Select Committee on Treasury Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Mr David Walton, Chief European Economist, Goldman Sachs

  From a macroeconomic perspective, the Pre-Budget Report (PBR) raises several issues, most of which relate to whether the Government's fiscal rules will be met.

1.  ARE THE TREASURY'S ECONOMIC GROWTH PROJECTIONS TOO OPTIMISTIC?

  The Treasury's main economic projections are unchanged from Budget 2004. GDP is forecast to grow by 3-3½% in 2005 and 2½-3% in 2006. These forecasts are based on a consideration of trend growth in the economy and the size of the output gap.

  Trend GDP Growth: Table A2 of the PBR (p 169) gives the Treasury's estimate of trend GDP growth. Between 2001 Q4 and 2006 Q4, it is put at 2¾% a year—down from just over 3% a year between 1997 H1 and 2001 Q3. Thereafter the economy is projected to grow by 2½% a year due to slower growth in the working age population.

  These estimates are very similar to those made by Kevin Daly of Goldman Sachs. Trend growth appears to have risen in recent years from 2½% to around 2¾% (see Chart 1). This is due partly to faster growth in the labour force but also to a better productivity performance. The level of productivity in the UK remains comfortably below that in the US and Euroland but the gap has been closing over the past decade (see Chart 2).

  Given the likely trends in employment and productivity from now on, trend GDP growth is likely to be maintained at around 2¾% over the next few years. Unfavourable demographics will then reduce growth after 2008. Table 1 gives Goldman Sachs' estimates of the contributions to GDP growth.

Table 1

GDP GROWTH PROJECTION OVER THE NEXT 10 YEARS
Average Annual Growth Rates1 1993-20032003-08 2008-03
GDP Growth equals changes in 2.7 2.82.5
Population0.30.4 0.4
plus Productivity (GDP/Hour)2.1 2.22.2
plus Labour Utilisation0.3 0.2-0.1
Of which Average Hours Worked-0.2 -0.2-0.2
Employment Rate0.40.2 0.4
Working Age Population0.1 0.2-0.3
1 Data are smoothed and may not sum to totals due to rounding.


  Output Gap: The Treasury believes that GDP is currently below potential by around 1%. The Treasury bases its view on three judgements: (i) average hours worked "remain below their projected trend levels"; the employment rate has also "grown at a little less than its projected trend"; "the lack of apparent inflationary pressure in the economy lends strong support to the current assessment of a negative output gap".

  Each of these judgements can be questioned.

    —  Average hours, which have been declining since the Industrial Revolution, are only slightly below a simple trend estimate (see Chart 3). According to the Labour Force Survey, the number of people who say they are in part-time work only because they cannot find full-time work is at a record low of 7½%. It is hard to argue, after two years of above-trend GDP growth, that the continuing decline in average hours is cyclical.

    —  On the employment rate, any difference with the "projected trend" can only be very small. In the year to 2004 Q3, employment rose by 0.16% of the workforce; the average rise over the previous five years was 0.21% a year.

    —  On inflation, a negative output gap would mean not just "a lack of apparent inflationary pressure" but its opposite—an increase in deflationary pressure. This is certainly not what is suggested by the sharp acceleration in core producer output prices and the gradual rise in non-bonus pay growth.

  Assessment: The Treasury's growth forecasts are reasonable if output is below trend. Given its view of the output gap, there would be a serious risk that inflation will continue to undershoot its target unless growth is as strong as the Treasury expects. We believe that the output gap is close to zero but the difference should not be exaggerated. On our view of the output gap and trend growth, GDP growth could average 2¾% a year over the next two years to be consistent with the inflation target—a cumulative increase in GDP of 5.5%. This is at the lower end of the Treasury's expected growth rate of 5.5-6.5%.

2.  ARE THE TREASURY'S PUBLIC BORROWING ESTIMATES TOO OPTIMISTIC?

  For 2004-05, the Treasury revised its estimate of the current budget from -£10.5 billion to -£12.5 billion. Of this £2 billion revision, £0.7 billion is due to discretionary changes announced in the PBR (mainly the £520 million added to the special reserve for the Iraq war). Central government receipts are forecast to grow by 7.2%, compared with growth of 6.3% in the first seven months of the financial year. Some pick-up in the growth rate of receipts is likely reflecting stronger corporation tax and petroleum revenue tax receipts, though we expect an undershoot of around £1 billion. Central government current spending is forecast to grow by 5.4% vs 6.6% so far this year—most of the slowdown in spending expected by the Treasury is within DEL, and quite likely to be seen. Thus we expect the deficit on the current budget to be around £1 billion larger than the Treasury expects. As in previous years, there is a good chance that investment spending will undershoot, leaving public sector net borrowing close to the £34.2 billion PBR forecast.

  For 2005-06, we are considerably more cautious about receipts. The Treasury is projecting a 0.9% rise in the share of tax receipts in GDP. Some rise is likely in response to the lagged effects of above trend growth and higher oil prices but the Treasury seems to be placing a lot of faith in the effectiveness of measures announced in the Budget to tackle tax avoidance. We expect an £8 billion shortfall in receipts and a similar shortfall in the current budget relative to the Treasury's expectations.

  Thereafter, we project a gradual clawing back in this receipts gap, mainly because the Treasury adopts a more cautious estimate of GDP growth in its public finance projections than Goldman Sachs.

3.  WILL THE FISCAL RULES BE MET?

  On the Treasury's definition of the economic cycle from 1999-2000 to 2005-06, we expect the golden rule to be missed by 0.05% of GDP a year on average. In the period from 2005-06 to 2009-10, we expect the golden rule to be missed by 0.12% of GDP a year on average. In both periods, the sustainable investment rule is met comfortably—net public sector debt peaks at 37.4% of GDP in 2007-08 and then begins to decline, below the 40% ceiling set by the Government (see Chart 4).

4.  DOES IT MATTER IF THE GOLDEN RULE IS BREACHED?

  If the golden rule is missed by a small margin in the current cycle, it would be of little economic consequence. Importantly, the UK would still have the soundest fiscal position of any country in the G7. As required by the Code for Fiscal Stability, the Chancellor would be required to explain the reason for the deviation. He could do this easily. He might, for instance, decide to treat the £5 billion or so of expenditure on the Iraq war as of a one-off nature, best dealt with outside the fiscal rules.

  Looking forward, there is a great deal of uncertainty about the path of tax receipts. One approach would be to raise taxes in Budget 2005, or reduce the growth of public spending, to be absolutely certain of hitting the golden rule over the next cycle. Another approach would be to see how things develop: fiscal drag could be sufficient to push the tax share up over the next cycle to hit the golden rule as the Treasury expects. A third approach would be to change the fiscal rules.

  There are strong arguments in favour of the wait-and-see approach. Net debt remains below 40% of GDP. The deficit on the current budget is narrowing. It peaked last year at 1.9% of GDP and is set to fall to 1.1% of GDP this year. A move back to balance is likely in coming years without government intervention. An analogy can be made with the actions of the Monetary Policy Committee. When inflation undershoots the target, the MPC does not cut interest rates aggressively to get inflation back to target as soon as possible. This would be too disruptive for the real economy. Instead it aims to get inflation back to target on a two year view. There are merits to a similar gradualist approach to eliminating current budget imbalances.

5.  ARE THE FISCAL RULES SACRED?

  The Code for Fiscal Stability is a lot more relaxed about the fiscal rules than many analysts are. It merely requires fiscal policy to be conducted in accordance with five principles:

    (i)  transparency (setting of objectives, implementation of policy, publication of accounts);

    (ii)  stability (process, impact on economy);

    (iii)  responsibility (management of public finances);

    (iv)  fairness (including between generations); and

    (v)  efficiency (policy design, managing public sector balance sheet).

  The Code allows the Government to change its fiscal objectives and operating rules provided that they abide with these five principles and the Government states the reasons for departing from the previous objectives and operating rules. This means that no new Government or new Chancellor is tied to the previous fiscal framework.

  In this regard, it is somewhat surprising—with a general election in sight—that all of the debate about the public finances, by Government and opposition alike, is conducted within the framework of the current fiscal rules. As the Treasury notes (on p 140 of its book "Reforming Britain's Economic and Financial Policy"), "it is for the elected Government of the day to choose and announce its fiscal policy objectives and rules, provided these are consistent with the fiscal principles set out in the Code."

  Once the election is out of the way, one of the first tasks for the Chancellor will be to set the fiscal framework for the new Parliament. This will involve a consideration of the appropriate levels of spending, taxation and borrowing in the next Parliament. There is nothing in the Code that requires the fiscal framework to be the same as in the last two Parliaments.

7 December 2004






 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 27 January 2005