, it can be seen that the effects on the definition of the optimum road user charge of including all the elements of Short Run Marginal Social Costs are very unclear. However, in the Department's tests undertaken using the National Transport Model, simplified calculations of accident and environmental costs were included. On the basis of these tests, the teams carrying out the tests using the Multi-Modal Study models were advised that they could concentrate on time and vehicle operating cost savings only as these accounted for approaching 90% of the total benefits.

  Finally, turning to the question of the Long Run Social Marginal Cost, determining the optimum level of charging in this case is more complicated because, in principle, the capacity of the road system should be adjusted to cater for the demand from each optimum charging structure and level. The addition of new infrastructure will, in turn, affect the position of the optimum benefits, and so some iteration is likely to be required to determine the optimum combination of charge level and structure and amount of new capacity.

KEY MESSAGES

Toll Roads

  If toll roads are to be considered, two principles should apply. First, the net increase in capacity should not exceed that required under an optimum area-wide road pricing scheme in the first year that such a scheme would be justified and practical. This would be consistent with the statement on page 7 of The Government's Response to the Transport Select Committee's Report Jam Tomorrow?: The Multi-Modal Study Investment Plans: "We will ensure that the case for road schemes taken forward following the Multi-Modal Studies is robust even if a decision is taken to introduce road user charging in the future.". Second, the benefits accruing to the users of roads relieved by the new toll road, including those on the existing motorway, should be "locked in" by either tolls on those roads (as well as the new road) or other management measures.

Area-Wide Road Pricing

  The basic principle of efficient road user charging is that users should, in theory, be charged for all the additional costs they impose by their use of the road system—road wear and tear, delays to other users, increased accident risk and environmental cost. When these costs are added to those borne directly by the user (such as fuel and their own time), the result is called "Marginal Social Cost". While the approach of applying charge rates which closely match Marginal Social Costs is theoretically correct, it can be problematic in practice. In reality, Marginal Social Costs will vary from link to link and finding a charging structure which (a) matches closely the pattern of actual Marginal Social Costs, (b) is comprehensible to road users, and (c) does not cause unwanted re-routeing effects, can be very difficult at least and impossible in some circumstances.

  Travellers as a group will usually experience a net loss from a road pricing scheme. Within that generality though, there will be a distribution of impacts, ranging from winners to losers. The winners will be those with high values of time on high value trips (such as business)—their gains from reduced congestion will outweigh the charges they pay. The losers will be those continuing road users with low values of time—the charges they pay will outweigh their gains from reduced congestion—and those who either do not travel or who change mode. Thus, in general, car travellers on business and possibly goods vehicles (depending on whether or not they pay significantly higher charges than cars) will experience a net gain, while other car travellers will experience a net loss. The sections of society too poor to own a car will gain from faster bus speeds as a result of the reduced congestion. They may also gain more substantially if some of the net revenues are used to provide better public transport services and other measures aimed at reducing social exclusion. Those travellers who change mode as a result of the charge may also gain if their new mode can be improved by use of some of the net revenues from the charging. Those most difficult to compensate are the low income car users who continue to travel by car and pay the charge, although the recycling of revenues to improve public transport may, if targeted carefully, partially offset the disbenefits to this group.

  In principle, there is an optimum combination of charge level and structure and the amount of new road capacity. Thus, the case for new road capacity, whether provided by traffic management or new infrastructure, should be considered in the context of, and jointly with, area-wide road pricing.

Denvil Coombe

Transport Planning Consultant

January 2005





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 2 August 2005