Select Committee on Trade and Industry Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 20-39)

ENERGYWATCH AND FUEL POVERTY ADVISORY GROUP

25 JANUARY 2005

  Q20 Sir Robert Smith: Therefore, would Ofgem be in a position to understand the world's investment climate and needs, to encourage further exploration and production of the oil and the wet gas?

  Mr Asher: They do have, as a result of the recent Energy Act, a broader remit in some of these areas, but we are not saying they should become the regulator of all offshore licences. There is a separate regime for that. They should, however, have adequate tools to do the job that the statute gives them, and clearly they have not. Look at their own report and you will see at least three occasions where they point to inadequacy of their tools.

  Q21 Chairman: Is it not the case that Ofgem's responsibilities extend to the beach and no further as far as economic regulation, the promotion of competition, protection of the consumer and the like? The problem is that there has never been a recognition that there was a dysfunctional market operating offshore and that this may or may not be evidence of dysfunctionality in that respect. No-one has ever suggested, as I understand it, that the DTI has an economic regulatory role in respect of pricing in the North Sea. It does have what is perhaps a conflicting responsibility for the promotion of exploitation and the regulation of exploitation. While that does relate to price, from their point of view it has been more about the facilitation of this exploration. I am not quite sure you are accurate in what you are saying about the relative powers of either the government department or, for that matter, the existing economic regulator. Is it not the case that we have not really thought through what may be a new market situation?

  Mr Asher: That is my very point, Mr Chairman, about recognising that we are an integral part of a European market. The prime regulator is very limited in its jurisdiction, whether it is to the watermark or not. The reality is that, to understand properly a market, to be able to understand the structure, conduct and performance of that market, you need to have an ability to obtain information, an ability to understand the things that drive that market. Ofgem, because of its concurrent jurisdiction under the Enterprise Act, has some powers that go to Europe and some that do not. I think there are discontinuities there. Perhaps now that we are net importer, it is time that we looked at those regulatory powers to make sure they are the right ones, not simply to pour jurisdiction on, but to make sure they are able to do the job that their statute requires them to do. At the moment the evidence is it does not.

  Q22 Sir Robert Smith: When we are talking about Europe, we mean the Europe Union in terms of regulations.

  Mr Asher: Yes.

  Q23 Sir Robert Smith: But of course the consequences of what the Government are doing with their strategy of standing back and letting the market drive things, is that the market has sent signals to suppliers and one of the big suppliers that is coming in is Norway, which of course is not part of the EU. So how would you see that supplier being regulated?

  Mr Asher: I think in the same way that the UK has negotiated information arrangements so far with Norway. I cannot think of any reason that willing buyers and willing sellers should not facilitate the best market arrangements. But when you talk about market signals, the signals that Lord Browne gives is of a market that is not working so that our health system and our education system and others are paying millions and millions unnecessarily for markets that are not working properly.

  Q24 Chairman: By your own admission, these other bodies are taking a risk because they have gone for interruptible contracts. If you go for interruptible contracts, then the interruption could well happen or you would not be getting the price advantage.

  Mr Asher: I do not think there is anything wrong with the availability of interruptible contracts. They are a good market mechanism. The problem is where you have people who are constrained, such as any government buyer of gas. They are quite limited as to what sort of contracts they can enter for supply and they are often disadvantaged. Primarily though—and this was my earlier point about the one-sided information—the producers know it all; the buyers know very little.

  Q25 Chairman: Mr Lehmann, in a previous incarnation you were involved in the gas business yourself. From your personal experience, do you think that the new provisions, which are being suggested as more likely to provide information about gas flows, go far enough? Do you think the information is going to be sufficiently helpful to enable proper market analysis and informed buying by wholesale purchasers?

  Mr Lehmann: I am answering that personally, not for the fuel poverty Advisory Group.

  Q26 Chairman: I am asking you because I know this was your trade in days gone by.

  Mr Lehmann: I agree with Alan on that point. I am not blaming the producers for anything that is happening, but the information flows clearly are not as good as electricity, and they should be improved to make the market work better. My own view is that even if it was working somewhat better, prices would be high, and there would be these very big profits—which is not their fault, but it is not just the hospitals that are losing out: the fuel-poor and low-income customers and all other customers are losing. Our view is that there are very large extra sums of money that are genuine windfalls: the companies have not had to do anything more to get this money. The very same prices rises that are bringing those extra profits to them are harming individual customers. We would like to see some of those profits recycled back into extra fuel poverty programmes.

  Q27 Linda Perham: My questions are to the fuel poverty Advisory Group. The Government acknowledge that there are about 200,000 people who will fall into fuel poverty as a result of the recent price rises. I think your estimate is that if prices go up by 10%, then the numbers double to 400,000. What do you think is the best way of helping those people? Is it raising the level of benefits? Or targeting energy efficiency measures? Or putting more money into energy efficiency? Is it any of those or others?

  Mr Lehmann: Two things. I will cover one and go to Gill for the other one. First, as we have said, the Government has done a great deal to expand the fuel poverty programmes, to increase the energy efficiency of the homes of low-income customers. Given the price rises, we think more is needed to try to make sure that we meet the fuel poverty target, and some of that should come from government sources and some, as we have said, from the profits that the oil and gas producers are making. That is one thing: expand the fuel poverty programmes. The other thing, which Gill will pick up on, is to make sure that low-income customers are getting the best possible prices of those available in the market. Would you like to pick up on that, Gill?

   Ms Owen: Yes. Obviously a lot of the low-income customers are paying by expensive methods. They are paying on pre-payment meters. One of our concerns is how we can make sure we can get down the prices for those people who are paying the highest prices. Here, I think we would like to see more action by Ofgem, to look at the ways in which we could get better forms of metering to bring down those prices, so they have more sustainable solutions, both of energy efficiency and better forms of pricing that will help people pay less in the future. We cannot predict the way that prices will go in the future—they may go up, they may go down—but the best thing is if we can insulate those who are in the worst situation from those problems, by energy efficiency and by the methods of payment that they have.

  Q28 Linda Perham: We are bombarded with suggestions from energy ministers, Ofgem and energywatch that we should switch energy suppliers to save money. This has not been enough to convince low-income groups. Given what you have said about best possible prices, what about low-income groups switching suppliers? If they do switch, I think they come off the priority service register. Is it really a good thing to encourage low-income customers to switch suppliers? Does that do them any good in getting the best possible price?

  Ms Owen: Obviously people can save by switching. The pre-payment customers can save by switching, but not as much as the direct-debit customers by switching, although things have improved a bit in that area. Obviously there are issues about having to come off one priority service register and then get on another one. It is complicated, this process, so it is not the only solution just to say switch is the message we would want to give.

  Mr Lehmann: Part of it but not the only one. I think we would still encourage people to switch if they can save money, and obviously there is a point that energywatch make a lot—rightly—that if the energy companies know that customers are going to switch if their prices are higher, that will act as a discipline on them and make them think twice about raising their prices. It helps to make the market work.

  Q29 Linda Perham: I am not sure if you cover this, but another question we had is about the three examples you mentioned in your memorandum, possible programmes to help the customers most affected by energy price rises. There has been criticism of the effectiveness, particularly of the targeting of those programmes. What could the Government do about that?

  Mr Lehmann: I think it is fair to say those programmes generally have been very good. They have improved the energy efficiency of the homes of low-income customers, so, in that sense, they have been good. Secondly, there have been some changes—announced at the end of last year by the Government—to improve the targeting of Warm Front which will be very helpful. Thirdly, while we agree to some extent with the criticisms, we think they have been a bit overdone. Let's give you an example. If the programmes had been much more heavily focused on the people who were in fuel poverty a year ago, we might have gone along to somebody and said, "You are not in fuel poverty, therefore we will not insulate your home," and those same people might now be in fuel poverty because of the price rises. So it is a bit of a moving target. We think the scheme is generally pretty good. There have been improvements and we think basically this should be expanded further.

  Q30 Mr Clapham: Mr Lehmann, could I pick you up on your reply to the Chairman about social responsibility and how you thought that some of the companies that are making profits may redistribute them, shall we say, to help to tackle fuel poverty. Given that some of the companies do not have supply arms, how do you feel this could be done in a fair way that would encourage companies to come on board?

  Mr Lehmann: I believe that is a very helpful summary of our views on it, because the companies which do have supply arms are doing a lot, partly because they have to and partly because they have actually taken ownership. If you talk to their chief executives, they have taken ownership of the fuel poverty problem, which they did not have some years ago. The people who produce oil and gas in the North Sea are obviously further from customers and do not feel that same ownership but we think that the money should be recycled. There are basically two ways that it could be done. One, UKOOA, the trade association, or individual companies could voluntarily give some money to fuel poverty programmes—and we have suggested some ways in which that could be done—and Neighbourhood Energy Action is trying to talk to some of them to encourage them to do that work with them on that. If the companies do not do that, then we think there should be a tax to recycle some of that money. But we hope very much they will do it. It would be a much better solution all round.

  Q31 Mr Clapham: Given that you have put some ideas to try to encourage the companies, what has been their response so far?

  Mr Lehmann: One or two have shown some interest, but I think the general problem is that those who are interested do not want to do it on their own and they cannot necessarily bring everyone along. But no doubt they will tell you about it. There is one other source of money, as well—much less important. As you know, National Grid Transco have sold some of their distribution companies and made a very substantial gain from that—which is absolutely fine, nobody has done anything wrong there, and they have been very supportive generally on fuel poverty. But, again, here is another possible source of money, to get a little bit of that money back into fuel poverty programmes.

  Q32 Mr Clapham: Given that the Government's figures suggest that for every 1% increase in income there are about 40,000 families lifted out of fuel poverty—and of course that situation is under threat as a result of gas prices—is there a role for greater liaison with some of the social services departments to work on that very vulnerable group of people?

  Mr Lehmann: Absolutely. We are working with them, and we are making a bit of progress—not as quickly as we would like. The Department for Work and Pensions are trying to persuade people to take up their benefits and the energy and energy efficiency companies are trying to get them to take advantage of these grants, so there is clear scope for us working together. They are showing some interest. It is hard work, but they are beginning to show some interest, and any encouragement you could give them would be helpful. We have had much more difficulty with the Department of Health centrally. Some of the local health staff are very good but we have not had any encouragement yet from the Department of Health centrally, even though cold homes are bad for health. We are working on that.

  Q33 Sir Robert Smith: Keep working! I had a private member's bill many years ago trying to encourage the Department of Health of the benefits of fuel efficiency. You have raised the idea of a windfall tax to try to get more money. Obviously, even without a windfall tax, the Chancellor is already better off than he planned to be. Do you think, as a start, he should be looking to make use of his own windfall?

  Mr Lehmann: Yes. To be fair, there was a very substantial increase in the funds available for fuel poverty in the last spending round, which we had not expected in a very tight spending round. So he has done part of his bit, but, yes, we think it should be a matched thing: the companies should give something and the Treasury should give something. Match it and that will help a great deal.

  Q34 Mr Clapham: Do you understand the worry of a windfall tax? If you were an investor, sitting in Calgary deciding where to go with your next investment to find oil and gas, and you have a choice of coming to the North Sea, where you hear talk of a windfall tax, and you have seen, a couple of years back, a surprise tax that frightened the market, do you think you might decide to go elsewhere, where you might see more stability for investment, or to come here, where it is an expensive operating environment and a mature province where reserves are beginning to be difficult to find?

  Mr Lehmann: Clearly a tough balance, and somebody has to weigh those risks, but other countries are obviously thinking of similar things. We are not alone. There are many advantages of investing here, but a key point is that, when the companies make investment decisions, they are assuming much lower oil prices than the current ones. They are usually using $30 or less, sometimes $25—and, again, no doubt you will be able to ask them. So they are investing at those levels and they do not expect the profits above that. So, if some of them are removed, then I do not think that would have a major impact. But you have to weigh them up.

  Q35 Sir Robert Smith: If the price were to fall, do you think the Government should step in with a subsidy to the industry to cover the fact that the price is below what they expected?

  Mr Lehmann: No. The normal swings and roundabouts one lives with, and the companies have benefited from relatively high prices in the past at times. It is only when they get exceptionally high, as they have done now, with exceptional amounts of money flowing in, that we think there is a case.

  Q36 Sir Robert Smith: How do you, as an investor, factor into your investment decision windfall taxes? Surely, as an investor, you have a lot of reasons—the price going up and down, the geology being difficult, the hostility of the North Sea and lots of other things—and if the Government then throws in an unstable fiscal regime, does that not say, "Go and look elsewhere where you might find life easier, bigger reserves and long-term returns"?

  Ms Owen: But surely the nature of a windfall tax is that it is not factored in, because it is a windfall and therefore it is not something which is going to happen regularly. I think that is the point. It is not going to happen with the ups and downs of the market generally. There are precedents for this in other countries. The United States did this in the '70s and a lot of the money there was spent on insulation programmes for low-income households. It is not something that is going to happen, as Peter Lehmann said, with every up and down of the market.

  Q37 Sir Robert Smith: But as the Government have said, their whole energy strategy is designed in not interfering in the market, except in extreme circumstances, such as the last resort of potential risk of safety. Surely consumers have benefited from that market keeping prices lower in the times when the market is really operating, and therefore the market going up is now saying to the Norwegians, "Bring gas into Britain" and so that other people build energy plants and so on. It is sending signals and that is how the market is designed to work. If the Treasury then keep stepping in and out at random and without warning . . .

  Mr Lehmann: I would just make one quick point. Obviously one has to make a judgment about the relative risks and advantages, but in other markets these profits would not be made because immediately there would be new entry. That does not happen in the oil and gas industry, so they have an extra advantage. If part of that is taken away—only part of it, I am not suggesting taking all of it—they are not at any disadvantage compared with other industries.

  Q38 Sir Robert Smith: Where has this pipe from Norway come from, if it is not a new entry?

  Mr Lehmann: There is no new entry into exploration and production in the North Sea very easily. If these profits are made, you do not get people coming in and competing it away.

  Q39 Sir Robert Smith: Then why is there more drilling now that the price is going up?

  Mr Lehmann: Fine, there is some more, but it takes quite a while, which it does not in other industries. We may not agree on this. It is a judgment. I think the main point we would make is that the fuel poverty targets will not be met unless the programmes are expanded. It is not quite clear that it is going to come from the public sector, therefore we have to be creative in finding new sources and we have to weigh the advantages against the risks.

  Mr Asher: Might I add one sentence on that market structure. The implicit deal with governments, not just in the UK, is that governments will provide a framework that provides for contestability and innovation on the supply side through competition policy and that the market will work well. Sadly, over the last 15 years we have seen a great concentration on the production side. The mergers in the oil and gas companies have led to only four companies having more than 50% of gas reserves for the UK, and then in the UK we have had a very permissive regime for allowing vertical re-integration, so that now all of the suppliers have hedged their generation, and they are increasingly expanding into gas, so that the market is functioning less well by the day.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 1 June 2005