Memorandum submitted by Cambridge University
Computer Laboratory Graduate Association
Universities can help catalyse local economic
growth particularly in technology industries. The flotation of
Google is a spectacular example which will bring great wealth
to California. Google could have been based anywhere but, in fact,
it's based there. We need to understand why. Every major country
wants its own Silicon Valley. Every major country wants their
own universities to catalyse the growth of local technology clusters.
Why have, so many policy attempts to develop
university led clustering, failed to produce significant results?
Why have attempts to encourage academics to do more industrially
relevant research failed to boost the economy? Why have more recent
attempts to commercialise academic IPR failed to produce wealth?
Will the attempt to stimulate industrial demand
for research inspired by the Lambert Review fare any better? Once
new businesses have been founded, will they grow to global scale
like their American counterparts? It's unlikely. Past efforts
have focused on only a part of the mechanism. Recent policy has
been based on the theory that clusters are mainly idea centric
and grow out of the idea flow. This article suggests that people
flow is an essential additional element of the cluster creation
mechanism rather than just idea flow on its own. Economies are
made of businesses. Businesses are made of people. People are
the raw material for the knowledge economy. Put some additional
focus on the people and the technology businesses will, more or
less, take care of themselves.
This article is in three parts. We start with
a discussion of the link between research and economic growth.
Second we look at the failures of the idea flow approach. Finally
the people flow approach is described as part of a detailed action
plan on how to use people flow to grow a technology cluster. The
results of an experiment to pilot one, small, element of the action
plan conducted over the past two years at Cambridge University
Computer Laboratory are described.
The costs of implementing the people flow approach
in a strategic department in a research university are very modest.
Most of the infrastructure required will be self financing and
could, at scale, generate a small surplus. Start-up capital of
about £250,000 would be required to reach the scale where
self-financing would be possible. One person in the infrastructure
required might require financing although suitable individuals
might be prepared to do the work on the basis of an honorarium.
Substantial benefits should accrue to the economy as a result.
If the thesis in this article is correct, namely
one can achieve a large positive economic impact for a modest
cost, one might ask why universities have not already pursued
this approach. The answer is that it is not and has not been the
mission of a research university to promote economic growth per
se. Responsibility for economic growth lies more with local
development agencies yet a major source of impact on economic
growth, people, comes from the university system.
UNIVERSITIES CAN
CREATE WEALTH
IN THEIR
COMMUNITIES
Education is an acknowledged route to increased
living standards, progress and indeed civilisation. In more recent
times, there has been a well observed and increasingly envied
connection between great research universities and the growth
of technology business clusters around Stanford University and
around the universities in Boston, Massachusetts. A small technology
business cluster has even grown up around Cambridge here in England
but on a much smaller scale. There is a similarly sized technology
cluster around Oxford. European policy makers would like to repeat
the success of the US clusters. Furthermore, economists have noticed
a correlation between spending on scientific research and economic
growth, making two good policy reasons to attempt to stimulate
university led economic clusters. As part of the Lisbon programme
for Europe, spending on scientific research is set to rise whilst
attempts are being made to catalyse the creation of wealth by
universities. UK science is already productive, producing many
more papers per pound of research spending than US science. This
scientific productivity is a good platform for using universities
as a engine of economic growth provided we can understand and
accelerate the mechanism by which one leads to the other.
BUT WE
DIDN'T
FULLY UNDERSTAND
THE MECHANISM
Despite years of trying in at least three different
ways, UK policy makers and universities still don't appear to
understand fully the mechanism by which universities augment outputs
from capital and labour and thereby catalyse the growth of technology
clusters. Research relevance, research commercialisation and most
recently stimulation of industrial demand for research have all
been wrongly identified as the broken link in the chain. Policy
actions to mend these links have failed to produce results because
these were not, in fact, the broken links:
The first theory was that wealth
was created by businesses using or based on academic research.
Policy measures to increase the industrial relevance of research
and to encourage research in strategic areas were tried. Research
councils applied money to the target areas. Industrial research
collaboration was encouraged and in some cases mandated. Academics
had to find industrial co-sponsors in order to receive funding.
Secondments from industry to academia and vice versa have been
encouraged. Many schemes have been implemented from CASE studentships
to the Teaching Company Scheme. Most recently, it has been suggested
that academics should sit on company boards.
More recent policy efforts have focused
on direct efforts to commercialise research by universities licensing
direct to industry or by setting up spin out companies. Generally
known as "technology transfer", this differs from publication
in that usage would require some commercial return to the owner
of the intellectual property ("IP"). An added attraction
was that the money raised could fill the university funding gap.
Large industrial liaison departments have been set up in many
universities to identify promising technologies and maximise the
commercial returns to the institution. However, not all is going
well and there are several ominous signs. Many university spin
outs from the last five years have failed. UK Government research
about US experience found that almost all such activity, loses
money. Note that pharmaceutical patents are an exception to this
general rule. Of the 20 or so spinout companies proudly displayed
on one university's web site, not one claimed a single commercial
customer. A director of industrial liaison with 10 years experience
at one leading London college told me that overall technology
transfer commercial results had been poor. Published research
confirms that marketing efforts by a university's technology transfer
office are the least effective mode (out of six possibilities)
for generating leads for potential technology licences; see Thursby
and Thursby, Industry Perspectives on Licensing University Technologies,
2000. This paper is based on research carried out in six institutions
in the US. Not only has commercial success been patchy but there
have also been major costs to the universities themselves. Licensing
the IP means owning it first. For Cambridge University, this meant
taking the IP away from the individual academics, who had owned
it since time immemorial. The scholarly Cambridge Phenomenon Report,
1st edition 1985, found that individual rather than institutional
IP ownership had been found to be a significant positive factor
in the growth of the Cambridge technology cluster. Taking the
IP away from the faculty would therefore harm cluster growth.
University IP ownership also appears to damage academic freedoms,
hinder academic mobility between universities and make recruiting
low paid faculty harder. A rebellion ensued at Cambridge. Currently
there is stalemate in Cambridge on the IP issue. There is also
a technical tax problem. Recent changes in tax law mean that shares
distributed by an employer to staff in spinout companies are taxed
at the time of grant as a benefit in kind. Since this came into
force, all formations of university spinout companies have ceased.
We suggest that current university technology transfer activities
are damaging economic growth and damaging UK universities' research.
Most recently, the Lambert Review,
set up to inquire into how universities can contribute directly
to economic growth, has noticed that industrial demand for academic
research is weak. They explain this partly by the fact that there
are few research intensive industries based in the UK. In other
words, there is weak "pull". Remember that everyone
agrees that universities catalyse the creation of technology based
research intensive industries in the first place and that we already
have great research universities. So Lambert's observation doesn't
address the key question of why our universities have failed to
catalyse the growth of research intensive industries nor propose
any means of fixing the problem. Lambert did correctly identify
that there has been an over emphasis on spinouts but is taking
us back down the, mistaken, technology transfer route again.
Real industrial demand for academic
research is weak because it's rarely a significant factor in business
success. Business people are pretty good at working out what it
takes to succeed. If buying more curiosity driven research was
a major means to business success, they would do more of it. Consider
that the definition of academic research is that the academic
can decide what to do and whether to publish and you can see that
that is hardly likely to be relevant to a business. Imagine going
out to tender to a supplier and saying that that what you want
can be anything the supplier chooses to deliver and that the results
can be published for free usage by anyone. Thursby and Thursby,
cited above, asked firms who routinely buy licences to externally
developed technology from other sources, why they rarely licensed
in university developed technology. The single largest reason
given was that "University research is generally at too early
a stage of development".
There is real business demand for
contract research, ie applied problem solving and there are plenty
of specialist consultancies and commercial research houses who
meet that demand. Confidentiality is of course essential. University
faculty and PhD students can and do satisfy some of this demand
and it is proper for them to do so but consultancy can conflict
with their core role of publishing novel research in their specialisation
simply by consuming their time. A professor in a leading science
department in Cambridge who has a global industrial company as
a generous sponsor told me that proprietary applied problem solving
for industrial clients under contract and doing academic work
don't really mix, at least not all of the time.
So why do industrial companies actually
sponsor academic research at all? If one segments industrial companies
by size and market position, their motivations become clearer.
There are several reasons but none are related to gaining competitive
advantage through proprietary knowledge transfer. Note that funding
academic research which may be published may not result in any
proprietary knowledge transfer to the provider of the funding.
Monopolists want influence over Government,
regulatory bodies and the society in which they operate. Elite
research universities can help provide this cost effectively.
Very large companies have sometimes established research institutes
alongside universities. Rank Xerox EuroPARC, AT&T Research
and Microsoft Research, all in Cambridge, are examples of this
approach. The institutes then sponsor joint research in the university.
Monopolists need to increase market size
to grow rather than increase market share. Intel wants more applications
for their chips rather than better chips than their competitors.
Monopolists also need to recruit top
quality talent into their organisations to maintain their institutional
leadership. Research sponsorship builds links with faculty which
helps recruitment of good students.
For companies of all sizes, global, national,
medium and small, managers may be motivated by a sense of philanthropy
or by a desire to socialise or work with academics in a particular
field and may need to recruit staff. Rolls Royce is a good example
of a UK company with a vested interest in building relevant skills
and a local science base.
Clearly in some instances companies may
need some technology and a university may be a cost effective
supplier but a university will be in competition with established
technology suppliers and pre-existing alternative technologies.
To sum up, economic growth is not primarily
about the idea flow from research. The linear model of innovation
from science to R & D to production to markets is too simple
a model of economic development. This is hard for academics to
accept because their work is about the value of their ideas; which
are very important. But not, really, for growing technology clusters.
Nor is industrial demand for research terribly important. In fact,
the two fields, business and research are pretty distant cousins.
So what is the answer?
PEOPLE (ESPECIALLY
POSTGRADUATES) ARE
THE MISSING
PIECE OF
THE PUZZLE
As you may have already guessed from the title,
it's the people. People are the additional part of the mechanism
which enables great universities to grow technology clusters.
Universities are magnets for quality people. They attract, train
and retain quality people within their locality. They enable people
to network amongst each other. Universities help make a place
an attractive location in which to settle and bring up a family.
They are engines of loyalty and retention.
People are repositories for technology knowledge
until it's needed in a commercial application and people perform
a matching mechanism for that technology when it's needed. Innovation
has been said to be the application of old technology to new,
valuable, problems rather than the application of new technology
to old problems. Blockbuster applications for technology may not
to be the application intended by the inventor. Transistors were
invented for hearing aids and the telephone was envisioned to
be a means for broadcasting concerts. Who would have expected
CD players to be a major application for lasers? So, technology
cannot be force fed into a commercial application but is likely
to have to wait until it's needed. Sometimes this wait can take
decades.
THE PEOPLE
FLOW MECHANISM
Not only do people grow businesses but they
have the added attraction than they are easier to monitor, control
and encourage than ideas which diffuse unpredictably and by multiple
means. Not only are people a key mechanism but they are an actionable
mechanism as well. Teaching science and engineering students is
not enough on its own. France and the UK have far higher numbers
of science and engineering graduates per head of labour force
than the US yet we lack US style technology dynamism. France has
1,430 such graduates per 10,000 members of the labour force aged
25 to 35. Comparable figures for the UK are 1,360 and 950 in the
US all according to the OECD. There has to be a mechanism which
enables these people to be involved in business growth. We suggest
there are several elements to the people flow mechanism; inbound
entrepreneurs, knowledge transfer in the heads of PhDs taking
full time jobs in industry and, third, graduates generally who
form a pool of skilled but good value labour who work in local
cluster companies.
Inbound entrepreneurs are key. Sergey
Brin, who co-founded Google, is Russian but is in California because
he went to do a PhD at Stanford. Postgraduate students are the
key element of people flow. Around half of foreign PhD students
in the UK settle permanently, enriching the economy. One such,
Dr. Hermann Hauser, came to Cambridge from his native Austria
to do a Physics PhD and stayed on in Cambridge. His first company,
Acorn, is believed to have led to around 30 subsequent companies.
One of those, ARM p.l.c., is believed to have led to a further
20 or so companies. Dr. Hauser's venture capital firm, Amadeus,
has invested in many local companies as well. Dr. Hauser's contribution
therefore to the Cambridge technology cluster has been very large,
leading in total to the creation directly or indirectly of around
100 companies. Recent research from the Cambridge Centre for Entrepreneurial
Learning confirms the important contribution of a relatively small
number of such entrepreneurs in Cambridge. In the other direction,
around 70% of British students doing PhD's in the US never come
back according to an article by Sami Mahroum of the Institute
for Prospective Technical Studies in Seville in Spain. This is
the highest stay on rate of any country. Only 8% of Japanese PhD
graduates stay on in US as a comparison. The high British staying
on rates have led to there being over 7,000 UK science and engineering
PhD graduates in the US in 1999 according to the OECD, the highest
number of any country. Canada is second at 5,500 whilst Germany
is a distant third at 2,500. Students like to do their first degree
near home. But after that, if you are entrepreneurial and want
to get into the US, a good route has been to do a post graduate
degree. If you are bright, you can usually get a scholarship,
can then study in your desired field for a few years and are guaranteed
a work permit if you want to stay.
Specialised knowledge transfer from
academia to industry occurs best in the heads of PhD graduates
according to British Government research conducted in 2003. Undergraduates
don't have knowledge from a research group. Faculty, in general,
don't go into industry. PhDs take their own knowledge and knowledge
of their supervisors' and peers' work, their social relationships
with the department and their peer group and their sector expertise
into their new employer. Thursby and Thursby, cited above, found
that personal contacts between R & D staff and university
personnel was the single most important source for identifying
the technology. This is evidence that movement of PhD students
into industry and the maintenance of subsequent contact with faculty
is the best means for promoting technology transfer from universities
into industry. Superior US economic performance might be partly
explained by their relatively high number of masters courses and
the relatively high number of science and engineering graduates
produced. Fewer UK graduates go on to postgraduate study than
in the US. We need therefore to increase postgraduate student
numbers and nurture their career moves into technology industry.
Careers are central to the university contribution to the economy
but this barely gets a mention in Lambert.
Both PhDs and graduates with first
degrees provide a talented labour pool in the cluster from which
local employers can recruit. Wages for computer programmers in
Cambridge with Cambridge University computer science degrees are
relatively low because a Cambridge computer science degree in
Cambridge is a commonplace. Elsewhere in the country such a qualification
would be rare and prestigious. Retaining the pool of graduates
locally therefore is a prime policy objective for cluster development
because it provides a high quality and relatively low cost labour
pool.
THE ACTION
PLAN FOR
UNIVERSITY LED
ECONOMIC GROWTH
Now that the people flow mechanism has been
explained, an integrated three part action plan for a university
can be developed which covers the people in the university (both
students and faculty), companies (whether founded by graduates
or others) and, thirdly, strategic industries that one hopes will
grow.
1. The first element of the Action Plan,
"People Flow", is to nurture the basic raw material,
the students, who in due course graduate with a degree and then
become alumni. There is a significant potential payoff to nurturing
them at each stage.
Investing in People Flow starts with
student recruitment and admissions. Growing an industry in a particular
field, eg bio tech, requires recruitment of promising students
into that department from all over the country and the world.
Successes of past graduates need to be celebrated. A book detailing
their achievements should be given to undergraduates and applicants.
Schools need to be visited and teachers briefed on how to help
good students, whatever their background, to make the most of
their talents. Each technology department's web site needs to
excite potential students about both the degree course and the
subsequent career opportunities.
Post graduate scholarships are particularly
valuable. Most should be based on academic attainment but some
should be awarded on entrepreneurial and separately, social leadership,
potential.
Undergraduates should be told about the
department's aspirations to help grow an industry and should be
briefed on successful prior role models.
Social bonding between students through
joint projects, team work and department based social activities
should be conducted to establish strong links which will be useful
later in their career. This is particularly important in collegiate
universities where the primary social axis is college and then
activity (sport, drama etc) rather than subject.
The second part of People Flow is helping
students get off to a good start in their careers. This has a
substantial potential return. The role of University Careers Services
was reviewed extensively in the recent report of Sir Martin Harris.
Careers Services are clearly important. They become strategic
when one sees a key goal as being that of helping build an industry
through People Flow.
There should be a careers talk in every
department at the start of the course and then again at the start
of each academic year. The basic talk should be given by the Careers
Service. Some departments in leading universities don't do this
at the moment. Through the course of the academic year, inspiring
graduates who have had interesting careers should be invited back
to tell their stories and provide role models to current students.
This is standard practice in leading universities in the US and
Europe and should be adopted more widely in the UK.
Summer placements organised by a summer
placement officer have been shown by our research to be very valuable
to students in informing their career choices and valuable to
employers in forming an extended interview. Summer placements
make the matching process between graduates and employers more
effective. Major effort should be invested in finding companies
to accept summer students, providing them with summer accommodation
and encouraging students to take up such work. Summer placements
also form a convenient focus for companies belonging to a departmental
industrial supporters' club, discussed at greater length below.
To enable them to find work, PhD's should
be given bursaries to stay on in the university after their studies
have finished. Foreigners wanting to stay on in the UK after graduation
should be given automatic work permits.
The third element in People Flow is taking
care of the graduate community once it has left the university.
As well as the economic benefits resulting from helping individual
graduates do better, developing an active graduate association
also brings benefits back to the department. The Harris Report
mentions approvingly a North East university which works closely
with a team of their alumni to support their students. Their alumni
take part in employer presentations, in summer schools and offer
work experience opportunities; see Cameo 3 on page 26. The Cambridge
University Computer Laboratory Graduate Association (the "Ring")
was founded in 2002 to achieve both goals, namely helping graduates
and helping the department. Overall the Association seeks to enable
graduates to derive a lifetime benefit from their Cambridge degree
through social, business and technical contacts and information.
3,500 people have graduated from the
Cambridge University Computer Laboratory since it started teaching
in 1953, the oldest taught computer science course in the world.
The Ring set out to understand where they had ended up, what they
needed in order to do better in their current job, whether they
had fulfilled their personal potential and if not, why not.
The Ring provides careers help for its
members through a panel of volunteer careers advisers, a jobs
board and is developing a mentoring programme. Note that is directed
to graduates after they leave Cambridge and therefore complements
the University's Careers Service which helps students find their
first job. The Ring organises regular social events and speaker
meetings on topics of interest. It provides an online contact
directory and regular Newsletter as well as a helpline. So far,
300 members have joined and events have been well attended.
The Ring has catalogued companies founded
by Laboratory graduates. The current number of 110 companies (the
"Hall of Fame") which is far from comprehensive, is
the most of any department in Cambridge, and is far more than
the number of university spinouts based on university owned IPR.
It seems obvious that the graduate community is far more fertile
ground for stimulating entrepreneurship than the faculty and students.
The currently most successful Ring company, Sophos p.l.c., recently
came back to the Lab to give a talk about their success story.
They employ 758 people and are the largest anti-virus vendor in
Europe and the 4th largest in the world.
The People Flow element of the Action
Plan covers students during their studies, getting them into jobs
in strategic industries (but only if it suits them as individuals)
and helping them to realise their personal career potential subsequently.
2. The second element of the Action Plan
is to help companies do better by enabling Company Growth. Government
policy initiatives to help small business and technology business
performance are legion. The focus here:
is on companies in a strategic industry
which have links to the university department in question. The
link can be either that they are a Hall of Fame company (founded
by a department graduate) or a local company which has become
a member of the departmental Industrial Supporters' Club. Both
the Halls of Fame and the Supporters' Clubs can be used to motivate
company management by holding annual awards dinners where company
successes are celebrated. Press clippings about member companies
should be circulated on a regular basis for example as a supplement
to a regular Newsletter.
Companies can be helped by de-bottlenecking
growth. Growth bathers should be studied and identified (commonly
product sales, recruitment of staff, access to capital and US
market entry) and steps taken to remove the bathers. The Cambridge
University Computer Laboratory has already conducted a study of
its Hall of Fame companies to find out why they have not grown
further than they have. This revealed that many stopped growing
once they reached 50 employees.
Local companies'
product sales can be helped in several ways. Seminars on Sales
Management Basics are popular and well attended in Cambridge.
The local business school should consider spending more time on
management education about sales force management. There appears
to be demand from technology companies for more sales training
which would in the ordinary course be met by commercial sales
training companies. Getting introductions to potential customers
is particular valuable. The Ring Who's Who (its directory of members)
can be searched by company, industry and location and therefore
can help members contact potential customers. The Ring Newsletter
publishes articles about Hall of Fame companies to build awareness
amongst potential customers.
Seminars can be held
on US market entry; potential local US contacts found through
the Ring Who's Who and US students in Cambridge returning to the
US can also be used. The author is frequently asked to give talks
and seminars on technology sales management and US market entry.
Access to venture
and development capital is already helped through a variety of
local mechanisms in Cambridge and is a well studied policy area.
In addition to encouraging the University
Careers Services to continue their good work, People Flow into
companies can be assisted in several ways:
By major investment
in encouraging student summer placements in strategic companies.
Proactively inviting
strategic companies to give more careers talks to key departments
and encouraging them to recruit students. This is the same point
as helping students into good careers but this time it is viewed
from the company rather than the graduating student end. This
illustrates the important win / win element of nurturing the People
Flow into strategic businesses.
Encouraging use of
the Ring jobs bulletin board which enables members to post jobs
ads free on the Ring web site enabling access to a pool of experienced
talent (as opposed to fresh graduates).
Companies can also draw on resources
from university departments by active participation in Industrial
Supporters' clubs. These may be research focused or student recruitment
focused. Demand for both can vary within a short space of time
with the result that companies not needing either at a particular
time may drop out. An elegant solution is to focus Industrial
Supporters' Clubs on student summer placements. This is a simple
and low cost proposition to the company, can be expected to happen
every year and requires reasonably close contact between the department
and the company every year. With summer placements as a secure
foundation, the Clubs will maintain their membership each year.
Industrial Supporters' Clubs also then encourage active permanent
recruitment of students, purchase by companies of consultancy
from the faculty, the provision of ideas and clients for student
projects as well as hosting valuable executive networking dinners
and social events. Commercial consultancy and student projects
provide contextual information for academic research. Without
the regular contact driven by summer placements, such clubs can
easily atrophy.
3. The third element of the Action Plan is
to develop future industries proactively, ie Industry Growth.
First identify an area where a university has an outstanding faculty
member working in a field with good industrial growth potential.
A good example would be to develop more of an industry based on
the recent House of Lords Report on "Chips with Everything".
Then our suggested approach is as follows:
Recruit, on secondment, a senior and
respected industrialist (a "Visiting Business Fellow")
to work full time in the target department to write the industrial
development plan. The plan needs to be done closely with the faculty
and agreed with the Head of Department. All available resources
should then be mobilised as part of a coherent plan eg:
Department graduates already working
in the target field should be identified and encouraged to join
the department's graduate association.
Related companies should be identified,
asked to join an Industrial Supporters Club and then recruit current
students, suggest projects and purchase consultancy.
Technical, business and social events
should be organised by the department on topics in the field.
These can take a wide variety of forms from executive networking,
industry case studies, academic briefings, problem solving workshops
and recruitment.
PR can be used to communicate the department's
business development goal and successes so far.
Next, attract more excellent faculty
in the department or from around the world to take up posts in
the field and join the group. Great faculty not only do good work
and but also attract outstanding students. Set up an MPhil programme
as well as taking on PhD students in the area. Include leadership
and entrepreneurial aptitude as admission criteria for some of
the faculty and students to ensure that the pool of people contains
a balance of leadership and academic excellence. IPR should be
ceded by the university to the faculty to both attract people
and make it easier to found companies. Entrepreneurs should be
invited to network with the graduate students so they may co-found
companies together. This is a key motor of cluster development.
Finally, a departmental support organisation
should be set up to help achieve the goal of industry growth.
The relevant activities fall under three headings:
Business development related:
(i) Strategic planning.
(ii) PR (including web site
editing).
(iii) Handling inbound queries
for consultancy and research.
Student careers related:
(i) Summer student placement
admin.
(ii) Industrial Supporters
Club sales and admin.
(iii) Student Careers Advice
(performed by the Careers Service).
Graduate association management related.
We propose therefore that an industry
development team room be set up containing 3 people full time
and having two further desks for team members. This should be
called the Action Plan Office. The team members should be:
1. Visiting Business Fellow doing the business
development activities above.
2. An Industrial Supporters Club manager who
recruits companies (who have to pay a Club membership fee) and
then persuades them to take summer students and recruit graduates.
3. A Director General for the graduate association.
4. A desk which is used by the Careers Service
person dedicated to the department and who should visit frequently.
5. A desk for someone from (what is known in
Cambridge as) Research Services Division to help smooth the way
to getting research contracts agreed from research funders.
The Graduate Association director general
will, at scale, be funded by individual membership subscriptions.
The Industrial Supporters' Club manager, at scale, will be more
than funded by corporate membership subscriptions. One may reasonably
expect these activities to generate a surplus. Before scale is
reached which may take 3 years or more, start-up costs will have
to be incurred. The incremental ongoing costs of the departmental
support organisation described above are limited to those of the
Visiting Business Fellow. Some suitable candidates might be found
who would work on a voluntary basis or on an honorarium but one
should budget conservatively on a cost of the Business Fellow
at £100,000. Based on the experience in the Cambridge University
Computer Lab costs will be in the order of:
One off start-up costs: £250,000.
Ongoing costs: up to £100,000 pa
from inception.
The measures of success of the Action
Plan are easy to identify:
People Flow is measured by strategic
industry participation and graduate earnings. This requires a
regular survey of graduate salary and employment; a common place
in professional associations.
Company Growth is measured by turnover,
profit and employment. The Hall of Fame should include these metrics.
Industry Growth is the aggregrate of
Company Growth.
COMPLEMENTARY INITIATIVES
IN THE
TOWN
Some modest complementary activities should
take place in the town to help industry cluster development:
Business management talent interested
in relocating to the area should be encouraged by providing an
agency or first point of contact to help them move in and find
contacts. They have to be helped to meet promising technical talent
so that they can jointly found and run companies.
Prize giving events should be held
for functional expertise eg in technology sales. This allows functional
knowledge sharing to occur. Such events have been commonplace
in the past for example amongst technicians and apprentices.
Investment in local schools should
be make it more attractive for couples to stay and bring up their
children in the area.
* * *
CONCLUSIONS: PEOPLE FLOW IS LOW COST AND
HIGH IMPACT
The mechanism by which universities catalyse
technology industry growth is complex and delicate but includes
an important people centric element. An integrated programme to
develop People Flow through a university department and into a
nascent local industry will help a technology cluster grow with
resulting substantial benefits. The programme requires a diverse
range of activities many of which need strong social leadership
to make them work.
People are more manageable than ideas. Encouraging
industrial sponsorship and research collaboration, downstreaming
research into businesses and investing in improving the university/academic
interface have all been tried as means of encouraging economic
growth but do not appear to be leading to the desired results
as fast as policy makers would like. Our submission is that people
centric investment will have a higher pay-off than current idea-centric
policy initiatives.
Recent work on the development of social capital
in technology clusters suggests that a further area of study could
involve understanding whether particular social protocols amongst
these groups engender desirable emergent phenomena. In other words,
cluster success may be partly explained by the fact that people
behave in certain ways towards each other. The attraction of this
for policy makers is that behaviours may be be identifiable and
replicable.
How can universities be encouraged to adopt
the Action Plan set out above? They already have substantial incentives
to attract good students and play a role in their subsequent career
success and the success of their companies. Good students want
to have good careers. Strong links into successful companies can
provide this. Faculty want ideas for research areas and outlets
for their work. Strong links into successful companies can provide
this as well. Universities as a whole are hoping to raise more
money from philanthropy in future. Future successful companies
and graduates who have derived a life time benefit from their
alma mater should make future fund raising more productive.
6 September 2004
|