Select Committee on Trade and Industry Written Evidence


APPENDIX 12

Memorandum by The Federation of Small Businesses (FSB)

1.  INTRODUCTION

  1.1  The Federation of Small Businesses is Britain's biggest direct-member business organisation with 185,000 members. It exists to protect and promote the interests of all those who own or manage their own business.

  1.2  The FSB has 5,500 publican members. Based on previous survey data we estimate that 3,135 are tenants of pub companies or brewers.

2.  SOME HISTORY—THE RISE OF THE PUBCO

  2.1  Prior to the Beer Orders, to which the Monopolies and Mergers Commission's (MMC's) 1989 report, "The Supply of Beer" gave birth, pub companies barely existed in the UK. Yet by 2004 just two pubcos, Enterprise Inns and Punch Taverns, owned some 16,000 pubs, or in excess of 25% of all pubs in the UK. A further 7,000 tenanted pubs are owned by other pubcos, whilst fewer than 10,000 pubs are in the hands of brewers. As the Director General of Fair Trading (DGFT) remarked in his review of the Beer Orders in 2000:

    "The structure of retail ownership has changed dramatically following the implementation of the Beer Orders and subsequent emergence of retail pub chains."

  2.2  How did such a fundamental re-structuring occur? It had been the intent of the authors of the Beer Orders that the c 11,000 pubs which the Orders compelled the big brewers to divest should be sold individually, to sitting tenants who would then trade free of the tie. For various reasons, theory was confounded and this did not occur. Instead, forced to act quickly in a declining property market, the brewers sold pubs in parcels to opportunistic venture capitalists, striking contracts to supply beer. The pubco was born.

  2.3  The traditional justification for the tie was that the existence of an estate of tied pubs guaranteed an outlet for the brewers' manufacture and distribution of beer. Pubcos do not brew beer so this traditional justification has disappeared.

  2.4  Over time these new companies amalgamated to form the two large players now dominating the market. This concentration has meant that the economic and real market power in the distribution chain has now transferred from large brewers to large pubcos and net prices paid by the pubcos have fallen dramatically. In 2000 the DGFT observed, based on data submitted by the industry, that:

    "Margins (achieved by brewers) on sales of draught lager to retail pub chains are zero if not negative."

  Lager represents over 50% of total beer sales. Overall, the DGFT observed that the brewers made a small margin on sales to pubcos.

  2.5  Thus, the Beer Orders have had the effect of a massive transfer of margin from brewers to pubcos. This benefit has not been passed onto the licensee but has been retained by the pubco acting as the intermediary.

  2.6  When the DGFT reviewed the industry in 2000 he stated that between 1992 and 2000 there was a 15% decline in wholesale prices achieved by brewers in their sales to pubcos (paragraph 4.6). Over the same period brewers' list prices, i.e. prices before discount, rose by 24.5%. (The British Beer and Pub Association (BBPA) Handbook 2000 shows an increase from an index value of 83.2 in January 1992 to 103.6 in January 2000).

  2.7  Lack of transparency in pubco terms means that the FSB does not have access to data showing the increase in prices charged to tenants by pubcos during this time. However, in the absence of discounts which we believe to have been uncommon at that time, the increase would have been in the order of the 24.5% increase in list price.

  2.8  Meanwhile it is a matter of record that the price of a pint has risen ahead of inflation. The shift in margin from the brewers has not reached the consumer. The DGFT found that the price increase in retail beer prices charged in the "on trade" of " a little over 25% (in real terms and pre-tax) in the last 10 years." (para 4.3.)

  2.9  So between 1992 and 2000 we saw:

    —  A price reduction from brewers to pubcos of 15%,

    —  An unknown price increase from pubcos to licensees, which may have been in the order of 24-25%,

    —  A price increase from retailer to consumer of 25%.

  2.10  It is the contention of the FSB that the margin transferred from brewers to pubcos has remained with the pubcos, and that individual tenants have not shared in the benefits of this market dynamic. Indeed many tenants believe that brewers were fairer landlords and better partners.

    "Whilst Whitbread brewed the beer and owned the pubs, the arrangement with rents and beer discounts was reasonably fair. Once venture capitalists came onto the scene things changed, quickly"—Enterprise tenant in the East of England.

  2.11  The economic imperative for brewer landlords is to set prices that maintain and improve beer sales. Pubcos are not driven by the same commercial logic.

  2.12  In short, the pubco, an unintended consequence of the Beer Orders, has taken a dominant role in the supply chain, but without, in our view, adding any real degree of value other than to their capital providers. It has supplanted the brewer as the owner of property, leaving little else changed. True, tenants have achieved better security of tenure but that was a product of legal change, and not a result of the advent of pubcos.

3.  THE PUBCO BUSINESS MODEL

  3.1  In essence the pubco's business model is simple. It leases a pub to a tenant via one of a number of different forms of lease. These vary in length and conditions, but typically specify full-repairing and full-insuring obligations on the tenant. Beer and some other supplies must be purchased from the pubco or from suppliers nominated by the pubco, and rent paid by direct debit, usually a month in advance. Income from amusement with prizes machines (AWPs) in some cases goes solely to the pubco but is generally shared equally.

  3.2  The relationship between pubco and licensee is sometimes likened to a franchise. This is not the case because the products offered by the pubco are also available on the free market, which is not the case in the normal franchise model, used for example by McDonalds. Normal franchisees also benefit from the marketing and advertising of the product or service.

  3.3  Rents are indexed, increasing annually by the increase in RPI. They are also subject to review at a prescribed interval, say three or five years. Most leases specify an upwards only review.

  3.4  Pubcos enjoy the "company's right of entry" into licensees' premises. They employ flow monitoring systems and regular surprise searches by external agencies to ensure the licensee is not buying "off-tie."

  3.5  The input and selling price of beer is crucial to the business model. As we have seen, the pubco buys cheaply, indeed near to cost. It then sells to tenants at prices which generate a handsome margin. It is not in dispute that pubco tenants pay higher prices than any other channel of distribution.

  3.6  The offset, or "countervailing benefit", to the tenant is in the form of a lower than commercial, or free of tie, rent. It is this that is meant to compensate for high beer prices and enable the pubco tenant to compete with other pubs and make a reasonable return.

  3.7  For the pubco this is a very effective and low risk business model. It is in a position of bargaining strength with both its suppliers and its customers. Growth is assured in that rental income is index-linked, as well as being subject to regular upwards only review, and increases in the cost of beer are passed on to the tenant. Cash generation is both strong and stable, whilst risk is minimised. The ease with which pubcos such as Punch, Pubmaster and Unique have securitised their income streams indicates the low risk nature of the model. Investors and bond holders have been well rewarded with double digits earnings growth and Enterprise reporting a 16% increase in profits for the period ending 13 March 2004.

4.  THE UNEQUAL PARTNERSHIP

  4.1  The FSB takes no issue with the right of pubcos to succeed. However, on behalf of its members, it seeks a more equitable sharing of the value created in the transaction between landlord and tenant.

  4.2  A survey of 350 licensees by the Publican newspaper in May 2004 found that 92% of respondents felt that the relationship between pubco and licensee favoured the pubco.

  4.3  Deutsche Bank AG (brokers to Enterprise Inns) has produced a sample Profit and Loss account for the average pub from both the lessee's and lessor's point of view ("The Bear Pit", October 2003). This is based on a pub selling 210 barrels of beer per annum, and achieving a retail turnover of £200,000. Making various assumptions, Deutsche estimate that the annual profits made are:

Tenant before "cost of living benefit" £24,240
Pubco before Head Office costs£60,841
Total£85,081


  4.4  On this basis, the pubco receives 71.5% of all profit and the lessee 28.5%. The Deutsche model enhances the earnings of the lessee by a further notional £10, 259 to represent the value of free accommodation, increasing the lessee's share to 36%. In our view the inclusion of accommodation in this calculation is questionable for a number of reasons:

    —  it is a non-cash figure; as such it is not available for re-investment in the business,

    —  it ignores the fact that prudent lessees need to allocate some earnings to future housing needs as they cannot retire in the pub,

    —  it ignores the incidence of multiple lessees who, of course, can only live in one property,

    —  it seems, erroneously in our view, to include the value of personal expenditure by the lessee on food, drink, and tobacco.

  4.5  For these reasons we have, arbitrarily, reduced the accommodation benefit by 50%. This is not unreasonable in our view, since it should be acknowledged that there is also a financial benefit to the landlord in having the enhanced security of ensuring that the property is occupied, (i.e. not merely operated as a "lock up" business).

  4.6  In our view, then, and based on the Deutsche model, the earnings available are shared approximately 32:68 in favour of the pubco.

  4.7  In case it should be argued that this reflects the proper sharing of the balance of risk, we quote Deutsche:

    "In practice, most lessees in the industry are sceptical of claims that they and the landlord share in the upside and downside risk in equal proportion."

      4.8  It might be argued that the share of earnings is immaterial and that what matter more are the actual earnings of the lessee. The cash earnings (ignoring any accommodation benefit) of the average lessee in the Deutsche model are £24,240 per annum before interest and tax.

      4.9  Like many self-employed people, pub lessees work long hours. In the pub business this is, to a degree, a necessity. It is not at all uncommon for a couple to put in over 100 hours per week between them. On this basis the average hourly rate of pay is £4.60—below the new National Minimum Wage rate—with all of the risks and stresses of self-employment thrown in, plus the additional stress of living "on the job".

      4.10  Certainly many of our members would dispute the figure used by Deutsche Bank AG, and assert that they are making well below the National Minimum Wage and working well in excess of the 48-hour-week permitted by the Working Time Directive.

      4.11  An FSB member in the Midlands states that she earns £10,400 pa compared to the £48,411 made by Enterprise. This is the equivalent of £200 pw for a 90 hour week or £2.22 per hour. Another Enterprise tenant in the West Country has provided Profit and Loss accounts which show that his annual income is less than £8,000 pa.

      4.12  According to an FSB survey in 2001, 24% of respondents had taken a second job to make ends meet.

      4.13  If, as we contend, the rewards from the so-called partnership are shared unequally and that this results in the average lessee achieving only meagre earnings, then we need to examine why this is so.

    5.  THE CAUSE OF THE PROBLEM

      5.1  At the heart of this issue is the price which lessees pay for beer and the rent charged for the property, and the relationship between these two. According to Deutsche, lessees forego some £70 per barrel of beer by buying from their pubco as opposed to buying on the open or free market. We have no reason to doubt the accuracy of this figure, which amounts to a disadvantage of 24p/pint, although we certainly know of instances where the disadvantage rises to £100 per barrel, or 35p/pint. For example:

      —  £113/barrel difference on Carlsberg for a Punch tenant in Wales (39p/pint.)

      —  £107/barrel difference on Stella Artois for an Enterprise tenant in the South West of England (37p/pint.)

      —  £100/ barrel difference on Castlemaine for an Enterprise tenant in the South East of England (35p/pint.)

      It should also be remembered that pubcos pay far less than the open market price due to their purchasing power which means they can attract bulk buying discounts.

      5.2  Under the Beer Orders brewers were required to publish the wholesale "list" prices that they charged to their tenants. Unfortunately pubcos are not bound by a similar requirement.

      5.3  Two other factors must be taken into account:

      —  Firstly, AWP income which most leases specify must be shared 50:50 with the landlord, and which Deutsche assess as being worth £4,800 per annum to each party. One FSB member reports that his new lease requires him to have at least one AWP even though he does not have room for it.

      —  Secondly, agreements specify varying degrees of tie on the supply of non-beer products. FSB members report that pubcos seek to tie for more and more purchases such as cider, Flavoured Alcoholic Beverages (alcopops), spirits, and soft drinks. Over half of the respondents to the 2001 FSB survey said that they were tied for all spirits purchases. Again this is in contrast to purchasing contracts which existed with national brewers under the terms of the Beer Orders. We have estimated this factor as costing the average tenant some £2,000 per annum. This figure can be expected to grow in line with the current trend for an increasing percentage of pub revenues to come from non-beer products, as consumers demand more innovation, variety and choice.

      5.4  As discussed above under "The Pubco Business Model", the offset to the cost of being tied is in a lower than market rent. Indeed, under EU competition law contracts containing an exclusive purchasing arrangement, such as the tie, have only ever been permitted if such a "countervailing benefit" exists.

      5.5  In the Deutsche model the average rental is included at 11.9% of the sales of the pub. Although we are aware of Enterprise tenants paying up to 28% of turnover, we are happy to accept the Deutsche model figure for the purposes of this submission. We contend that the average free of tie rent is about 15% of sales, and this is supported by conversations with industry commentators. Thus, the average lessee benefits to the extent of £6,200 per annum by way of rent "subsidy" (15% minus 11.9% multiplied by £200,000 trunover.) This compares to the penalty of higher beer and other drink prices, plus the loss of 50% of AWP income thus:

Higher beer prices£14,700
Higher non-beer prices£2,000
Loss of AWP income£4,800
Less Lower rent£6,200
Net deficit to lessee£15,300

  5.6  Pubcos may argue that the deficit is compensated by other commercial offers which they make available to lessees. This could include business advice and group procurement terms on, for example, insurance. We would question the value of such services. Feedback from FSB members suggests that their leases are fully repairing and fully insuring, that they do not have regular meetings with their Business Development Managers, that they have to pay for training (albeit sometimes at cost) and that the standard of marketing and training is poor. Overall they would much prefer to forego these commercial offers and receive cash discounts in their place.

  5.7  We conclude that pubco leases and terms are such that high prices paid by tenants are NOT compensated by lower rents.

  5.8  No wonder then that many members comment on the difficulty they face in competing with other local "on trade" outlets. Often the retail prices offered by local branches of large chains (not only on beer, but also on faster growing lines) are so low that tenants cannot compete with them. The position is exacerbated in that price increases announced by the national brewers are passed on in full to tenants, who are then confronted by the choice of a margin squeeze or a loss in sales to more competitively priced outlets.

    —  My nearest competitor is charging 90p less for a pint on some products."—Enterprise tenant in South East England.

    —  It (the high prices charged by a pubco) makes it very difficult to compete in such an overcrowded marketplace. We are forced either to drive up prices beyond our customers' wallets or keep prices down and struggle to break even."—West Country tenant of Enterprise.

6.  THE BASIS ON WHICH RENTS ARE SET AND INCREASED

  6.1  If the rising cost of beer works against the tenant, so too do the arrangements for rent increases.

  6.2  As described above, rents typically rise annually by the general rate of inflation. Changes in the circumstances or the fortunes of the pub are not part of this process.

  6.3  Tenants complain that when it then comes to the time for a full review of the rent, the process is neither transparent nor subject to negotiation.

  6.4  An Enterprise tenant in South East England was advised by his accountant to ask for a written explanation of how his rent was calculated. He was refused both a written explanation or even a breakdown of the possible factors which could influence rent levels. He concluded "rent is charged at whatever rate the pubcos feel they can get away with, with no prescribed formula or framework for calculation."

  6.5  Another FSB member argues:

    "The basis of setting rent seems to be a black art which seems to be dominated by `models' when there are few pubs that can be compared directly. The prospect of a rent reduction never seems to be available and there is no visibility of what consideration is given to massive increases in outgoings like wages, utility bills and rates."

  6.6  We contend that the rent review process disregards realistic wage and operating costs such as the Working Time Directive, National Minimum Wage, changes to premises required by the Disability Discrimination Act, planned maintenance, cellar requirements, administration, and the costs of licenses for entertainment. The Chief Executive of Mitchells and Butlers is on the record as saying that the operating costs for his managed estate increased by over £10 million per year between 2000 and 2002 as a direct result of government regulation. In the tied pub estates, it is the lessees who have born the brunt of the cost of compliance and this element has not been adequately factored into the rent review process.

  6.7  Some licensees are subject to Upward Only Rent Review clauses. Such clauses are not restricted to the tenanted pub sector but are particularly inappropriate to the trade because premises have a single user specified, because rent is the key countervailing benefit justifying the tie and because overall trade is in decline in volume.

  6.8  Even where leases do not include such clauses, the pubco expects to see an increase in line with any increase in the profits / turnover of the pub, but the incidence of a reduction or standstill in rent is all too rare. Indeed data provided by Punch in the presentation of 2004 interim results (available on the Company's website), shows that just 15% of all reviews in 2002-03 and 2003-04 resulted in no increase or a decrease. Further, Goldman Sachs, in a note on Punch Taverns dated 23 March 2004, state that the average rental uplift at five-year review in 2003 was 13.5%.

  6.9  It is our opinion that rent should be based on profits not turnover (or arbitrary comparisons with other pubs in the vicinity.) Two pubs may have the same turnover but vastly different profits.

  6.10  A further important consideration is the question of the ethical marketing of leases, and whether or not pubcos may over-state partnership benefits in their marketing of leases. Whilst the low risk and low capital retail business entry model attracts a steady and competitive stream of applicants for pub leases, it is for consideration whether they are adequately coached to take independent financial, business, and legal advice in order to verify the stated partnership benefits in lease agreements and the full business implications before entering into contract.

7.  MARKET ACCESS

  7.1  In his 2000 review of the Beer Orders the DGFT remarked, "I believe that the level of competition in the industry could be better, in particular, the level of access in the market for competing suppliers at all levels of distribution."

  We can but agree. This market failure affects our members as both suppliers to the pubcos, and customers of them.

  7.2  Pubcos tend to negotiate large national contracts with beer and other suppliers, leaving little or no scope for the local entrepreneur to deal with the local pub, thus effectively barring market access for them.

  7.3  As an example, we cite a family business in the West Country with six employees supplying and maintaining gaming equipment to pubs and clubs. Such would-be suppliers must be nominated by the pubco before a tenant may use them. The company in question sought to become nominated, but found the pubco terms too onerous. Moreover they were forced to sign a confidentiality agreement preventing disclosure of these terms. The effect of being excluded from such a large part of the market is very damaging. The proprietor quotes several examples where business has been lost overnight, against the wishes of the pub tenant, when a pub has been taken over by a pubco.

    "As a family concern the arbitrary loss of business on this scale is extremely damaging to us as a company, and as individuals".

  7.4  Tenants of pubcos also suffer as a result of this phenomenon. They are denied access to what may be more advantageous contracts. An important case in point is locally-brewed beer. In general our members report that pubcos now supply a reasonable range of national beers. However, access to a "guest beer" is invariably denied, particularly within newer agreements such as the Punch "Growth Lease". This can represent a major missed opportunity for the tenant, not only to meet customer demand for a local brew, but also to purchase at least one beer at a competitive price.

  7.5  An FSB member who owns and runs a small brewery in the East of England describes the difficulty of gaining a listing from pubcos for the company's beers. The price demanded makes any sale uneconomic, so they are forced to rely on sales to a diminishing number of free houses. The company was founded 10 years ago, and sales grew for 5 years but have since languished as pubcos extended their grip on the market.

  7.6  There is also the case of independent wholesalers to be considered. In 2000 the DGFT reported that:

    "The Beer Orders do not appear to have been effective in improving the position of independent wholesalers . . .(their) share of the market has altered little since 1989."

  7.7  Prior to the Beer Orders, it was the power of national brewers that excluded wholesalers from the market, now it is the pubcos. This is to the detriment of tenants too who would welcome the flexibility to have greater access to the portfolio of strong brands available from wholesalers which would enable them to appeal to consumers' changing tastes.

  7.8  Another FSB member who is an independent wholesaler complains of the confusion he faces as to which pubs are allowed to trade with him, with threat of legal action from pubcos hanging over him if he gets it wrong. It is for consideration whether the terms of business demanded of local wholesalers by pubcos, and in particular the discounts demanded of them, amount in effect to a refusal to trade.

8.  THE DISENCHANTED TENANT

  8.1  Pubcos argue that their business model provides a low cost route into the trade for entrepreneurs and that they have scores of people lining up to become tenants.

  8.2  An FSB member who is an accountant with licensee clients reflects: "there is an endless supply of people who dream of running a pub, have £20,000 available from redundancy etc, but who don't have a clue about running a small business and don't expect pubcos to rip them off."

  8.3  Unfortunately many licensees are not so enthusiastic once they have some experience of the relationship between pubco and tenant. The FSB has a file of correspondence from members expressing discontent with one aspect or another of the relationship with their pubco. A report by the Investment Bank Dresdner Kleinwort Wassertein (DKW) "Tenanted and Managed Pubs" (March 2003) also states that Punch and Enterprise recognise that across their whole estates a tenant is at a pub for an average of only three years.

  8.4  Separate evidence of such disenchantment comes from a timely report in The Morning Advertiser, a trade paper, on 28 May 2004. The report presents the findings of a survey carried out in April 2004 in which 624 tenants participated. Some 64% of respondents were tenants of Enterprise or Punch (or of companies now owned by them).

  8.5  Asked whether they would take out another lease with their current landlord, the response was:


Total %
Enterprise %
Punch %

Definitely
13
6
7
Probably
17
11
14
Possibly
23
23
17
Probably not
21
26
25
Definitely not
24
34
36


  (Columns may not add up to 100 due to rounding.)

  8.6  Thus over 60% of Enterprise and Punch tenants would be unlikely to take out another lease. This can only be seen as a very poor level of customer satisfaction.

  8.7  Tenants of Enterprise and Punch have a low opinion of the fairness of their landlord as business partner, with 55% assessing their degree of fairness as "poor" or "very poor".

  8.8  The survey reveals disquiet at the experience of the process of drawing up the contract and reaching agreement with their landlord. This is an issue across the industry, and not one confined to Enterprise or Punch. Over 30% of respondents rated their landlord as "poor" or "very poor" at disclosing all relevant information and over 40% said their landlord had been "poor" or "very poor" as regards flexibility in drawing up the contract. Scores for the landlord's clarity in specifying what investment he would make were even worse.

  8.9  Confusion at the outset of a business relationship is in no one's interest. Nor is the worrying fact that 41% of respondents failed to take legal advice at this crucial time.

  8.10  Although tenants must share a degree of culpability where they fail to seek legal advice, this cannot detract from the fact that the survey represents an indictment of the unhappy relationship which many tenants have experienced with their pubco landlords.

9.  WHAT CAN BE DONE?

  9.1  The FSB does not seek the immediate ending of the tie. We recognise that, in the right circumstances, it can form part of a good business partnership. Local breweries operate tied pubs as an essential part of their business model. The tie guarantees distribution for the output of the brewery, and prices to tenants reflect this. They could not otherwise compete with national brewers. Local brewers, however, have a reputation for fairness in their dealings with tenants. Complaints of unequal partnership are relatively few.

  9.2  This stands in contrast to the situation that has developed with large pubcos. Here the tie is far from benign. For pubcos we propose an end to the compulsory tie so that tenants are offered a choice of a free of tie or tied lease. The free of tie lease would include an open market rent, but without purchasing restrictions being placed on any item, including AWP operations. A variation of this might be an option for a lessee to switch to a franchise agreement that calculated the sharing of upside to business growth between the pubco and the lessee/franchisee via a franchise fee calculated as a percentage of turnover.

  9.3  Where the tenant is given the choice of a free of tie lease it will be important to ensure that excess prices for beer are not simply added back in rent increases on review. There may be a role for the Office of Fair Trading in monitoring pubco behaviour in this regard.

  9.4  For those tenants opting for a tied lease, the existing balance of risk/reward must be shifted back toward the tenant so as to redress what we term "the unequal partnership". Firstly the tie should be loosened. We recommend that pubco tenants be allowed to purchase one guest beer, either directly from the brewer or from a wholesaler.

  9.5  Taken together these two proposals will not only enhance the tenant's income, but will also go some way towards redressing the issue of market access.

  9.6  Within tied leases there is an issue with the way in which rents are set and reviewed. Firstly, we propose the cessation of the practice of upward only rent reviews in the tenanted pub sector.

  9.7  The way in which rents are increased annually in line with inflation, shifting any risk from changing trading circumstances entirely to the tenant, needs redress. We propose that annual indexed rent increases be stopped.

  9.8  We also propose that there be greater transparency in the rent review process. The process should place greater emphasis on realistic wage and operating costs, and on profits rather than turnover.

  9.9  Changes to the rent review process should accompany any changes to the operation of the tie. If they do not there is a danger that excessive margins on the wholesaling of beer will be transferred to the rent.

  9.10  Finally, no commercial partnership can flourish on the basis of legal conditions alone. There must be some degree of goodwill. Regrettably this does not exist in the relationship between pubcos and tenants to the degree that it should. Quoting from a letter from an FSB member from the Midlands,

    "Get out from behind your legal comfort zone and build relationships with lessees based on trust, promises kept, and moral fibre."

  9.11  We believe that there is scope for a Code of Conduct for Pub Companies. Pubcos should propose a blueprint for this but such a code of practice should include:

    —  The procedure for resolving disputes,

    —  The right to have rent reviews decided by the courts irrespective of whether there are provisions for such reviews to be conducted by an arbiter,

    —  A commitment to transparency in lease negotiations, rent reviews, and in wholesale "list" prices charged to tenants,

    —  A mechanism by which prospective licensees can compare standard terms and conditions of the various leases offered by pubcos,

    —  The specification of advice and support to be supplied by the pubco,

    —  An educational scheme for potential licensees arranged by Learning and Skills Councils / Business Links with a requirement for pubcos to inform potential licensees of its existence.

David Bishop

Deputy Head of Parliamentary Affairs

2 June 2004





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 14 March 2005