Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1-19)

25 NOVEMBER 2004

PROFESSOR CHRISTOPHER PISSARIDES, PROFESSOR DAVID MILES, PROFESSOR ANDREW SCOTT AND MS BRIDGET ROSEWELL

Q1 Chairman: Good morning and welcome everyone. Please identify yourselves for the sake of the record.

Professor Pissarides: Chris Pissarides, from the London School of Economics.

Professor Miles: David Miles from Morgan Stanley and Imperial College.

Ms Rosewell: Bridget Rosewell from Volterra Consulting.

Professor Scott: Andrew Scott from the London Business School.

Q2 Chairman: Welcome and thank you for coming along. May I start with a question to Bridget. The MPC only narrowly avoided reaching the lower limit of its permitted range around the target in September and having to write an explanatory letter to the Chancellor. You warned us in May that you felt the Bank may be tightening policy unnecessarily. Do you think the below target inflation we have seen this year falls into the category of avoidable policy mistake or was it an acceptable error in uncertain circumstances?

Ms Rosewell: It sounds like a "Have you stopped beating your wife?" question! I think the borderline between what ought to be avoided and what cannot be avoided is obviously a very narrow one and hard to define. I think what we have been seeing is an international situation which has been particularly hard to call, and continues to be hard to call. Indeed it is that bit of the economic conjuncture I am most concerned about at the moment. We have seen a much stronger international position than probably we were expecting to see. In other words, in spite of the strength of the oil price generating economic weakness and the wobbles around the international political situation, nonetheless economic growth in world economies is very strong this year; and that produced an underlying position which is rather different. That might also then have created an economic position of the UK which was stronger, and where interest rate increases needed to be put in place to slow all that down. That is the bit which has not come through. Inflation has not come through on the back of that international position in a way people would have expected in the past. Indeed, if you read the Inflation Report there are some words around what has been happening to the exchange rate which say, "It might go this way and it might go that way". Again, that is one of the parts of the economy which is hardest to predict. I would say that the Bank continues to be very focussed on what it sees to be its difficulties in the domestic economy, and that has led it to be more cautious than probably it needed to be.

Q3 Chairman: On the issue of being too cautious, as we know it has typically undershot the inflation target in the past. We have had a memorandum from Roger Bootle which says, "With regard to the inflation outlook, I broadly concur with the Bank's profile, although I think, not for the first time, it is overdoing the inflation dangers". Does anyone feel strong on that?

Professor Miles: I would have said not. I can see certain risks to the upside, possibly even more than are emphasised in the Inflation Report where I think they argue the risks are somewhat asymmetric, that is that there are more risks to the downside than the upside. The one I would point to stems from potential movements in the exchange rate, where sterling is in the somewhat unusual position of being, on any plausible measure, substantially over-valued against the US dollar, at a time when the US dollar itself is coming under downward pressure and may indeed fall significantly in the near term. That might mean that sterling, in order not to become even more over-valued against the dollar, would need to go down with the dollar and that would have some inflationary impact and cost impact going forward. So this generates a risk of a pick- in inflation pressures in the future. Another risk is related to the puzzle as to why wage settlements have stayed at such unusually low levels. There really has not been much of an increase in wage settlements, even though measured unemployment has fallen to probably the lowest rate in 30-odd years. The Bank clearly is somewhat puzzled by why that has been the case. This is one of the reasons why inflation has turned out to be somewhat lower than they have been predicting for most of the last few years. They keep thinking that we have reached a position of tightness in the labour market such that wage pressures should increase, and they have not yet. That must be a source of uncertainty to the Bank and to most economists.

 Ms Rosewell: One of the issues in that is the way the Bank is looking at the domestic economy and one of the things I think it would be worth asking them is what their take is on what is happening to the output figures, the GDP figures. When you look at the Inflation Report I almost begin to wonder if they do not believe or think that the GDP figures are measuring what is going on in the economy. They are much more concerned about what they are calling the "resource take": because of the difficulty of measuring public sector output, let us look at what resources are being taken out of the economy. One of the possible things going on in the wages front is if the private sector is actually quite weak, and there is not much room for expansion there. While the public sector is doing something different, then you might see it as segmenting into 2 different parts of the economy. It is not clear to me how far they think that is really what is happening and it might be worth probing them on that.

Q4 Chairman: Do you think there will come a time when the MPC needs to cut rates to preserve credibility, given it is undershooting regularly, even if its forecasting models continue to forecast a rising trend in inflation at some point in the future? Is it a credibility issue here?

Professor Pissarides: No, I do not see a credibility issue. Like the 2 previous speakers, I do not think the Bank is being over-pessimistic. I do not agree with Roger Bootle's analysis in the memorandum he gave. I see the world economic situation improving unexpectedly. I see the money supply, which was not mentioned by my colleagues here before, growing faster than usual. I see oil prices and allied costs going up. The only part of the market which is subdued is the labour market. If the labour market were to pick up then inflation would take off. I do not see the need for the Bank to cut rates to improve its credibility. I do not think it would make good economic sense at the present time to cut rates. I think we are seeing many things taking place both in the world economy and the UK economy. We are not sure yet exactly what the implication will be for inflation, and the best thing to do is to wait and see. We will probably have to sit back and wait for 6 months before we know what is going on.

Professor Scott: I think on the issue of credibility it is actually quite healthy to have a conservative central bank which gets very twitchy about inflation. I think that is an inbuilt bias in the system. I think we have to be a bit careful that the changes in the inflation we are talking about, at least in the numbers, are really quite small. The UK has been staggeringly boring economic-wise in the last 3 or 4 years compared to everything else. We do tend to make a lot about small changes. If you look at things like a very strong world economy, oil prices, the GDP forecast and what that implies for the output gap, it is clear that the Bank can make a case for rising inflation. What is very interesting for me is a slight tension, because if you look at the main inflation forecast beyond 2006 they have increased their inflation forecast; but the Report is mainly about downside risks and why they do not need to do much to interest rates at the moment. If you look at their forecast on inflation, it does go above target after 2006. That forecast is based around market expectations of interest rates. The obvious implied assumption is that the Bank thinks rates are going to rise faster than the market is forecasting. Yet all it talks of are downside risks, and that is probably unnecessary. If they are talking about inflation rising I do not think they are showing an undue attention to it. If anything, their emphasis on the downside risk shows they are reluctant to raise rates.

Q5 Mr Beard: They are a long way from the target, are they not? 1.14.

Professor Scott: 0.6 is not a huge target, but monetary policy operates at such a lag that a rise above target in two years' time is something the Bank will need to be thinking about in setting interest rates over the next 6 months if they seriously believe that. Everything seems to suggest inaction rather than a rise in rates.

Q6 Norman Lamb: If I can turn to some internal management issues. This summer the MPC switched to using the implied interest rate in the money markets rather than constant interest rates in constructing their central projections for inflation and growth. Has that been a sensible development?

Professor Pissarides: I think so. Even before they did it, in this place we raised this point before that perhaps projections should be done on the basis of market expectations. Although the Bank sometimes leads market interest rates, it is very much a follower of market trends as well and it is the right way of doing it—to follow and try and push slightly in the direction you want policy to go. You do not want to go totally against market expectations, because then you are confusing markets and your policy is less effective and market participants do not know what you are going to do next. The policy of using the market expectation of the interest rate instead of the constant one is the sensible assumption to make. There is nothing magical about current rates that will continue in the future. The future course of interest rates will be determined to a large extent by market trends and partly by the direction you want to push policy. They are reasonably saying, "We do not want to indicate now where we will want to push policy in the future, but we might as well take account of market trends".

Q7 Norman Lamb: Do you all agree with that?

Ms Rosewell: Yes, absolutely.

Professor Miles: The timing, in a sense, has been rather good, in that at the moment it so happens that market expectations are pretty much that rates stay where they are. So there is not much difference in terms of the picture between unchanged interest rates and market expectation. How sensible the change is depends upon how sensible the market expectations are. If you were in a situation where market expectations, for some reason, generated a picture of projected inflation which took inflation very far away from 2% it would put the MPC, the Bank, in a rather strange position in showing the projections.

Q8 Norman Lamb: So expectations can be irrational in some respects?

Professor Miles: They could be. I think at the moment the situation is a comfortable one because the expectations seem sensible given what they then imply for the Bank's forecast. One could imagine a situation where that was not true.

Ms Rosewell: Equally, you could say that to produce a projection where you are saying that the interest rates will never change that would also not be true. That is also irrational because if the world changes a lot then the interest rates will also change. You have got a problem on either side of that.

Professor Miles: I absolutely agree with that.

Q9 Norman Lamb: They have also started to publish forecasts for three years out. Is that sensible given the margins of error that inevitably exist in that range of forecast?

Ms Rosewell: They are not much different from the range of error on two years out! If it is the case that it is still a two-year horizon on the speed with which interest rates work through to the economy—and, as Andrew was saying earlier, some material implies that it might be a bit shorter than that, or the Bank thinks it is shorter than that—then to have some idea whether you think you are going up to the end of that period is sensible and gives some context at any rate.

Q10 Norman Lamb: The House of Lords Select Committee on Economic Affairs has been rather critical of the Bank for lack of transparency, particularly in not publishing its economic model. It points to the Treasury as a model of transparency, making it available to the public, and the fact that it is used by the ITEM club etc. Do you think there is a strong case for the Bank publishing its economic model?

Professor Scott: I think one of the issues is the way the Bank does modelling. There is one core model but it does strongly emphasise that forecast issues are new issues and that you have to use a range of different models. I think the danger of just having one model that everyone sees as being the Bank model which generates the forecast would be quite misleading.

Q11 Norman Lamb: Is there any case for secrecy? Should it just be in the open?

Professor Scott: If you say, "These are all the models we produce. Here they are", that gets rid of any problems of hiding things. I think there is a danger people take the model far too seriously and far too automatically. In a way it is easier for the Treasury because the Treasury is not setting interest rates.

Ms Rosewell: The Treasury has always produced its model and allowed its basic model to be used for academic purposes and other purposes and, indeed, the ITEM club. However, the version of the model that is being used by the Treasury when they produce their own forecasts for their own purposes is almost certainly not precisely the same because it is always being worked on. All forecasts are a matter of judgment as much as they are a matter of the model, in any case. That is always the case. Indeed, the range that is being produced for the Bank's forecasts—if you remember we have had previous discussions with the Bank about how they do that, and in previous Inflation Reports they have reported on that—that is as much a matter of judging what the sort of the scenarios are that you might look at, as saying, "Here is some sort of confidence interval around that central forecast". There is an awful lot which goes into producing a forecast which is beyond what is in the actual model.

Q12 Norman Lamb: Are you broadly comfortable with the current situation that it is not published and so it cannot be tested independently?

Ms Rosewell: I think it would be nice for academic researchers if it were published. I do not think it would make any difference to our ability to judge the performance of the Bank of England in its monetary policy.

Q13 Norman Lamb: Would either of you take a different view?

Professor Pissarides: I am in favour of more transparency. I should also say in favour of the Bank that they do so show their model to the outside world—at least the underlying model. Less than a year ago they had a big one-day conference on the model they call BEQM, where they invited academics and other central bankers to comment on the outline and the detailed equations of the model. What is probably not a good idea to show outside, for the reasons just outlined, is the policy forecasting model, so that other people could put in the policy instruments and forecasts. In fact, reading the November Inflation Report is a very good example where they should not do it. There are many things there which they point out, and I am thinking in terms of the BEQM model which they have. On the basis of the BEQM I would have guessed that the economy was going to go in a certain direction, and yet the Inflation Report says, "We don't think the economy is going to go in that direction because of such and such a thing that has happened since August". You cannot put that into the model. There are arguments both for and against. But on balance I think more transparency is better.

Q14 Norman Lamb: Just quickly on errors in forecasting. The House of Lords Select Committee has been quite critical in its recent report on areas both in inflation forecasting, where it says, "The remarkable finding is that the MPC consistently over-predicted inflation until 2002, and after 2002 it consistently under-predicted inflation", and then it talks about errors in GDP growth rate forecasting. Its conclusion in that section is that, "Errors in forecasting remain a live issue"; they say that professional economists should be showing a greater interest, including why errors in forecasting persist. Is this a fair criticism or is it just the international context that is very hard to predict and they are doing the best they can?

Ms Rosewell: They are definitely doing the best then can. In fact, they are probably doing better than most of the rest of us.

Q15 Norman Lamb: So it is an unfair challenge?

Ms Rosewell: I think that is an unfair challenge. The difficulty with short or, indeed, medium-term forecasting is that essentially we do not have enough data for enough accuracy to be able to do this. When we have had another couple of hundred years of capitalism maybe we will know enough about the way that these economies operate that we will be able to do accurate forecasting—but I would not bet on it. These are complex situations with lots of interactions going on in them. With unpredictable events on top of that, and data which is measured with inaccuracy, and indeed gets revised all the time, quite often you will find that what looks like an error in forecasting turns out to be an error because the data has subsequently been changed. In a world where you never know where you are but only where you have been (and that with error), the fact that anybody gets this at all right most of the time or gets it in the right ballpark is a matter for congratulation. This is much, much more difficult than people think. Indeed, it is noticeable and I think the Bank should be congratulated on the way it has tried to make this clear on every occasion. It introduced the fan charts in the first place into the public debate; and tried to get us away from the idea we could know with certainty which way the economy was going; and indeed that is why they are making these month-by-month adjustments and attempts to catch-up with where we are. If it were easy then none of us would be here. We would not be employed, and neither would the MPC.

Q16 Norman Lamb: On the voting records in recent times, has it surprised you that it has been unanimous ever since last April? Is it because the judgments ultimately have been clear and obvious, or does it perhaps imply a lack of independence from the outside members? It is an unusual run they are having.

Professor Pissarides: The arguments have been a little bit more on one side recently than in the past. I still find it quite remarkable that so many economists agree for such a long period of time.

Q17 Norman Lamb: Unique!

Professor Pissarides: Maybe the arguments for or against were persuasive at the two-day meetings than before. There is more consensus now.

Professor Scott: The real test will be if they all change their mind at the same time. That seems to me the most worrying side of it. Then you would be able to distinguish between two hypotheses about what is driving them.

Q18 Norman Lamb: Do you share the worry expressed by some that the current external members are failing to challenge Bank orthodoxy in the interest rate decision?

Professor Scott: I am not at the meetings. I do not know.

Q19 Chairman: I think Norman's first question to the Governor next Tuesday, Bridget, will be a congratulatory comment. Is that correct?

Ms Rosewell: Definitely.

Angela Eagle: There will be nothing to say!


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 14 January 2005