Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 160-179)

18 MAY 2004

PROFESSOR STEVE FOTHERGILL, DR PETER TYLER AND MR JOHN ADAMS

  Q160 John Mann: The figure for those of working age is 66,000, so that makes it about 5% rather that 14.2%. In the last three years, Bassetlaw has had the second highest increase in employment of any constituency in Britain. It is a coalfield community. Why is that? Why does Bassetlaw have the second highest increase in employment of any constituency in Britain, despite the fact it is a classic coalfield community.

  Dr Tyler: There would be a number of factors. One might well be local players getting their act together to improve the area, which one hopes it is. It has a good location and the assistance of some of the coalfield money and other things to improve the place. If I am thinking of the correct place, it will be about encouraging new industries to replace industries that were there before.

  Q161 John Mann: What is the key factor then, Dr Tyler, in encouraging new industries in an area like that?

  Dr Tyler: Personally, as I said earlier, I believe there is a range of factors. One is that I do believe you need key stakeholders, if I can use that word, to come together and be asked what can be achieved. You see plenty of good examples of that outside your own area as well. You do need the resources. Again, I can think of a range of government resources that have assisted the endeavour you are talking about. A number of things come together. I can equally say, though, that without that local willingness to work together, you can fail. I therefore point heavily to institutional factors. I mentioned local capacity, people coming together, as very important, but you still have to have resources to do it.

  Q162 John Mann: Could I suggest three factors: first, people; second, land availability; and third, transport. Let us take transport as an example. With the roundabouts gone on the A1, the average journey time from Bassetlaw will reduce by 10 minutes, so for a round journey by lorry that will be 20 minutes. If you are taking strawberries to East Anglia, who would be the beneficiary of that productivity gain?

  Dr Tyler: I am sorry; what is the point you are making?

  Q163 John Mann: If the transport time for a round journey from Bassetlaw reduces by 20 minutes, which it will do, taking strawberries to a distribution centre in East Anglia, where will the productivity gain be in terms of regional productivity?

  Dr Tyler: That improves the competitiveness of your location for the activity and you may wish to use your local resources to do that sort of activity. I am not sure why the transport itself is argued to be the only factor there. It will be the quality of the labour and the rest of it.

  Q164 John Mann: Where will the productivity gain be in terms of the national economy?

  Mr Adams: The company that is selling the strawberries will have some sort of productivity gain, and then the company in East Anglia, if they get strawberries cheaper than from a different source, will make more money and have some productivity gain there as well.

  Dr Tyler: the productivity gain will be with the company because that is what employs the labour if they are able, as it were, to achieve more strawberries. The reality of it is that the productivity in that sense is not the only factor in that whole decision to locate there. Access to markets is an important consideration.

  Professor Fothergill: Could I say to John Mann that I think you are absolutely right in many respects. It is not rocket science to promote new jobs in places as long as you get some of the basics right. Just before you made your comments about the ingredients of success in Bassetlaw, I jotted down four points that I thought were the key to regeneration. Three of them are identical to yours: trained labour; making sure there is a readily available supply of sites; and good transport access, principally road access. Over and above those factors, it is giving the areas of need something extra, some sort of financial incentive that they can offer other places that have similar attributes to say, "Come here because you are needed more here". It is incentives as well. It is not rocket science to make things work in the right circumstances. Of course it needs financial resources to make some of this happen. You do not get the development of these sites free. In the Bassetlaw area, as you are very familiar with that, English Partnerships have expended huge amounts of money in bringing forward former colliery sites for development, and that is how they come to fruition.

  Q165 John Mann: I am going to leave the question of where the productivity gain will be, which region, on the table for the Committee to ponder at some stage because I think it is key. I have two other questions. The informal sector: what should be done to translate the informal sector into the formal sector and in particular what government agency should take the lead in relation that? My second question is more esoteric. If you take a load of stockbrokers and stick them in Bassetlaw, then from what was said earlier, our regional productivity would go up in terms of quality-of-life indicators. Would that be an improvement in the quality of life for local people?

  Professor Fothergill: Let me answer the second question. Yes, in purely statistical terms, in the way that the Treasury go about measuring regional indices of productivity, if you inject into an area a large number of highly paid workers, given that GDP is largely dependent on salary levels, yes, it would statistically boost your area's GDP per head. Whether that is a solution, though, to the underlying problem, I think I very much would raise a question mark, just as I was trying to say in the first instance that this preoccupation, if you like, with productivity as the be all and end all of solving the regional problem really diverts too much attention from many of the other things that actually need to be done. On the informal economy, I think I would have to bow to the judgment of my two colleagues as to what they feel on that issue.

  Dr Tyler: To be honest, we do not know a lot about how the informal economy meshes with the formal economy. I suppose I would take the view that if we could get the level of activity up in some of these very low activity areas, then one might hope that we would see more of the informal activity moving to the formal economy. It is of great interest that in some of the areas that have had such historically low employment rates, and of course have been so depressed, in a way they have managed to survive as they have. I would argue that as you increase the availability of real jobs and also increase real incomes, then you will probably see the informal economy reduced, but you can go either way.

  Q166 John Mann: Mr Adams, which government department should take the lead in trying to translate the informal economy into the formal economy?

  Mr Adams: The Department for Work and Pensions I would presume because if you are active in the informal economy, then you are signing on for job seekers' loans.

  Q167 John Mann: If I can throw that back to you then, if it was the general economy, we would be looking at the Treasury and particularly the Department of Trade and Industry to take the lead in terms of job creation, entrepreneurship and innovation, and yet, when it is the informal sector, we suggest it is the Department for Work and Pensions.

  Mr Adams: I think the Department for Work and Pensions should take a much closer interest in regional policy anyway. The Department for Work and Pensions is notorious for being regionally insensitive within Whitehall. Very often I have been in seminars with DWP where the fact that regions exist has been denied; regional employment has been denied. The policy which the DWP promotes is that there are jobs across the whole of the United Kingdom, if only we could get people to access those jobs. I think the DWP does need to integrate itself more closely into the regional problem in any case across the board because, as I said, employment is one of the big issues which causes the north/south divide, and so the DWP obviously has a role.

  Q168 Mr Cousins: May I ask you about the funding arrangements? We have had territorial block allocations in this country for Scotland, Wales and what was originally Ireland, now the North of Ireland, since the end of the nineteenth century. Do you think it would be of advantage to have territorial block allocations for the English regions? I am talking here about public spending of course.

  Professor Fothergill: Can I come at this purely from a regional policy angle, not necessarily from a political devolution angle?

  Q169 Mr Cousins: That is precisely the angle I want you to take.

  Professor Fothergill: The important point, from a regional policy point of view, is less whether or not the budget line is devolved, but more perhaps the overall scale of the budget line. If devolution to the regions meant that all regions were treated equally, then that would not be a very good situation in terms of promoting development in the weakest regions. What matters is the degree to which you discriminate in favour of those areas that need the greatest help. On that issue, I have to say the Treasury documentation is very vague at the moment. There is no firm commitment as to how much of the resources are going to be prioritised into some regions rather than others. The act of devolution of budgets in itself is not necessarily the solution. What matters is the scale of the budget.

  Q170 Mr Cousins: To be clear about this, the issue of territorial block allocation is quite separate from the issue of devolution. Territorial block allocations existed in this country for decades before there were elected parliaments or assembles for the areas in question. It is a completely separate issue. Let me put the point to you again: do you think it would be useful, in terms of promoting regional policy, if the English regions had territorial block allocations of public spending?

  Professor Fothergill: In a nutshell, my answer would be: not necessarily. What matters is what the scale of those budgets is and how one region is treated vis-a"-vis another.

  Q171 Mr Cousins: How can you find that out unless you have the territorial block allocations?

  Dr Tyler: I suppose the reason I am having trouble with what you are saying is that we know obviously that certain depressed regions have been favoured through the Barnett Formula and this has been a great source of concern, I know, to the North-East. At the margin there has been injustice there because, as all the statistics we have presented you with and which you have no doubt looked at show, the North-East is the least performing region in many ways along with a number of areas where extra public expenditure would no doubt help. I suppose what I am having difficulty with is that it seems to me that it all depends how you give the extra resources. For instance, one way of doing it is perhaps through the business rate mechanism that is increasingly being discussed as a way of giving local resources. I suppose I tend to be supportive of the notion of saying that some regions do need more resources if we are going to make this step turn that we are trying to bring about. Exactly how you do that is open for debate.

  Q172 Mr Cousins: The Barnett Formula, which you have introduced into the discussion, is simply a way of determining the size of the territorial block allocation. My question is: would territorial block allocations in themselves be of advantage for regional policy?

  Mr Adams: It may depend whether you think the current system is fair or not. If you think that your region would receive more public expenditure from a different form of territorial funding mechanism, then I am sure that would be, even if only on the margins, of some benefit to the GDP of the region which benefits from that public expenditure change. It comes down to a value judgment maybe as to whether you think the current system is fair or not or whether you think lagging regions, and in particular the lagging region you care most about, would benefit from any change in particular funding mechanisms.

  Q173 Mr Cousins: At the moment, we do have territorial block allocations to the English regions in one limited sense and that is the single pot for the RDAs, which of course covers a tiny span of expenditure compared to the territorial block allocation system in Scotland, Wales and Ireland. Do you think that has been sensible? Do you think it has had good effects? Would you like to see it extended?

  Mr Adams: Yes, yes, and yes. I think it has been a very useful innovation and has been very important in allowing regional development agencies to act with more responsibility and more autonomy. There is an academic consensus that strong regional institutions and strong autonomy at the regional level, strong accountability mechanisms at the regional level, does have some sort of impact on regional economic growth. I think the RDAs have benefit from that; their policies have benefit from it definitely. I would like to see it increased. In particular, I think regional institutions should have a lot more flexibility over what they spend their money on. If the RDA in a particular region did not want to spend money on industrial grants to the private sector but rather wanted to prioritise some sort of transport innovations and transport infrastructure, then the regional agencies should have the autonomy and the flexibility to do those sorts of things. Yes, I think the single pot was a very good idea and we need to go further.

  Professor Fothergill: If I have understood your question correctly, you are asking in essence the question: if we handed over a large block of money to the English regions, rather like we do to Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland, would that be good news for regional policy? I think that is very heavily dependent on the political choices then made within each of those regions. If the local politicians—and I am assuming it is local politicians who control those regional budgets—decided "yes, we want to allocate the money to regional policy", it would be good news; on the other hand, they might have other priorities. They might want to spend the money on education or health. I do understand, for example, that while we have been getting extra funding to the English RDAs, actually the situation in Scotland has gone in the other direction in recent years, that the political discretion in Scotland has been used to curb the budget of Scottish Enterprise, the local RDA.

  Dr Tyler: I would support more flexibility at the regional level so that the regions are able to make choices on what they spend resources. If what we are talking about here would allow that, that would be welcomed, subject to the caveat that there would be sufficient capacity at the regional level to manage the decisions appropriately. The reason I am having trouble answering the question effectively is that I believe that requires knowledge that we do not currently have because, in English regions certainly, we have not moved to that yet. I feel it is important to give more flexibility because I see a lot of these infrastructural problems being about difficulties in getting resources to get things moving. If the regional level would allow that to speed up, then it has to be welcomed. At the same time, you have to make certain you have capacity at the regional level to deliver. We have not had regional capacity orchestrated around that. We just do not know enough about that at the moment.

  Q174 Angela Eagle: I am someone who thinks regional policy does work because I do not believe in the iron law of the market. Do you think that so far in the regional policy that this Government has pursued there is an over-concentration on the supply side, and particularly a lack of willingness to look in some of the really deprived areas, which have an obvious history of declining heavy industry and large numbers of people on incapacity benefit, particularly middle-aged and older men? Do you think that there is an unwillingness to look at demand-side solutions?

  Professor Fothergill: May I say that I think broadly I would agree with Angela Eagle in terms of the balance of government policy. Government policy at the moment seems to be underpinned by the assumption that if you reconnect people with the labour market, the supply of labour will create its own demand. That is what economists call Say's law, which was discredited many years ago, but seems to have reappeared. It is certainly probably true in the parts of Britain where the economy is very strong that if you can reconnect people with the labour market, there will be an outlet for their skills. In the absence of improving the demand for labour in some of the areas you are talking about, motivating people to get out there and look for work and get training, will tend, if anything, only to increase the scramble for the available jobs. It becomes something of a zero sum game. I am not trying to say those supply-side measures are not worthwhile. Actually, they are very worthwhile, but by themselves they are not really attacking the core problem in those most deprived areas. We continue to have a very large imbalance in the labour market, an imbalance principally absorbed these days, as you indicate, by the large numbers we divert on to Incapacity Benefit rather than the large numbers we park on Jobseeker's Allowance.

  Dr Tyler: Can I just say, I believe in many ways the thing becomes almost a matter of semantics. Obviously we do need supply side policies, particularly in our more intractable areas. The level of labour market skills and any other problems are such that we have to improve the supply side but, having said that, as my colleague says, it is also a question of balance. My experience of regional policy is that if you can get the level of aggregate demand up in an area then in many ways you begin achieve some of the effects you want on the supply side. One of the biggest things we have not talked about is the perverse and pernicious effects of migration. Generally speaking, what is happening in many of our depressed areas at the moment is that marginal gains on the supply side lead to people moving out. Unless we can get the aggregate level of activity up in many of these areas through a number of other mechanisms than just simply on the supply side then we are always going to be running hard to have an impact. I do feel on the supply side that I would play a lot more heavily on access. John Mann mentioned transport. I believe that is a crucial policy which you can say is a supply side policy, which I allude to in my note, and which we need to use more to enhance regional accessibility and allow more demand, as it were, to get to these places. I do feel that if anything the current policy is to be supply driven when we know that the levels of activity in most of these areas that we are talking about is too low, as evidenced by the employment rate.

  Q175 Angela Eagle: There has been some increase in overall demand because of things like tax credits, particularly for women workers who have gone into the labour market in a way they had not before, to slightly introduce aggregate demand even in some of the most depressed areas. Are there any more detailed demand side policies that might be much more focused that any of you have been considering that might help to redress this imbalance which currently exists between welcome supply side policies but a neglect on the demand side?

  Professor Fothergill: To my mind, the key demand side policy is regional economic policy. It is the sorts of measures that John Mann has talked about that have created an environment which enables new investment, new jobs, new economic activity to flourish in those areas. That is the key, to get that new business investment into the areas.

  Mr Adams: I think bringing more women into the workforce is obviously increasing supply rather than promoting demand.

  Q176 Angela Eagle: It helps increase aggregate demand because of tax credits, there is more money to spend in the local economy.

  Mr Adams: Yes, there is that multiplier effect. I think you put your finger on the most important debate within regional economic policy circles and that is whether it is supply side or whether it is demand side and that is the most fundamental thing. If you are looking at trying to improve the demand side, we have been in this situation since the time of the Great Depression and if there was a magic bullet we would have found it by now, but there is no simple answer. There are so many factors that led us into this situation that we have to have a very broad strategy to get us out of it. Land and property is important, that is true, but we have to look at skills policy, we have to look at enterprise policy, we have to look at innovation, Government structures and things like that. We have to have a cross-cutting approach across all of these policy areas focused on raising the level of demand and appreciating when some things improve productivity and when some things improve levels of employment. For example, skills policy focusing on people with doctorates, focusing on very high level skills policy, is very good for productivity but it does not create that many jobs certainly in the short-term. Focusing on, say, level two qualifications, something like that, is much more useful for bringing those people furthest away from the labour market into work. I think there should be a cross-cutting approach across all sorts issues but appreciating when we are talking about productivity and when we are talking about trying to create demand side employment.

  Q177 Angela Eagle: I want to talk about skills policy and also a little bit about business support. Why does the level of skills and workforce qualifications vary so much between regions? If we look in the North East only 58% of 16 and 17 year olds remain in full-time education compared with 70% in London. We know there is also graduate outward migration, which you have already referred to. Why is there so much variation in qualifications and what can we do to redress that balance?

  Dr Tyler: Principally it has got to be the industrial heritage of our past. Great parts of the areas I go into have had a tradition of large producers who tended to take most of the labour force for many, many years and there was not a premium put upon getting trained or whatever. Over 20 years a lot of that has shaken out but many areas still have this endemic or inbuilt tendency. At present we are very much influenced by what we have been in the past and to bring about the change at the margin is obviously slow. We have to find whole new ways of bringing people into the skill base that they have not needed in areas historically. That is still going on. We are still losing manufacturing jobs, we are still losing many jobs that perhaps we would like to keep. A lot of jobs that have been created are distribution jobs that do not carry high income with them and they do not bring big skill requirements with them, so the market itself often is not bringing impacts there either. That is part of the reason as I see it.

  Professor Fothergill: I think if you want to understand the overall skill level in any locality you have got to really look at the net impact of two quite separate processes. One is the production of skills locally, the extent to which kids stay on at school, the extent to which an area generates graduates from within its own boundaries. Clearly there are cultural variations across the country that are rooted in socioeconomic factors, that are rooted in the long economic history of places, and I think Pete Tyler is absolutely correct in the description that he portrays. That is only part of the overall jigsaw. The other part of the jigsaw is where do people live once they have got the skills. The fact is that a lot of the northern regions, for example, do generate quite high numbers of graduates but there are not the relevant jobs to keep them in the northern regions, so they drift southwards.

  Q178 Angela Eagle: They then lose out.

  Professor Fothergill: Often when we point to many areas, to Merseyside and to Tyneside, and say they have not got very many graduates, that this is the cause of their problems, it is confusing cause and effect. It is an effect of their problems because the graduates go elsewhere, they go down South to find the jobs.

  Q179 Angela Eagle: Do you think that employer attitudes are an issue here? There was a report in the Financial Times recently that take-up of the Employer Training Pilots has been low amongst employers outside the South East. There seems to be a North-South difference in attitude amongst employers to allowing their employees access to training. Have you come across that?

  Mr Adams: I came across a report from the Institute for Employment Studies last year, which was an evaluation of the first year of the pilots, which said that take-up had been pretty good. However, when you drilled down into that you discovered that the take-up in very large part had been in the care sector, in nursing homes and so forth, so, in fact, what a lot of Employer Training Pilots were doing was just training the care sector and enabling employers to train those. I have not come across the north-south divide issue, I will look at that. The other point to make is that Employer Training Pilots are, of course, focused on level two qualifications and I think the evidence says that level two qualifications are particularly useful for getting females into the workplace but not so much men and they do not have a huge effect on wages or, indeed, possibly no effect on wages.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 11 April 2005