Select Committee on Trade and Industry Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 32-39)

QINETIQ GROUP PLC

20 JANUARY 2004

  Q32 Chairman: Good morning, Sir John and Dr Mears. We have been looking at evidence from the World Economic Forum called competitiveness ratings and we get the impression that Britain is falling behind. On the other hand, you look at Porter and we may not be quite as bad. So it may be it just depends on to whom you look for comfort. Your submission incorporates the World Economic Forum ratings and you say that this drop in the ratings may be due to the R&D investment gap between the UK and other countries. Is this gap getting worse? It seems that there are always calls for greater levels of investment. We know about the issue. Are we addressing it or is it getting worse?

  Sir John Chisholm: The World Economic Forum paper itself said that the R&D gap is one of the issues leading to our relative performance. You mentioned that there are a number of different surveys of a similar sort—the OECD does its own as well—and what is clear is that we are not, if you like, in the Finland league. There are examples of nations who have done really rather well over the last 10 or 15 years; I do not think we have done especially poorly but we have not done as well as that. We certainly have not succeeded in the way the United States has done of creating what is apparently a sustainable, vibrant, world-leading economy. So whichever way you look at it there is plenty for us to learn about and, in amongst the package of things which one needs to worry about, the continuing under-performance, particularly in the industrial foreign league, is clearly one of the issues.

  Dr Mears: On Michael Porter, I suppose he is slightly more optimistic than the negative views you get if you read the DTI economic papers, which you can get rather depressed about. However, Michael Porter does make the point that OK, the UK has pulled its socks up in the last two decades but we do now face a pretty major change in what is going to make us competitive. We were competitive previously because we did tend to have low wage rates and freedom from regulation. Now we do have to be competitive based on added value and innovation. His story is not that positive. He says, "Don't get depressed, but nevertheless the UK has got a pretty serious challenge".

  Q33 Richard Burden: In the last three years there has been the introduction of tax credits for R&D investment to encourage that. Originally that was for SMEs but there was quite a big demand for that to be extended and, obviously, it has been to large businesses. How effective do you think they are?

  Sir John Chisholm: They are undoubtedly helpful; there is no question about that. They could be more helpful, for instance, if one looked at the rules more closely. Particularly, you will see in the paper we submitted that we said that knowledge-networking is highly important in innovation. Extending the tax credits to this element more strongly would be very helpful. They are a bit restrictive on that front. On their own they will not solve the whole problem. There are nations—Finland for instance—which do not have significant tax credits (in fact the reverse) who have done extraordinarily well over the same period. Equally, for international companies making decisions as to where to invest, tax credits are one of the things that they take account of. So tax credits are helpful.

  Q34 Richard Burden: What more do you think needs to be done? You mentioned Finland. Obviously they have a different cultural background and the rest of it, but what are they doing right that we are not?

  Sir John Chisholm: That is always the big question. One of the things which we point to in Finland is that the role of VTT in Finland—the national RTO—has been absolutely crucial in the creation of the technology base which they have exploited with phenomenal success through Nokia and others. The national understanding of what they could invest in, and invest in not just the discovery (because there is not a lot to discover in mobile phones) but actually the innovation process which gets you to marketable products, is a key part of that success.

  Q35 Richard Burden: What role do you think RDAs have in encouraging investment? In your own case, you are part of the central technology belt that Advantage West Midlands have been promoting, and they are quite bullish about the relationship of their technology corridors and their cluster strategies and so on. Do you feel that actually does have an impact in helping network things to the extent that it will actually lead to an increase in investment of the kind that you think will be needed in the West Midlands?

  Sir John Chisholm: RDAs can undoubtedly be extraordinarily helpful in knowledge networking in exactly the way we have instanced in our paper. If you look for international comparators, there is no doubt that after the Second World War one of the   things Germany did very well was the regionalisation of technology; the Fraunhofer Institutes, which were sponsored by the individual Länders, did an extraordinarily good job at capturing the innovation potential of the regions, drawing companies together with the research centres and creating a surviving economic base from a total mess. So the business of pulling together a regional cluster is clearly extraordinarily helpful in terms of economic growth. In this country RDAs seem to us to have quite an important role to play.

  Dr Mears: One of the important differentiators in RDAs is to have enough technical knowledge. One NorthEast has created five centres of excellence, and this is because in order to do the coupling of research from university into industry it needs to have people with the technical knowledge to do the bridging. That is what Fraunhofer has got; the Fraunhofer Gesellschaft has 57 scientific institutes with internal scientists and they also have associated researchers in universities. They are technically very expert and that expertise is important for doing the bridging between companies and universities. So, if the RDAs try to act as knowledge brokers without the real understanding to translate the information between universities and industry, and to help industry to understand how to use the information, then they will not be as effective.

  Q36 Linda Perham: In your submission you mentioned the concept of open innovation, saying that one of the weaknesses of the closed model is that internal research goes straight into products and services and you are not picking up on something that has already been invented—reinventing the wheel etc The Government and others are now actively encouraging more efficient means of technology and knowledge transfers. Do you think the open model is more effective and, if it is, what are the main factors that influence its effectiveness?

  Sir John Chisholm: I think, quite clearly, it is more effective. The classic, erstwhile linear model, where you poured money into discovery at the front end and, somehow, by a magic process, you got wealth out at the end is widely discredited. If you look at what has happened in industry, in the 1950s and 1960s many large companies had their own research organisations, they did their inventing in those research organisations and then pulled that through into a product. They do not do that anymore, for the reason that it has not proved successful. Companies now pay a lot more attention to widely networking and sourcing innovation from many different quarters. That has proven to be a more successful model. So success depends upon that open innovation infrastructure which enables companies to understand how best to develop and where best to develop their products. That seems to be a much more successful model.

  Q37 Linda Perham: Is there not a problem with intellectual property rights or patents, if you are going for that model?

  Dr Mears: The closed innovation model is based on protecting the knowledge, so it is linear, and it did work well in the middle of the last century—laboratories like Bell Labs and the invention of the transistor and those sorts of things. So that was a good model 50 years ago, but, as Sir John has said, industry has tended to move away from it because—and this is certainly true of the IT sector in the US—it is much better to just take technology from other suppliers and bring the right technology together (you could say stealing the knowledge but certainly accessing knowledge) to apply it; it is much more successful, certainly in the IT sector, than having your laboratories do research on the linear model. In some areas the linear model has worked quite well until recently. Pharmaceuticals is one area where it has worked well because it is a linear process: to discover a drug and go through all the problems of  getting it clinically trialled and proven. Even that  now is changing because, with genomics, pharmaceuticals is much more complex and has to involve bioinformatics; it is no longer just life science, it is becoming information science. So even pharmaceuticals is altering and you can see the drug companies are placing less emphasis on their own laboratories and more on picking up information via biotechnology, computational biology, and so forth. The closed model did work but, increasingly, things are much more complex now, and you need ways of managing that much more complex information and networking.

  Sir John Chisholm: In most economic activity having a licence is just as good as having a discovery. Provided you can access the knowledge through a licence and put that together with other knowledge you have got, you can create just as viable a product as making a discovery and locking everybody else out of it.

  Q38 Linda Perham: Losing the chance that the genius who discovers something will still get the credit for it.

  Sir John Chisholm: That is a very good point. We have in our national psyche the idea that wealth creation is to do with the lone inventor in a garret in Leeds who thinks of a brilliant idea and makes a fortune for the country. That does not work; we should absolutely delete that model from our mind. The world does not work that way anymore.

  Q39 Chairman: It has been suggested that the American model, as it were, has been in part at least successful due to the Bayh-Dole legislation where state funded research and the rewards from the exploitation of that are quite clearly laid down between the institution, the individual and the commercial partner who is brought in. Do you think that we need to formalise IP, as it were, reward allocation in the way that they have done in the US?

  Sir John Chisholm: I would say that it is not unhelpful but I certainly would not put that as the cornerstone in the US economic success in innovation.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 22 March 2005