Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 40-59)

MR MERVYN KING, MR PAUL TUCKER, MS MARIAN BELL, PROFESSOR STEVE NICKELL AND MR RICHARD LAMBERT

24 MARCH 2005

  Q40 Angela Eagle: There has been a significant downward shift in inflation expectation?

  Mr King: There has been a significant downward shift in inflation expectations and it is very closely linked to the target. There was a small upward shift in the last few months that we would watch very carefully—it is one of the factors that would lead us to be concerned on the upside—but by and large that has helped all those involved in wage bargaining focus on the medium term, confident that the inflation target will be met. And I think that helps wage bargaining then focus on the issues about the demand and supply for particular types of labour in particular areas rather than be concerned about some national movement in inflation: if inflation were to move away we had better get the wage demand in now. That has all helped and I think the reforms to the labour market over 20-25 years now, the cumulative effect of all that has given us a much more flexible labour market and that has helped to ensure that patterns of remuneration have been more flexible. All these things probably add up and it is very hard to know what the impact of any one of them is. I think, to go back to the starting point of your question, if you had said to me three years ago that unemployment would be where it is now, and it is lower where there the MPC thought it was going to be three years ago, so unemployment has fallen more than we thought and wage inflation has not picked up as we had expected, that is a real development. I think it is an accumulation of factors that explain it, but since we cannot be entirely certain we have to watch very carefully what happens in the labour market, and we will do so, right through the coming wage round and onwards. As I said earlier, it is not just settlements that would concern us, it is pay drift and the growth of average earnings, and regular pay drift has started to pick up. We will have to watch it very carefully, but it is a very striking development, and one that has been helpful to us in meeting the inflation target.

  Q41 Angela Eagle: Marian Bell, you seemed to indicate earlier that you thought there was more supply in the economy than perhaps other people thought. Does that apply to your view of the labour market as well?

  Ms Bell: I think one of the striking things for me over the last few years has been this combination of strong growth and lower inflation, both in general and in wages, than we might have expected. I think the most obvious explanation for that is that supply is greater. But I am not a labour market expert and I have no greater wisdom in any of this than the Governor, so I would not like to claim that I have the answer. I think it is certainly the case when you speak to businesses that there is greater flexibility. Quite often they are meeting shortages by allowing more flexible working practices, allowing women with children to work, perhaps people to enter the labour market who may not have been very active in it in the past. We have seen an increase in older workers. I think there are lots of potential explanations and I do not know that we will ever have the right one, but I think it is important that we allow for the possibility that some of what we have seen might be sustained.

  Q42 Angela Eagle: The Red Book talked about the highest level of employment ever for people of working age—I think 71.9%—and had an aspiration to increase that to 80%. Again that would imply that there is slack in the labour market rather than it being tight, or at least the potential for shifting the space in which the labour market exists. Do you have worries about that?

  Mr King: Let us ask the country's expert on this, Professor Nickell.

  Q43 Angela Eagle: Mr Nickell?

  Professor Nickell: Thanks very much. The 80% is obviously an aspiration. However, if you look at some of the countries in Europe, such as Denmark, then it is clear that such an aspiration can be achieved. The issue about what that means for labour market slack, however, is a bit different. If you introduce policies to try and get people who are currently inactive into work, those policies are usually uncertain in their outcomes and take quite a long time. The impact that would have on labour market slack in the short run is probably not going to be very great.

  Q44 Angela Eagle: I suppose I am asking about long-term structural shifts here rather than short-term dealing with a certain tightness, when clearly migrant labour is a more obvious way of dealing with it?

  Professor Nickell: I think in the long term we can certainly look forward to higher participation rates among people aged between 60 and 70. I think it is absolutely undoubted that that will happen, and it is happening already, and that will obviously increase the potential labour force. I think it is likely that participation rates among single parents will probably go up further. They have gone up somewhat up until now, but I think that they will probably move up further. I think that those are the two main areas. Aside from the whole issue of disability, I think it is highly—

  Q45 Angela Eagle: There is a big potential pool there?

  Professor Nickell: Yes. I think it is highly likely that some progress will be made in allowing people currently on disability benefit to get work. As I understand it, the pilot schemes, Pathways to Work schemes, are looking quite hopeful in that regard, and, of course, as you rightly say, there is an enormous pool of people there and that in the long-term could also make some difference.

  Q46 Angela Eagle: In the minutes in paragraph 20, when you were discussing wage inflation, quite surprisingly you said the Bank has received information on only about 15% of the January wage settlements, so you were left to make your judgment with quite a small sample of information. Is there any way that you can increase your access to this information more quickly so you could make a more accurate assessment of what is going on in the labour market than relying on 15% of the wage settlement?

  Mr King: Perhaps the wording here is not as clear as it might be. The phrase "January wage settlements" refers to settlements which are normally made in January, and some of those settlements may have been delayed or come in later. It does take time for information about those settlements to trickle through the very sources to reach the Bank's database, which is pretty comprehensive, so that number will go up towards 100% as time goes by.

  Q47 Angela Eagle: So it is the slowness in the negotiators coming to an agreement rather than the slowness in you getting the data?

  Mr King: That is partly it. It is both. It is not easy for us. We cannot tell people, "Let's hope you reach a wage settlement. Ring the Bank of England tomorrow, the first thing you do, and let us know." You have to go through the usual channels for receiving this information, but it can also be the case, and this is a very interesting reason for making sure that you keep tracking back to the settlements that may normally be reached in a month where the information comes in later. If it is the case that those settlements have taken much longer to reach, it may be because it has been a more difficult settlement to reach and, hence, perhaps a higher settlement, so we do have to keep track of that and we look at the revisions each month when we meet and are briefed by the staff.

  Q48 Chairman: Governor, in recommending a rise in the minimum wage to £5.05 per hour the Low Pay Commission argued that wage growth is low, clearly not threatening the Bank of England's inflation target. Do you agree with that?

  Mr King: I am not sure if that was a terribly good argument to give for setting the national minimum wage at a particular level.

  Q49 Chairman: That is down to you here?

  Mr King: When they started setting the minimum wage they were pretty cautious in setting it below the level where they thought it might settle eventually because they did not know how many people will be affected by it, and, as time went on, I think they have found that fewer people have been affected by the minimum wage than they had expected or feared and therefore it was possible to move it up to a level they thought was appropriate, and that is for them to make a judgment about how far they want to move up the wage distribution in setting the minimum wage. I think it is fair to say that over the last year I have heard more comments about the impact of the minimum wage on labour costs from employers, markedly more than I had heard before, so I think it has got to the level now where it is having an impact and where employers are beginning to say, "This is affecting the wage settlements we have to reach for those above the minimum wage level", as people attempt to restore differentials. In the Inflation Report we did point to the fact that in the hotel and restaurant sector wages had risen at 6.8% a year in the three months to November, up on the previous rate of increase, so it is starting to have an impact now. A balance has to be made and the objectives of the minimum wage are partly to do with interaction with tax credits and partly a social argument about how far you can move up people's relative incomes—there has to be a balance there—but I would say that we are beginning to get to the point now where employers start to mention this as a factor that is relevant to their overall labour costs.

  Q50 Chairman: The Inflation Report suggests that pay settlements tend to reflect trends in RPI inflation and not CPI inflation. Does that create problems for a central bank given an inflation target set in terms of CPI inflation?

  Mr King: I am not sure if we really know what index truly affects people's bargaining behaviour. I am confident if you are in a bargaining situation you tend to adduce evidence from whichever index seems to favour the claim you are making, and at present, since RPI is higher than CPI, it is not surprising that people turn to RPI and use that to justify a higher claim—it is an irresistible temptation—and that has always been the case. If you remember a long time ago, I think Nigel Lawson introduced RPI X in a way to get away from RPI and wage bargains, so I think it is bound to be the case that there are these different measures of inflation. Indeed, I think it would be a mistake for us to pretend that there is only one measure of inflation that represents the truth and that any other measure of inflation was misleading. That cannot be right. Everybody has a different basket of goods and services on which they spend their income, and for each basket there is a different measure of inflation. What we are trying to do is to target 2% CPI inflation, a broad based measure of consumer price inflation. I think that is broadly understood, but it is our job to try and make sure that the target is clearly understood.

  Q51 Mr Walter: I wonder if we could now look at some costs pressure in the economy and perhaps focus immediately on oil prices. On 7 March the Department of Energy in the United States reported in its March Outlook Report that they estimated that the 2005 average price of West Texas Intermediate (their bench mark) would be $48.95 a barrel, which was up 7.5% on the previous month's report and, in fact, this time last year they were forecasting only $29.40 for 2005. In the minutes of your last meeting, which were released today, at paragraph seven you comment that oil prices have risen by more than 20% since the Committee's February meeting in both dollar and sterling terms, with oil prices expected to be over $40 a barrel over the next three years, well above the level assumed at the time of the February Inflation Report. Last autumn, when oil prices went above $50 a barrel, you noted that the implications for the world economy depended on the extent to which the increase turned out to be permanent. That sort of evidence that I have given would seem to indicate that that is very much the case that it is going to be permanent, certainly for the next couple of years. Should we be getting more concerned about energy costs?

  Mr King: Clearly energy costs have risen, and, as you point out, they rose very sharply last month up to our recent meeting, but I think that the current spot price is still well above the price that the market expects to persist over the next two years. I think you are quite right to say that the path of oil prices that the futures market implies and that people expect to hold over the next two years has moved up significantly since last autumn and it does not show much sign of falling back. It is also the case that the information that we have from oil suppliers—from those in the industry—suggests that this is something which represents, if you like, a risk premium that they believe that there is adequate supply and that prices at this level will call forth supply more than enough to meet the demand. I do not think there is any reason to panic about this at all. Oil prices do move up and down, and the price can be very sensitive to quite small changes in the balance between demand and available stock, so the stock position is also quite important. I think we will see volatility in the price. It is very sensitive to political developments too. Although demand remains strong, and is likely to grow, there are plenty of signs that in the medium term supply is there to meet that demand at prices certainly not above the current price and I think the market would suggest at below the current spot price. China is investing in new capacity. There are reserves available. I do not think one should get too worried about it, but it is a factor. It has led to higher input costs and probably output prices of manufacturers. It has fed through and, clearly, it feeds through to petrol prices, so it is something we have to take into account. I think what we can all draw some comfort from is that central banks around the world have taken note of this. They look at the effects on inflation, but inflation expectations—to go back to the answer I gave before—seem to be sufficiently well anchored to the inflation target, whether explicit or implicit in different countries, that it is not leading to a rapid change in inflation expectations, which itself calls forth a need for a policy response. I think the greater climate of stability in which it works makes it easier to handle these short run fluctuations in the oil price. Certainly, I do not want to sound complacent. There is no doubt that the finance ministers of the G7, for example, have spent a good deal of time talking about how they can ensure there are adequate supplies.

  Q52 Mr Walter: Looking specifically at the domestic inflation situation, would you favour the Treasury not increasing the duty on petroleum products?

  Mr King: That has to be a matter for the Treasury to comment on and not us.

  Q53 Mr Walter: Can I look at non-oil commodity prices. In your February Inflation Report you say, in dollar terms, non-oil commodity prices have increased by around 5% since the November Report. Is that a worrying factor?

  Mr King: I think it reflects the strength of the world economy. If you like a strong world economy, that is a natural consequence of it. Again, they can be fairly volatile and move up and down, often in anticipation of movements in world economic demand. In itself, I do not think it is a great matter of concern. I think it highlights the fact that the world economy has moved from a position in which there was widespread discussion—including around this table at some time—of deflation, to a situation where people are more concerned about ensuring that policy is adequate to head off inflationary pressures.

  Q54 Mr Walter: Perhaps I can shift slightly now. Your Inflation Report highlights a fairly dramatic switch in UK imports from developed to developing countries, such as China, and the role this has had on holding down import prices. If we net off the upward pressure from countries such as China on energy and commodity prices—which we have just been talking about—against their downward pressure on prices for manufactured goods, has the UK inflation rate, in overall terms, been higher or lower than we might otherwise have expected?

  Mr King: I think this development has lowered consumer price inflation. Indeed, one of the quite marked factors of the last two to three years has been that consumer price inflation has been lower relative to domestic producer price inflation than we might have expected. That is true of the United States as well, though, interestingly, not of the euro area. I think this has been a development which has been significant for consumer price inflation and has affected the course of policy. How long it will persist is hard to judge. Professor Nickell has done a lot of research on this question, perhaps he would care to comment on it.

  Professor Nickell: Certainly, it is true that import prices and the switching from more expensive to cheaper countries has undoubtedly contributed fairly substantially to the very low level of import price inflation, indeed falling import prices, over the last few years. As far as the switching to cheaper supplies is concerned, I think that will go on for some time. Of course there are other factors governing import prices, including the general buoyancy of the world economy, which could start moving import prices in the other direction in the near future. Overall, going back to oil, in one respect we are quite lucky in this country in that we are less oil intensive than nearly all the other major industrial countries. I do not know why that is, but I assume that is because of our relatively high level of service sector relative to manufacturing. Of course, the other thing is oil prices do not feed through into retail prices in quite the same way in this country as they do in most other countries because of the extremely high levels of tax on petrol. The direct impact of oil prices is less in this country.

  Q55 Mr Walter: Professor Nickell, I wonder if I can direct a question at you on some work you have done. You have done some research on the role of improved efficiency and squeezed margins in the distribution sector. You concluded that without a further squeeze on distribution margins, we will see a rising trend in the CPI goods price inflation. Distribution sector margins are already near a ten year low, is there much scope for them to fall further?

  Professor Nickell: I would not have thought so. Retail margins were squeezed quite a lot about three or four years ago, there has been less of a squeeze since. Going forward, I think the key issue is distribution sector productivity growth. If distribution sector productivity growth reverts to the average level of productivity growth in the private sector, then looking forward, with the benefits of negative import prices coming to an end, a slow rise in CPI inflation is a plausible outcome. Of course, if it turns out to be the case that the distribution sector productivity growth remains at its current relatively high level, then that would, of course, exert downward pressure on inflation going forward.

  Q56 Mr Walter: Going on from there, if we look at the Inflation Report, page 28, chart A, distribution sector profits, what we see there is retail margins have been on a rising trend while those distribution sector margins have been falling. Is this consistent with the view that a highly concentrated retail sector, particularly in areas such as food retailing, has been squeezing both the supply and the distribution chains and, therefore, keeping a large part of the gains for itself? I have to say, certainly, that is the view of dairy farmers in my constituency who see the retail price of milk going up whilst the farm gate price is static or falling. I think we have seen Sainsbury's reporting a 6% jump in profits this morning.

  Professor Nickell: I do not want to get too bogged down in the issue of supermarkets versus supermarket suppliers. Certainly, I think it is true that in the distribution sector, as a whole, the retail part of the distribution sector has, in some sense, squeezed the wholesale part of the distribution sector, there is no question about that. Of course, to some extent it has taken over part of the job of the wholesale sector so that major supermarkets, in some sense, now do their own wholesaling and have their own distribution sector dealing directly with the agricultural suppliers and other suppliers. I think that picture you see there is representative of this trend, which I guess will go on.

  Q57 Mr Beard: When you referred earlier to the botched reform of the Stability and Growth Pact, you spoke of the lack of fiscal discipline which it will leave and, also, the dismay of central bankers. What are the likely economic consequences of this for the euro zone?

  Mr King: Only time will tell. The point I was referring to was the need for very careful institutional design. I think one of the successes of our framework is we have very careful institutional design and that is one reason why it has been successful. There is no doubt that those who planned monetary union thought, also, that they needed very careful institutional design. They succeeded with the European Central Bank, with the Stability and Growth Pact they have not and the consequences will be seen in the future. In terms of implications for long-term interest rates, primarily, it may take some time to come through. In the long run, it is difficult to imagine a monetary union being successful without genuine collective fiscal discipline.

  Q58 Mr Beard: Long-term interest rates around the world have fallen to levels which we last saw when there were widely voiced fears of deflation a couple of years ago, which you mentioned already. Do you share Alan Greenspan's view that the recent strength in bond markets could turn out to be—in his words—"short-term aberration"?

  Mr King: I do. I think it is quite possible to understand, in the present circumstances, why with a great deal of saving in the world economy coming from the developing countries which one might otherwise expect to be borrowing to finance investment, in fact, they are saving more than enough to finance their own investment. This may be a relatively short-lived phenomenon. I think it is plausible to imagine—with weak domestic demand in much of the euro area and still in Japan—that real short-term interest rates might be very low, leading to low interest rates at the short end. This level of rates, at the very long end, does raise questions and you have got to be pretty confident, over a very long period, of the determination to keep inflation down and close to price stability. You have to be very confident of that over a very long time period in order to justify this level of rates. I suspect at some point there will be an adjustment, it need not be very large but the rates do seem to be extraordinarily low.

  Q59 Mr Beard: The search for yield by investors has translated into an appetite for higher risk in both bond and equity markets. The latest Financial Stability Review noted an underlying concern about this trend, and Mr Tucker has warned that the price of risk was "possibly too low". Are we getting into the "irrational exuberance" which Alan Greenspan warned about in 1996 when the capital market bubble first began?

  Mr King: Let us ask Mr Tucker.

  Mr Tucker: Chairman Greenspan has described both the low long-term rates, the government yields, which you were talking to the Governor about a moment ago, and the low credit risk rates as a conundrum. I completely agree it is a puzzle; it is a puzzle which has to be a worry too. It has been going on for some time. Long-term yields—long government bond risk free yields—have been on a downward path for quite some time. And accompanied with that there has been this search for yield—which we have talked about in the Financial Stability Review—probably for about 18 months now. I think it is fair to say that those of us who have contact with the market on these issues have continued to be surprised that it has continued to the extent which it has. Are there risks in that? Yes, there are. I think the risks take two quite distinct forms. One is the price of credit is just too low, and on a slow fuse that will lead to the corporate sector internationally borrowing too much to re-leverage their balance sheets. The other kind of risk is quite different: there will be a short, sharp and uncomfortable adjustment at some point. One cannot be certain that either of those risks will crystallise. In fact, over the past month or so, perhaps a little bit less than that, there started to be some correction. Chairman Greenspan has talked about this a number of times. Since the last time he talked about it the rising inflationary pressures in the United States have caused long-term bond yields to edge up quite a bit really, approaching 50 basis points. That still leaves intact the conundrum and puzzle which the Governor talked about. More recently—in part, perhaps, triggered by the news from General Motors a week or so ago—credit spreads, in particular in the lower quality high yield industries, have continued to edge up. A gradual adjustment of that kind, if it were to persist, on balance would be a good thing probably, but I do not think we are out of the woods yet in terms of these risks.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 15 April 2005