Select Committee on Welsh Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Written evidence from Swansea Business School

MANUFACTURING AND TRADE IN WALES

PROBLEMS AND OPPORTUNITIES

Preamble

  A1.  The weaknesses of the Welsh economy are well known and there is little point in re-iterating them here. Furthermore, the relatively high dependency of the Welsh economy on manufacturing is also well known, as are the continued concerns about the decline in manufacturing in general and in Wales specifically.

  A2.  Economic development policy in Wales has until recently concentrated almost entirely on inward investing manufacturing concerns. Indeed, WDA statistics regularly report the strength of the manufacturing sector in Wales, although this is inevitably based on the activities of external, inward investing firms. It is however now widely accepted that the products of manufacturing concerns attracted to Wales are at the mature stage of their life cycles. All the technical development, design, marketing, distribution and financing is complete. Consequently the products are unsophisticated and are at the final stage of the life cycle. The aim is to sell as many as possible and reap the rewards before the product finally becomes obsolete. The skill level is basic and consequently pay is commensurate with limited skill.

  A3.  Inward investment it is often argued has a multiplier effect; local businesses are encouraged to supply goods and services, thus increasing the effectiveness of the original investment. The reality however is that suppliers exist in economic space but not in geographic space.

  A4.  Success has been associated with the single criterion of employment, whether in manufacturing or indeed of late, services. But wealth creation and economic development do not come solely from the provision of employment. In reality, success in employment provision has served to depress longer-term development because the skills required are entirely inappropriate to an economy pursuing self-sustaining growth. The skills required by inward investing manufacturing firms are largely basic assembly skills. Managerial, financial, research and development, engineering, technical and marketing skills drive the modern economy, but these remain firmly rooted outside Wales.

THE BASIC PROBLEM OF THE WELSH MANUFACTURING SECTOR

Three fundamental weaknesses in Welsh manufacturing can be identified

  B1.  FDI has been successful in providing employment but as countless surveys and reports have noted and to which reference has been made above, the products are inevitably at the end of life cycle; all the development and associated "quality" work is complete.

  B2.  There is a limited multiplier effect from FDI, which is again well known.

  B3.  More fundamentally, and a greater strategic problem for the future. The WDA's much publicised contemporary activities in the manufacturing sector are based upon products for which there is derived demand. It is products for which there is final demand that drive the economy, attract customer loyalty and are demand inelastic. The derived demand criticism can also be laid at the door of more recent FDI, such as the food industry.

AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACHTHE "DIAMOND" AND SPECIFIC PROPOSALS

  C1.  It is not therefore the intention of this submission to re-iterate these problems, enough has already been written about the problems of the Welsh economy and the role of manufacturing within it. The intention of this submission is to identify issues that have been omitted and to suggest alternative measures that might lead to further encouragement of the manufacturing sector.

  C2.  It is also assumed it is the intention of government at all levels that manufacturing is to remain at the heart of economic policy. Manufacturing is fundamental to economic well being, international competitiveness, an important source of employment, innovation, growth and fundamentally, can have a significant multiplier effect in the economy.

  C3.  Economic well being, especially in the regions, must to a great extent depend upon manufacturing and the productivity and competitiveness that it brings. Indeed, contemporary regional development policy rejects the previous piece meal approach to development and offers a more strategic approach based on Porter's "diamond" theory, the role of clusters and thus productivity and competitiveness. The weakness of the Welsh manufacturing sector and threats to it are not simply the problems of manufacturing per se but the fact that the sectors within which Welsh manufacturers operate are not providing the bases for the competitiveness critical to successful application of the diamond.

  C4.  The Swedish economist Gunnar Myrdal was one of the first economists to examine and consider the issues of regional and sub national economies. He described two generic economic systems—virtuous circles of growth and vicious circles of decline. Porter's work could form the basis of reversing what must be regarded as the current—and longstanding—vicious circle of decline of the Welsh economy.

  C5.  Economic success depends on a number of inter-related and complex factors, the most important of which is national competitiveness. This is, according to Porter, the nation's ability to achieve or maintain an advantageous position over the other nations in a number of key industrial sectors.

  C6.  This submission might be a timely reminder of Porter's diamond theory, which updates and draws upon a long tradition of economics and indeed regional economics by developing the idea of what is essentially cluster theory. This theory suggests that, given certain circumstances, firms gain advantages that provide mutual strengthening and thus competitive advantage. This idea has its roots in the much earlier work of Marshall (agglomeration economics), Myrdhal (vicious and virtuous circles) and the "stratified diversification" adopted by the Tennessee Valley Authority during the great depression. It is perhaps worthwhile outlining the ideas behind the diamond theory

THE "DIAMOND" APPROACH

  D1.  The most successful competitive advantages are achieved when a set of four key competitiveness enhancing elements are in place. These four elements mutually reinforce one another and generate a situation of cumulative causation. It is, according to Porter, "a mutually reinforcing system" and that "the effect of one determinant is contingent upon the state of the others". However, what is implied in the diamond approach is that the successful application of the entire approach relies essentially on success in two sectors of the economy, manufacturing excellence and new firm formation.

  D2.  The first of these four elements are the demand conditions, requiring a strong sophisticated and demanding home market with an international outlook. Pressure is brought to bear on local firms by local consumers to ensure they are innovative and responsive to changes in taste, leading to strong competition amongst firms. Particular emphasis is placed on home demand as the driving force in providing the impetus to upgrade, innovate and compete. Businesses are sensitive to the demands of their closest customers thus the characteristics of home demand are fundamental in driving competition. Specific demand conditions include—inter alia—a healthy local economy, sophisticated and demanding buyers, a rate of growth in the home market and fundamentally, segmentation and specialisation in products.

  D3.  The second element is factor conditions. Factors of production are developed and refined over time with highly specialised factors being distinguished from general factors. There is a significant difference between "basic factors"—natural resources, climate, location—and "advanced factors"—sophisticated skills, education levels, research facilities, economic infrastructure. The latter is the more significant for competitive advantage because whilst basic factors may be regarded as somehow endowed (such as coal in South Wales), advanced factors are a result of investment by individuals, businesses and government. However, the most successful basis for competitive advantage is specialised advanced factors. Specific factor conditions include—inter alia—human resources such as skills, physical resources (such as land and climate), technical and scientific knowledge and education, infrastructure, including telecommunications.

  D4.  The third is firm strategy, structure and rivalry: This requires the best possible environment, within which firms can be created, organised and managed. This requires a particular form of corporate governance and industrial and market structure.

  Specific factor conditions include—inter alia—strategic awareness by the individual organisation, organisational structure, organisational objectives and sustained commitment, managerial practices and attitudes and national culture, prestige and priority.

  D5.  Central to this element is the role of new firms. Domestic rivalry—and the subsequent competitive advantage—depends on the creation of new businesses to create new competitors. Porter notes that

    "invention and entrepreneurship are at the heart of national advantage"

    but requires a favourable environment;

    "what looks like chance (in new business creation) is actually differences in national environments".

  D6.  There is a hidden problem which serves to depress those factors required for the diamond approach to succeed and thus the main aim of regional policy, that of self sustaining growth. This problem is that of organisation size. Large organisations with products at the end of the life cycle require employees with limited skills, specific to that particular product. These skills are of little or no use elsewhere. This has been the weakness of the Welsh economy, and is a weakness that is likely to continue with present policies. The size structure of employing organisations is the important, indeed fundamental determinant of new firm formation. There is a growing body of literature, based on empirical research which strongly suggests a causal link between the number of new firms in any given economy and economic growth and well being. Research undertaken in 2002 for Barclays Bank sought to identify regions with greater entrepreneurial potential. The research confirmed the findings of countless researchers over the past 20 years, that the number of small firms in an area is a fundamental determinant of new firm formation.

  D7.  The relationship between economic change and the effect of organisational size cannot be over emphasised. The extent to which a local economy is dominated by large or small organisations is the main determining influence on the rate at which new firms are set up and thus economic health. Large plants do not make good incubators because of their mechanistic structures and need for specialist and often product specific skills. These skills are of little or no use to employees who may consider establishing a new firm. The larger the incubator (in employment terms), the lesser the number of potential new firm founders, small incubators are the most prolific in providing new firm founders. There is a clear statistical relationship between incubator size and spin off; the number of individuals leaving to start a new firm will decline as incubator size increases. There is consistent evidence that small plants lead to successful development of an indigenous business sector. Indeed, it is the major factor. There is a simple reason for this; small organisations need and develop many skills; large plants inevitably develop individuals with a single, product specific skill, entirely useless in any other work situation.

  This is what I have called the "causal chain." The number of new firms is determined by the number of small firms (because of the greater spin off rate), which in turn directly determines economic well being.

  D8.  The fourth and final are related and supporting industries. Ready access to supply chains and close proximity to related industries. Investment in advanced factors has a "spill over" effect, successful businesses group into clusters, mutually reinforcing innovation, competition and development. Economies external to the individual firm are internalised within the industry cluster This is a development of cluster theory and requires—inter alia—internally competitive suppliers, related industries, domestic suppliers and appropriate managerial and technical personnel.

  D9.  The key to understanding the diamond model and indeed to its successful application is interaction between these factors; it is this interaction that establishes and sustains competitive advantage. Take for example a link between demand conditions and factor conditions. A strong home demand for a particular commodity will stimulate firms into training and education, which leads to a distinctive uniquely skilled workforce. This in turn provides a skill level that maintains the nation's competitive advantage. Similarly, groups of rival firms competing with each other (firm strategy, structure and rivalry) encourages specialist suppliers to establish to provide external economies and a specific supply chain (related and supporting industries) thus enhancing competitive advantage.

  D10.  Porter's model has changed the thinking on national (and regional) economic development, moving the emphasis from national natural advantage to national competitiveness and the role within that of business. It provides an interesting and challenging model of economic development, although it can be argued that, at the present time, Wales lacks many of the individual factor attributes required by the model and is unlikely to develop them in the foreseeable future.

  D11.  However, the model itself is open to criticism. The first and obvious is the sample; the countries used by Porter included three of the world's leading economies with economic and cultural environment fundamentally different to Wales—and for the matter Great Britain. Furthermore, it largely ignores the role of government, which can be central to certain developments such as education. In addition, cluster theory is not new and there is the dangers that clusters and the businesses involved can themselves become non-competitive and complacent if worldwide competition fails to emerge. Finally, there has been some criticism of late of the whole approach to clusters.

  D12.  It is not suggested that the adoption of the so-called diamond model is the panacea for the Welsh economy and Welsh manufacturing. What it does is to reject a piece meal approach and consequently the need for a clear strategy with full support and resources from all levels of government.

  D13.  The problems of the Welsh economy being based on goods for which there is a derived demand (and to which reference is made in section b) is graphically illustrated by examining existing clusters. Statistics provided by the dti (2003) list 14 Welsh clusters in all. The largest clusters are in metal processing, employing 36,000; electronics which includes both components and television and associated products (based mainly on inward investment) employing 22,000 and automotive components employing 12,000. For completeness, it should of course be noted that the largest cluster of all is agriculture and livestock, employing over 54,000. There is no recognisable cluster of creative industries or biotechnology outside the health service; toys and games employs 2,000. Interestingly, the one sector often identified as typifying the "new" Welsh economy —aerospace—employs just 5,650, mostly in Flintshire, but not, arguably, in any form of cluster.

SPECIFIC PROPOSALS

  E1.  If it is the wish of the committee to investigate ways in which the manufacturing sector might be encouraged and improved in Wales (and for that matter throughout the UK) and the ideas behind the diamond approach notwithstanding, then there has to be radical programme, probably driven both by WAG, its agencies with support and funding from central government. There is little point in examining and repeating the many problems facing the Welsh economy and of course, Welsh manufacturing. It is important that academics interested in helping to resolve these problems, in addition to presenting appropriate models of growth and change, suggest practical ways in which such ideas can remove these problems and improve the economy. Before doing so however, it is worth re-emphasising the appeal made by Cardiff Business School in its position paper presented to this committee, that there is a strong case for establishing a system that records accurately changes taking place in the economy. Academics and government policy makers continue to work in the dark,

  E2.  First and foremost. Almost all government and quasi-government financial schemes (and indeed the measurement of economic success) are linked in some way to job creation criteria. In reality, productivity gain and competitiveness often result in little additional labour and indeed the shedding of labour. This job creation criterion should be removed.

  E3.  A fundamental change in the way that FDI schemes are evaluated is suggested. For FDI schemes, the adoption of the Production Mandate concept as developed in Canada, is suggested. Incentives are offered on the basis of a "production mandate" prerogative. The idea is to attract and encourage investor with new products and processes. Financial and other incentives remain, but offered on the basis of the amount of "mandate" (ie autonomy) given to local management to purchase locally, the amount of mandate to undertake research and development, product development and innovation at the Welsh site.

  E4.  The main government scheme of financial support is Regional Selective Assistance under the terms of the 1982 Industry Act. This scheme has been heavily criticised in England. In February 2004 the House of Commons Public Accounts Committee severely criticised the scheme, noting that it had largely failed to impact upon unemployment or improve the relative wealth of the poorer English regions. Improvements in manufacturing emanate from productivity gains and inevitably the use of high technology. The basis upon which RSA is decided works against the encouragement of productive manufacturing and the scheme should be used to improve productivity and competitiveness. This scheme should be simplified and made more relevant.

  Specifically, remove the job creation criteria and make the scheme more transparent. In addition to the job creation criteria, present awards under the scheme are based on the twin concepts of "additionality" and "viability". However, the additionality criteria and the viability criteria are mutually exclusive. If, to quote the scheme "the project will not go ahead in time or scale without assistance from the public sector" then the project was probably not viable in the first place.

  E5 .  Remove the additionality concept for all publicly funded schemes. The criticism of "additionality" noted above applies to almost all public funding schemes and should be removed. Consider a "reverse" additionality; investment and support is based on what the initial investment further develops in terms of further additional spending outside the organisation.

  E6.  There are specific schemes, some current and others no longer available that directly encourage, assist or expand schemes that improve productivity and competitiveness:

  SEFIS—the Small Firms Engineering Investment Scheme was available throughout the UK in the early 1980s. Its intention was to assist small firms to purchase new advanced capital equipment. A grant of 30% was available, paid as of right upon invoice. A very successful scheme, although to some extent regionally imbalanced and the funds were quickly used up.

  The WDA has a similar programme (TEP), which can provide a grant of 50% of cost to a maximum of £10,000. However, the scheme is not straightforward. It is based on additionality, is aimed at a so-called "technical step" (rather than straight purchase of capital equipment) and requires support and clearance from the Innovation Technology Council.

  The original SMART scheme aimed to provide a grant of up to 25% for new product and/or process development and was straightforward. The WDA's replacement scheme (SMART Cymru) was launched in September 2003, is a phased scheme with grants of up to 75% at the initial development stage. However, the application process is complex and the scheme is again additional.

  E7.  A more imaginative approach to funding. Public funding sources—especially investing funds rather than grant aid—should not be awarded on the basis of investment return criteria. The problem is the appropriateness of funds and the delivery mechanism. There have been arguments made in the past for some form of development bank, although with a remit to be more adventurous. There are, according to the Rowntree Foundation problems with debt and failure to repay "soft" loans, the SFLGS is relatively expensive and there still remains the problem of addressing the equity gap. Whatever the requirements of due diligence, a more adventurous approach from Finance Wales should be required.

  E8.  Provision of manufacturing incubator units and funding for their development along the lines of the Business Incubator Fund available in England. Such a fund would assist all manufacturing and not simply high technology.

  E9.  Adoption of the SME tax incentives that have proved so successful in Ireland and elsewhere. The success of the Republic of Ireland has highlighted the use of taxation as an important tool in economic development since it can be manipulated to encourage economic growth. Zero tax rates have been offered in the past, and taxation rates as low as 10% have been available to manufacturing concerns that export. Corporation tax in Ireland has been as low as 12½%, compared to 30% in the UK. In addition, capital allowances have been used to encourage investment. The significance is that tax incentives and capital allowances encourage successful, profitable and growing business. In addition to tax incentives, the IDA does not use grant aid as the single tool of economic development. Investors have been offered equity in place of grant; any grant aid that was offered was conditional upon a strategic and measurable growth programme, including training, use of local suppliers and encouragement of local management and not—as has been the case in Wales—solely upon the provision of employment. The focus has been on emerging sectors such as the health care, electronics, software, high technology and more recently, e-commerce. In addition, the IDA is separated into two functions. One deals with inward investors, the other with encouraging indigenous business. The two have successfully worked side by side; inward investors are required to source within Ireland, thus the skills and training levels of the newly introduced industries reflect in local firms.

THE NEW FIRM AND SME SECTOR IN WALES—SOME POTENTIAL SUCCESS INDICATORS

  F1.  This brief paper is based on research into new firms in West Glamorgan, which began trading between 1980 and 1987. The research was in two stages; firstly all new firms (within a strict definition of newness) were identified, these amounted to 2,509 in total. This provided an insight into the general direction new firms were taken the local economy. Secondly, field research was then undertaken between 1990 and 1991 on a sample of 300 of these, which included both surviving and non-surviving firms. Employment data was as at 1991. Although on the face of it the data appear dated, this is the most recent in-depth research into new firms in Wales.

  F2.  In general, successful firms established in sectors that had a larger "market footprint". This means that the product or service could be "exported" from the region and/or was of use in the provision of external economies though not necessarily, it should be emphasised, as simply sub-contractors. This concept of the larger "market footprint" is very much in keeping with research undertaken throughout the UK.

  F3.  Of the 2,509, supposed "mature" industries played an important role. Activities 3,410 to 3,480 of the 1980 Standard Industrial Classification represent advanced engineering practices, as do those industries involved in the general machine shop. Fifty firms were involved in these Activities and accounted for one third of all firms in Division 3 (Metal Goods and Engineering). A great deal of this was due to the role of new technology-based equipment in lowering barriers to entry and increasing productivity.

  F4.  In Division 4 (Other Manufacturing) 103 firms (39% of the Division) established in innovative or high technology sectors. Of these, 21 firms (8%) were in activities classified as high technology. The classification of innovation and high technology were based on research elsewhere. Many of these were not necessarily "innovative" in a technical sense, but were based on and provided development capability, often because of the type of product or the market footprint. Examples include Toys and Games, Plastic Products and Travel Goods, products that further develop skills and, more importantly, customer (market) commitment.

  F5.  Other sectors that were successful were printing, repackaging, repairs (not motor repairs), nursing homes and (surprisingly) plant hire and civil engineering. Personal services were also notable, especially fitness centres, sporting facilities and training and educational establishments. Interestingly, the first three were operated on manufacturing principles.

  F6.  A balanced team approach was stronger in manufacturing; successful firms had a balance of technical, marketing and administration skills in their founders, or in some cases recruited these skills early on. Two thirds of firms that survive had such a balanced team approach.

  F7.  Fifty-six per cent of firms used personal savings, either as the sole source or with bank lending. The data are unclear, due to clouding by multiple funding packages, but 43% of firms which funding only on debt failed very early on.

  F8.  Perhaps the most interesting aspect of this research was the employment generation, which was substantial. There was a notable contrast between employment created by new firms and by inward investment. During the period 1983 to 1987 (the temporal data available on inward investment at that time), 2,975 jobs were provided or safeguarded by WDA and (then) Welsh Office activities. However, during the same period, new firms that did not exist before 1980 had created almost 2,000 jobs. It is important to note that the jobs created by new firms was a sample of 12% whereas the employment quoted for traditional policy was for all organisations. It is therefore clear that in all probability, new firms actually created far more jobs than inward investors. The 255 firms still trading in 1991 employed just less than 3,500, of which 65% were in manufacturing.

  F9.  The research also pointed to a number of other issues:

    —  new firms played an important role in diversification ie moving the economy away from large employers and the public sector;

    —  one in 10 firms were in high technology sectors (including those classified as services by the Standard Industrial Classification eg Software Houses);

    —  substantial proportion of employment provided was for skilled employees;

    —  over half of the firms established with capital costs of less than £5,000 and a third for less than £2,000;

    —  the majority of employment came from only a few new firms;

    —  the service sector accounted for almost 80% of all new firms. This is again important because traditionally it is in the service sector that Wales lags behind. The majority of employment was however in new manufacturing firms; and

    —  the manufacturing base was maintained in the face of contemporary economic collapse.

  F10.  This research also points to a previously unrecognised phenomenon. Growth in new firms appears to be related to the amount of turbulence within the economy. It therefore follows that if an economy is static and dominated by one or a few employers, the rate of indigenous growth is likely to be small.

RECENT EVIDENCE ON THE SME SECTOR

  G1.  As a part of this submission, brief research was undertaken to establish the current position of those new manufacturing firms that had completed the original questionnaire between 1990 and 1991.

  G2.  Of the original 106 manufacturing firms that completed the original questionnaire, 30 were found still to be trading, a survival rate of 28%, substantially higher than the 4% or so suggested by research. Of these, 23 completed a brief questionnaire.

  G3.  The 23 firms came into being at different times between 1980 and 1987. However, the total employment in 1991 was 354; current total employment is 434, an increase of 23%.

  G4.  Of these firms, 11 were in "other manufacturing" and in engineering, all of which represented advanced engineering practices.

  G5.  Only six of the 23 firms had contacted a public sector advisory service within the recent past and 10 reported that all or most of their suppliers were regarded as local ie within south Wales.

  G6.  Updating the original data continues as part of a wider research project at Swansea Business School.

  However, what this initial brief analysis clearly shows is a greater than expected survival rate of new manufacturing firms, employment gain and a substantial multiplier. It also calls into question the role of the wider advisory services, in keeping with the original research. The importance of these preliminary research findings is not the numbers but in the magnitude of the growth in employment and the need for critical mass in terms of new firm formation.

Dr John Ball

12 March 2004





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 24 February 2005