Select Committee on Communities and Local Government Committee Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 140-159)

MR JOHN CALCUTT, MR TREVOR BEATTIE AND MR DENNIS HONE

8 MAY 2006

  Q140  John Cummings: But you argue that a modest rate of PGS can be absorbed in some areas. What would be a modest rate for my area in the North East, do you think?

  Mr Beattie: It is not for us to take a view on that. We have run it through at a rate of 20% and the figures are there in our consultation response.

  Q141  Mr Betts: You are the experts in development, are you not? You know what works and what does not work, so I think we have an interest in knowing what your view is of the rate.

  Mr Beattie: We think at 20% it works. Can I give an example of why I think at 20% it works which I know reasonably well? One of our examples is a greenfield site where at 20% the take from PGS and section 106 under the new system is greater than the existing section 106 take. If you run at a rate of 15%, interestingly the old and the new system takes are exactly the same. That is for a greenfield site needing substantial infrastructure. That suggests to me that for that sort of site, that is roughly the right area.

  Q142  John Cummings: I am trying to tease a bit more out of you here. Is the rate of PGS which could be absorbed before PGS becomes a disincentive to investment consistent across the country or does it vary with different types of development and different locations?

  Mr Beattie: It varies very dramatically. On page 8 of our consultation document we show that the PGS rate at which PGS and new section 106 would equate to the old 106 for greenfield sites actually varies between 7% and 22.5%. So it is very variable site to site.

  Q143  John Cummings: You have mentioned the PGS rate set at 20%, is this a cash equivalent of developers' contributions to infrastructure provision, or would it actually be less under PGS than it is at present?

  Mr Beattie: That depends on the site, it depends on the section 106 obligations already on the site. As I was explaining, on some sites the new system under our figures shows you will be paying less, on some it shows you will be paying more.

  Q144  John Cummings: Why do you argue that only a low rate of PGS can be accommodated?

  Mr Beattie: Because the new system will apply comprehensively to development across the piece. It is equitable in that respect in that it applies to development across the piece, whereas currently only about 40% of development is subject to section 106 obligations.

  Q145  Mr Betts: Is there a case for a variable rate?

  Mr Beattie: I do not think so, no. We were talking about clarity and certainty and a complex range of different rates would obstruct that clarity and certainty. We have, however, suggested there might be a case for a discount of the rate for five-star environmental developments, actually linking up fiscal policy and environmental policy. We think there is a great opportunity to do that here. But a framework of different rates—no.

  Q146  Mr Olner: It is okay having planning gain supplement if that raises more revenue for infrastructure than 106 does, but if you are going to have a rigid 106 system and it is argued the reason for bringing in planning gain supplement is that some authorities are better at negotiating 106 agreements than others, there is going to be some disparity. How do we bridge that? Mr Hone is nodding so he knows what I am saying.

  Mr Hone: It is obvious if you apply a constant rate across the country, it will have different impacts in different areas. English Partnerships are not saying it will not. What we are saying is that if you are bringing in planning gain supplement, you need to do it in a way which gives absolute clarity to the developers. We are sub-dividing, as it were, the section 106 negotiations because certain elements are staying under section 106 and others are going under planning gain supplement. From a development point of view, that is a benefit if they gain certainty through that and there is a value to that certainty. When we look at the consistency argument, it is important we have a consistent rate.

  Mr Calcutt: To add slightly on that, I think you substitute the characteristics of the site for the planning skills and abilities of the local authority which is doing the negotiations. In other words, obviously you are going to lose the input of what I would call key negotiators, but on the other hand you are going to more equitably distribute the tax insofar as its impact, as I understand it, is going to be those intrinsically difficult sites with low inherent land values which are automatically going to have a lesser tax payment than those which are intrinsically more valuable in areas where you need less infrastructure. That seems to me to be a level of equity that is wholly desirable rather than, as it were, key negotiating powers bringing about an anomaly.

  Q147  Mr Olner: But in shire counties the major planning authority is the district, and it is usually the district which does the negotiation on 106. How widely is that going to be spread in the future? As I said before, you have local infrastructure to provide, the local authority ones, you have regional, the shire county ones, and then you have national ones. At the moment you have one clear negotiator for the section 106 stuff. It seems to me that this issue is going to be clouded in the future in providing infrastructure because it does not only rest with one set of people.

  Mr Beattie: There will continue to be one clear negotiator for the site-specific element of section 106, but for the national infrastructure there will be the Communities Infrastructure Fund.

  Q148  Mr Olner: So it is essential that as well as planning gain supplement there is also section 106 agreement as well?

  Mr Beattie: Under this new system, site-specific infrastructure will continue to be negotiated in the same way but for a narrower range of facilities.

  Q149  John Pugh: I think we are reaching a view that you accept there is going to be a degree of diversity, although we are not in a position to be able to say how much diversity and what degree of clarity we are going to have here, but taken in the round you also seem to be saying that the new system will generate more money by increased land values for the public good than the previous section 106 agreements by themselves. That is fairly common ground, is it not?

  Mr Beattie: Yes.

  Q150  John Pugh: Do you think it is going to be significantly more to the extent there will be a real substantial uplift in the amount of money available for strategic infrastructure?

  Mr Calcutt: Can I start and then let my colleagues come in? I think it depends how you are drafting the tax. We have seen previous attempts to tax windfall gains and they have run into enormous efficiency problems insofar as the cost of administration and all the rest, and things get locked up in litigation for years, and the actual take is poor. I think there are two sides to whether you achieve it. Does it in principle, yield more and everybody paid their due amount? The numbers equation is, as I understand it, that it would raise significantly more revenue. On the other hand, if in fact practically the way the tax is administered results in it being bogged down with every chartered surveying company and legal firm inside the country and offshore, then clearly as a matter of practice you are not going to get the revenue take you want. So the devil is in the drafting of detail which enables this thing to be what I would call efficiently administered.

  Q151  John Pugh: So when the regulation and legislation come forward, there is a need for real scrutiny?

  Mr Calcutt: As a former lawyer, I would say this is going to be a parliamentary draftsman's either nightmare or paradise, I know not which. Certainly the devil is in the detail here.

  Q152  John Pugh: If the planning gain supplement raises less than section 106 does at present, does that mean in fact the tax rate is too low or that the purpose of the introduction of PGS itself is frustrated?

  Mr Calcutt: I am going to push my luck here and say to you that the dilemma is that if you set the tax rate too high then clearly the incentives people have for going down the route that I have described in terms of trying to avoid paying this thing with schemes or just withholding it in the hope that it will change in the future, which is a common one, and again go up on a curve, and so part of the cleverness of this, I think, is first the drafting but also setting rates at a point at which perhaps people's incentive for avoidance is not going to be as high as it otherwise might have been.

  Q153  John Pugh: So the Government, like a good parasite, should not kill off its host?

  Mr Beattie: One or two of the proposals in our consultation paper were designed exactly to hit this point. We argue that the payment should be phased; it should not all be up front at the point of starting on site but, as happens as present in Milton Keynes, it should be 25% up front and 75% on completion so you can give an incentive through the operation of the system for developers to come forward with sites.

  Q154  John Pugh: How long do you think it is going to take the land markets to adjust to the new regime?

  Mr Beattie: One of our submissions is that the transitional arrangements for this are going to be absolutely crucial. I do not think it will take the markets terribly long to adjust. I think the short term impact will in many cases be a reduction in the value of sites because the PGS will in effect be taken off the site value. That might work in favour of those of us trying to bring forward major strategic developments but there is going to be a period of transition, it is going to be very important to protect the tariff arrangements in that transition and markets will certainly swing around before they stabilise under the new system.

  Q155  John Pugh: In arguing for greater simplicity and clarity, as you have, do you think there should be a scheme that allows a very few exemptions rather than a lot of well argued, cogent exemptions?

  Mr Beattie: Yes. I do not see the need for exemptions. If you have a site with very little or no value you will pay no tax. On brownfield sites, as we have shown in our case studies, where there is very little uplift, there will be little planning gain supplement to pay, and by and large on serious brownfield sites there is less tax under the new system than under the old system. It is to some extent a self-regulating tax: the more uplift, the more tax.

  Q156  John Cummings: What is the merit of exempting sites with option agreements from PGS liability?

  Mr Calcutt: As a former developer perhaps I am qualified to answer on this one.

  Q157  John Cummings: I thought you said you were a lawyer.

  Mr Calcutt: I was the company solicitor and subsequently I became chief executive of a major house builder, and so I do both, I am afraid. I think that "option" is a generic term for those parcels of land that have been secured on fixed terms that we are holding at the moment, so it will cover conditional contracts, options, uplifts and the like. The only point there is that lots of developers and house builders have entered into agreements that provide for a specific sum to be paid on the grant of planning permission and in the event that a tax is then levied on that those contracts will probably plunge the developments themselves into deficit or sub-normal profits which again will have one of two effects. You will either have people carrying out the very sorts of avoidance tricks they can get away with or, much more probably, simply sitting on land, not bringing it forward for development, causing housing supply to move sharply downwards, trying to wait out the consequences of a bad contract. I think it would have very undesirable effects and would damage the house building industry. Whether that is a good or a bad thing I do not know.

  Q158  Mr Betts: Would there not be a case then for saying that if sites with option agreements on them are going to be exempt that exemption only applies for a period of time to encourage the development of those sites because once the time runs out there is not going to be the exemption?

  Mr Calcutt: That does sound as though it would have quite a lot of merit in it. The only thing I would say is that quite a lot of options and conditional contracts take land now 10 years before it comes forward and it is then promoted through the planning system and therefore we are talking about very long timescales here. I think the sort of thing that you are talking about might well be able to be achieved by other means.

  Mr Beattie: Linking the planning system to it.

  Q159  Mr Betts: You might like to reflect on that and let us have a note about it because I understand it is a technical issue. Perhaps you would like to give us a note after the meeting on your further thoughts on that. Let us come back to the point we were discussing before about your general commitment to hypothecating planning gain supplement going to the local authority where the development is taking place. I heard what you said about English Partnerships being the knight in shining armour that goes into places like the coalfields and assists where there is not the money for infrastructure development around, but is there not a danger that if we concentrate all or the vast majority of the resources from planning gain supplement in those areas with high land values we are simply going to add to the overheating in those areas?

  Mr Beattie: We are also going to provide more resource in order to tackle the consequences in terms of strategic infrastructure of that overheating. You will be generating more resources where you need more strategic infrastructure. You have to have a body like English Partnerships in existence to deal with areas like the coalfields, but this generates resource where it is needed.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 7 November 2006