Select Committee on Transport Written Evidence


Memorandum by Mott MacDonald (LR 87)

INTEGRATED TRANSPORT:  THE FUTURE OF LIGHT RAIL AND MODERN TRAMS IN BRITAIN

INTRODUCTION

  Mott MacDonald [MM] is pleased to submit evidence to the House of Commons Transport Committee. MM is a leading multi-disciplinary consultancy with transportation as its main business. We have over 8000 staff world wide and over the last 20 years have played a leading role in the planning and development of light rail schemes in the UK, including the schemes in Newcastle upon Tyne, Manchester, Nottingham, West Midlands and Dublin. We continue to provide advice to the promoters of these schemes and are providing technical and procurement advice on the development of schemes in Edinburgh and Liverpool.

  For the Light Rail and Modern Trams industry in Britain to have a successful future then we must look at the history of experience both at home and abroad to guide its direction for the future. To have taken steps, that in the safety of retrospective wisdom can be seen as less than ideal is only human and the basis on which civilisation progresses. To repeat those mistakes is tantamount to carelessness.

  Society at large can benefit enormously from this form of Transport but unless we can fully embrace all the difficult issues associated with implementation, progress will be painfully slow or even non-existent.

  The following provides our comments on the issues being addressed by the Transport Committee.

THE COSTS AND BENEFITS OF LIGHT RAIL

  Cost per kilometre varies substantially depending on conditions, terrain and level of promoter specification/expectations. Typically costs in the UK are currently ranging between £15 million and £20 million per kilometre. Tramcars represent approximately 25% of this capital cost, with vehicles currently costing between £1.5 million and £2 million each.

  The design, particularly the weight, of vehicles determines many other system costs; variables include energy requirements, the size of the overhead equipment and its supporting infrastructure and track installation design. Simplicity of vehicle design can also reduce the cost of depot infrastructure and long term maintenance. Yet the vehicles are often one of the last items to be considered and procured.

  Utilities relocation costs may represent 20% of capital cost. In the UK promoters have to pay 92.5% of the costs of diverting utilities. In Germany promoters contribute less, while in France they pay nothing. The necessity of relocating utilities on the premise of minimising future disruption to service patterns is no longer accepted or affordable and this will have an effect on cost. Many current schemes are seeking to adopt a risk based approach to managing utility diversions. This is yet to be fully accepted by the Utility Companies.

  It is important to define what is meant by "benefit" in examining the performance of light rail schemes. Different schemes are promoted for different purposes and a clear understanding of the policy objectives of the promoter is required. Typical objectives are:

    —  to serve the local economy;

    —  to help reduce road traffic growth and thus congestion;

    —  to benefit the environment;

    —  to tackle social exclusion;

    —  to assist in regeneration.

  Economic benefits form a large part of the Government NATA and STAG evaluation techniques and all schemes have had to demonstrate benefits in this area. There is ample evidence from the Manchester Metrolink and Croydon Tramlink to show that the overall local economy has improved with the introduction of tramways.

  Road congestion is largely a result of the ever-growing level of private car use. Disincentives to car use [congestion charging, road tolls, high parking charges, fuel duty escalators, etc.] are unpopular, as demonstrated in Edinburgh. Additional means of securing a modal shift are required. Evidence from current UK tramways has shown that they have all demonstrated a modal shift of between 15-20%, without the direct application of disincentives to car use. Bus priority schemes have had a less successful track record. The Director General of the West Midlands PTE is on record as saying that whilst Midland Metro had achieved 15% modal shift the "bus showcase" routes [which are run by the same operator] have only achieved 2-3% modal shift.[27]

  Environmental benefits are largely as a result of modal shift replacing trips by internal combustion engine vehicles with electric traction, thus ensuring no pollution at the point of use.

  Social exclusion results from disadvantaged groups not having access to reliable transport, or not being able to afford transport. In this context the "price" of transport includes not only the fare, but also reliability and the time spent in making a journey. Evidence from a number of schemes has shown that providing reliable, quick and affordable travel has opened up work and leisure opportunities for disadvantaged groups.

  Regeneration had been the objective of a number of schemes and is best exemplified by the success of the Docklands Light Railway. Initial studies suggested that potential redevelopment in Docklands could only justify a bus link to existing railheads. Developers responded by insisting that only a reliable, permanent fixed link would encourage them to invest in the area. The initial railway was opened in 1986 and demand has consistently outstripped transport supply from that date. On a smaller scale Croydon was experiencing decay in the older parts of the town, with decaying occupancy rates in 1960s office blocks in the new town. Tramlink has improved access and has resulted in virtually 100% occupancy rates in the older parts of town and a spurt of refurbishment and rebuilding in the new town.

WHAT LIGHT RAIL SYSTEMS NEED TO BE SUCCESSFUL

  Within four years of opening Manchester Metrolink was carrying 13 million passengers per year, almost twice the previous railway loadings. Although conceived primarily as a city centre commuter service, the particular success of Metrolink has been for attracting off-peak travel.

  Newcastle, Docklands and Manchester are very much seen as the exemplars of success and have helped justify why such schemes are needed. They either had an existing rail base or supported massive land use changes. Unfortunately, this was not the case for Sheffield. Unlike these schemes Sheffield is mainly a street based system which provided new capacity on (mostly) new alignments in heavily trafficked corridors. Insufficient traffic priorities at junctions has lead to longer than anticipated journey times and poor punctuality. It was also planned prior to, but opened after, bus deregulation and was prone to significant competition from local bus operators.

  Stagecoach won the 26 year operating franchise for Sheffield Supertram in 1997. Significant efforts to better integrate with the City's transport network have since seen passenger numbers rise. Ridership having increased from just over 5 million in its first full year of operation to over 12 million by 2003.

  To maximise their potential light rail schemes should preferably penetrate the city centre. This has not been the case with the West Midlands scheme, which terminates on the edge of Birmingham city centre and as such lacks the visibility and penetration of other schemes. The proposed Snow Hill to Five Ways extension seeks to redress this issue.

  If light rail schemes are to be successful they need to be:

    —  integrated with the land-use and development plans of the local authorities—Docklands has shown how this can be achieved.

    —  integrated into the overall transport network. This requires adequate park and ride facilities at outer termini, taxi and bus feeders to the tramway trunk network and integration with major heavy rail and metro stations.

    —  Passenger information and ticketing must encourage multi-modal travel across the transport network—public transport operators should be competing against the private car, not competing amongst themselves. Cities such as Hanover, Zurich, the Hague and Strasbourg demonstrate how this can be achieved.

HOW EFFECTIVELY IS LIGHT RAIL USED AS PART OF AN INTEGRATED TRANSPORT SYSTEM?

  Light rail can be one element of an integrated transport system. To be effective integration requires a firm, consistent, long term framework on which plans can be based.

  With the exception of London there is no effective example of an integrated transport network in the UK. Setting an overall strategy for economic development, land use and transport planning in the UK is overly complicated and lacks co-ordination . In any given area the functions are spread over a number of local authorities and transport executives and an array of ad hoc government initiatives and agencies. The ability of public bodies to plan and provide public transport is frustrated by the fragmented nature of the industry. Rail is operated by a mixture of central government subvention and private sector operation. Bus and taxi services are deregulated, with local authorities having very little influence on service patterns.

  Most UK tram systems have not been set in the context of an overall public transport network, which would utilise buses and taxis for low-volume short trips, trams for major corridors into cities and metros or heavy rail for the highest volume and longer trips. An integrated network would see each mode acting as a feeder distributor to the other modes. Unfortunately a UK legacy for competition within the industry, rather than competition between public and private transport, has resulted in all modes fighting for patronage—even where inappropriate and the competition damages the overall public service.

  Both the Newcastle Metro and Sheffield Supertram were promoted as part of an integrated bus/rail network. Deregulation shattered the integration—resulting in the collapse of Metro ridership and the continuing underperformance of Sheffield. Later systems, such as Croydon and Nottingham have been better integrated. Nottingham has good Park and Ride facilities and the bus network has been reshaped to remove wasteful competition with the tram line. London (including Croydon) has the benefit of an overall planning authority for metro, tram and bus, with through ticketing, common information and marketing. The 2004 fares revision has attracted significant further custom by making bus and tram ticketing interchangeable.

  The disintegration of the public transport industry in the UK, coupled with the largely cautious approach to inter-operator cooperation adopted by the OFT has prevented the industry mounting an effective challenge to the dominance of the motor car over much of the country. At the same time the private sector is reluctant to provide the investment needed to compensate for the lack of government investment in public transport when the industry is so fragmented and internally competitive.

  The UK position contrasts markedly with the position of most of our EU partners; Germany has an integrated public transport system in each major conurbation, centrally planned and promoted and incorporating a mixture of municipal and quasi-private operators; in France joint public/private enterprises operate integrated public transport networks in cities outside Paris and similarly integrated approaches are adopted in the Netherlands, Belgium and Italy.

BARRIERS TO THE DEVELOPMENT OF LIGHT RAIL

  Lack of standardisation is a major barrier to development. We fully agree with NAO recommendations for the formation of tram specific technical, operational and safety standards. To derive maximum benefits it is important that harmonisation is achieved where possible at an EU rather than purely national level. The recommendations coming forward from the European Commission LibeRTIN project (the thematic network investigation technical harmonisation and standardisation of light rail vehicles) could provide an appropriate mechanism to drive this process forward.

  Vehicle costs are unduly high as a relatively small number of vehicles is required for each scheme and the uniqueness of each UK fleet reduces the opportunity to take advantage of economies of scale, particularly with respect to long term maintenance costs.

  Interface and reaching agreement with Network Rail has often proved unduly prolonged and expensive. In part this is due to their complex management structure and at times a reluctance to actively assist towards enhancement of public transport provision as a whole.

  A less prominent but effective barrier to the development of light rail in the UK has been Government failure to recognise the benefits to be derived from a steady flow of work, thus allowing industry to build up and maintain a corpus of knowledge and expertise.

  The processes involved in the Transport and Works Act procedures are long and subject to unpredictable delay and a promoter has no clear indication of the time that it will take the Secretary of State to reach a final decision on the award of an Order. This is similarly off-putting to firms participating in early private sector involvement in schemes.

  The delays in agreeing government investment in schemes offers a further disincentive to private sector involvement and can see some of the value of public sector funds being eroded by inflation. The allocation of risk is often skewed and results in the price of the scheme being inflated by private sector risk premia [see section on financing arrangements, below ]

  This attitude can be compared with that of the French government. Here the government willed the end of reducing private transport use; identified the means as light rail (or mini-metro in a limited number of cities); provided part of the financial wherewithal by means of the versement transport payroll tax; has helped to streamline the obtaining of powers for schemes and has encouraged public/private joint working through the societé mixte approach. The result has been that 10 successful tramways have been built in France in the last 19 years.

  Including local bus operator(s) in the concession is a way to minimise competition, and can lead to an effective "re-shaping" of local bus services around the tram network to maximise integration. This has been the case in Nottingham, where fortuitously the local bus operator was part of the winning consortium, but it seems wrong to leave this choice to market forces. Where bus competition is a concern authorities could seek to actively manage risk through use of local authority powers to enter into bus quality contracts.

  The procurement process offers an expensive and high risk exercise to the private sector. Many firms are now refusing to participate in the process. Those that do are seeking to recover their costs by higher bid-prices. Contract award delays, such as experienced on Manchester Metrolink Phase 3, will inevitably further increase costs and reduce the attractiveness of PFI light rail procurements to the private sector.

THE EFFECT OF DIFFERENT FINANCING ARRANGEMENTS ON THE OVERALL COST OF LIGHT RAIL SYSTEMS

  The funding mechanism adopted on UK schemes to manage and secure funding of schemes is the Private Finance Initiative. Under a traditional PFI contract a private sector consortium will design, build, finance, operate and maintain the project. The Consortium in return receives service payments over time out of public money, linked to its performance during the contract. Such structures (as used in Croydon and Manchester) do not cope well with subsequent extensions to the system.

  Inappropriate risk allocation in UK schemes, as between the public and private sector, is contributing to the high capital cost compared with schemes elsewhere in Europe, and is making light rail unattractive compared with other forms of public transport. In particular, the private sector is rightly reluctant to fully accept farebox/revenue risk.

  Where the private sector takes revenue risk, it will seek to mitigate risk by ensuring the scheme's revenue forecasts are conservative and that its financial structure has taken account of the possibility of a shortfall between predicted and actual revenue. Funders are very sceptical of the accuracy of patronage and revenue forecasts and it is difficult to raise private sector funding for light rail schemes where repayment relies substantially on farebox revenue. An alternative approach might be for the public sector to bear most of this risk in its introductory phase, with an increasing transfer of risk to the private sector as a scheme becomes more fully established.

  There is a growing difference between the cost of the input elements of a scheme and the price charged by the private sector. These differences are largely a reflection of the risk premia applied by the private sector, combined with an element of disenchantment with the delays and frustrations experienced in previous UK light rail schemes. Some companies have withdrawn altogether from the light rail market, whilst other financial agencies are seeking a much higher Internal Rate of Return for what are seen as difficult and high-risk contracts.

  The essence of PFI was to place risk where it could best be managed—transferring ridership risk to the private sector contradicts this principle. The holder of a 30 year operating concession has very little influence over macro management of the local economy, cannot influence land use and planning decisions, nor road building programmes. They are not even given an enforceable contract as to the level of priority that they will be given at signalised junctions in the highway—even though such priority is vital if they are to achieve and maintain competitive run times.

  Private financing approaches might be considered to work best when they follow the models adopted for Prisons, Hospitals, Roads, etc., ie a structure where the private sector has no exposure to revenue risk and facility operation [other than routine maintenance of the structure]. This approach has been developed over a number of contracts by the DLR. The Lewisham extension was financed by a PPP procurement on an availability and part revenue risk arrangement, with rolling stock, signalling and operations remaining with the public sector. The current DLR extension to Woolwich, via City Airport has used a "classic" PFI procurement with the public sector paying an infrastructure availability fee for the fixed concession term. In this case, the private sector is carrying the risks it is readily able to manage; design, financing, build and availability. The public sector carries the patronage, operations, rolling stock and signalling risks.

  Time will tell which of the DLR approaches produce the best results, but the Lewisham procurement has resulted in an extension delivered on time and on budget, with a financially sound private sector element. The Woolwich approach demonstrated a short, comprehensible, bidding process with an early selection of the preferred bidder—so minimising bid costs.

  Alternative approaches that are precedented and worth consideration include;

    —  the original DLR was publicly funded by the London Docklands Development Corporation using public funds that were generated by the sale of land at increased value as a result of the development of the light railway. This approach could be of great value where the Government is seeking to regenerate brown field sites—as in the Thames gateway.

    —  many first generation tramways in the USA were built to open up new tracts of land for development—the cost of the line was set off against the increase in land value once the improved accessibility was achieved. Similar approaches were adopted by the private sector Underground Group in London before 1933.

    —  increases in land values not owned by the tramway promoter can be captured and recycled into capital funding by use of local Transit Improvement District property taxes, which are used in the USA, or the oneoff property taxes levied in Toronto.

  The model structures emerging in Edinburgh and Liverpool (which separate operations from infrastructure contracts and incorporate a more reasonable approach to risk and revenue sharing) may also prove effective. A clear need exists for an evaluation of alternative model structures to identify how financial viability can be improved.

THE PRACTICALITY OF ALTERNATIVES TO LIGHT RAIL, INCLUDING INVESTMENT IN BUSES

  Bus services continue to carry a significant number of passengers and improvements in bus services are important. With a few notable exceptions, bus services are in continuing overall decline, [down by 21% between 1982 and 2002][28] both in absolute numbers of passengers carried and in market share. This must be set against rail travel increasing by 36% between the mid 1990s and 2002.[29]

  The notable exception to this is in London, where almost all the ridership gains reported for England and Wales are generated. Conditions in London are potentially advantageous to buses; the fleet has been modernised thanks to TfL requiring new buses from tenders, there are extensive bus priority measures, much of the infrastructure [both highway and parking space] provided for cars is already saturated, the Congestion Charging scheme in central London has had a beneficial effect in driving modal shift and the Mayor is committed to subsidising high-frequency bus services. This imay prove an extremely expensive option, with estimates of total bus subsidy predicted to rise to £1 billion by the end of the decade.

  The cost of bus improvements are often understated, This infrastructure is publicly funded and effectively provided free or at a low "rent" with roads, bus stops, busways, traffic management and policing all being funded by the taxpayer. The provision of Fuel Duty Rebate skews the system against the adoption of electric traction. All these elements are no doubt worthy of public investment, but they must be taken into account when making like-for-like comparisons between bus and tram schemes. The Confederation of Passenger Transport UK gave evidence to the 1999 Select Committee Enquiry and said "For complete new systems on reserved track with new stations, infrastructure and a new vehicle fleet, the capital cost [of a busway] could be similar to that of a light rail line".

  The ability of busways to generate modal shift is also open to debate. The comparative experience of West Midlands PTE has already been referred to. Compared with light rail, there is rather less than 100 miles of guided busway in the world and the longest section in the UK is the 1.5km of the recently opened Edinburgh "Fastway". The longest established guided busway in Europe is in Essen and it is notable that far from being extended to serve wider areas it has been curtailed and the Essen public transport authorities are concentrating on upgrading their tramway and light rail operations.

  The experience of unguided busways is less encouraging, with most of the long established north American systems failing to achieve ridership targets. Ottawa spent 20 years developing Bus Rapid Transit as an alternative to rail, but has now embarked on a rail development programme. The UK's longest established busway is in Runcorn, far from attracting new passengers to public transport it has generated fewer trips per head of population than in comparable towns across the north west.

  The lower staff passenger ratio possible on a bus system and the shorter service life of a bus mean that in operating costs a rail system should offer lower passenger/km costs than a busway. Studies carried out in the UK and the US would seem to support this contention.

  A development of light rail with significant potential for the UK, is the "tram train" concept. Several systems are currently in operation, most notably in Karlsruhe, in Germany. This comprises a dual powered "tram like" vehicle able to ride on both heavy railway tracks and the tramway network—thus offering customers convenience and frequency of direct access to the very heart of the city. This form of shared track operation is also being developed in France and the Netherlands.

February 2005




27   HC153, 24 May 2000. Back

28   DfT Transport Trends 2002. Back

29   DfT Transport Trends 2002. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 10 August 2005