Select Committee on Constitutional Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 140-149)

NICK STARLING, JUSTIN JACOBS, DOMINIC CLAYDEN AND PHIL RUSE

10 JANUARY 2006

  Q140  Dr Whitehead: Would it be, for example, a good idea to include before-the-event insurance on all policies, so that you would not have to take out after-the-event insurance, and would that have a substantial impact were that to be done?

  Justin Jacobs: I think ultimately it has to be customer choice, and the market cannot decide actually that it will force people to buy before-the-event insurance because that would be anti-competitive, but it is a product that is out there and it is often attached to motor insurance, for example, and it has to be customer choice about whether they wish to take that up.

  Q141  Dr Whitehead: When you say "cannot force it", would any sort of code, or arrangement, or agreement such as you have on the success fees, be the sort of mechanism which might replace compulsion but bring about a beneficial result?

  Justin Jacobs: I think if insurers as a market said, "We are only going to sell X policies if they include before-the-event", no, that would be anti-competitive according to the competition law.

  Q142  Dr Whitehead: You would not advocate, for example, changing competition law then?

  Justin Jacobs: No, I think that would be quite difficult.

  Dominic Clayden: I can add to that. For example, in the motor market there is evidence to show that the level of take up of before-the-event insurance is in the range of 80 to 90%, so there is a real take up of it, and we would certainly prefer people to use that in preference to the more expensive options, and we believe solicitors should look at that. In any event, if before-the-event was a blanket across the board, there would be a group of claimants who have suffered injuries who would not ordinarily be covered. For example, pedestrians would not necessarily have the coverage, so in the current system there would be a place for after-the-event insurance, and we are not per se against it. We have concerns how the system operates in part, but we are not desperately against all of it.

  Q143  David Howarth: Can I take you back to the answer you gave to me earlier about the tariff system? I am trying to think through why you are suggesting this, and I am puzzled by something. I am obviously just missing something. At present what happens—and I know this from personal experience—is that the initial offer to the victim from the insurance company is rather low and then, as you say, it is then haggled up. If there is a tariff and the tariff is based on the existing law, that at first sight would mean that insurance companies would be losing, because instead of getting some people to settle at below the tariff rate they would now be settling at the tariff rate. That means that the savings that you would make in terms of lower transaction cost—that is those lower haggling costs—must outweigh that difference; but that then the raises the question of why you do not do this now. Why do not you just offer people more at the tariff rate at that set in the well-known practitioners' books like Kemp and Kemp and save yourselves this money from the start?

  Nick Starling: Can I make a general comment about that, and I think Dominic will want to answer the specific point. Insurers want to pay appropriate compensation, and, as I said I think earlier, it is for society to decide what those levels of compensation are, and those levels of compensation are then reflected in the premiums that you pay, that we all pay, and I think that is a fundamental to the way we approach things. A tariff system just makes it clear what levels can be expected for relatively straightforward accidents. We do not have that at the moment, and I think that leads to the sort of negotiation and discussion which happens now with the system.

  Q144  David Howarth: But we sort of do, do we not? Through the Judicial Studies Board's tariff and through the leading practitioners' works like Kemp and Kemp we do have a tariff. My own experience of this negotiation was as follows. Insurance company to my wife, who had been injured: "We will offer you £500." My wife to the insurance company: "I have looked it up in Kemp and Kemp. It is more than £4,000." Insurance company: "Okay, here is 4,000." Why do we need to go through that iteration? Why did they not just say, "Here is £4,000"?

  Dominic Clayden: I think that what we are identifying as part of the difficulty with the current system, that what we see on a number of occasions is a situation where the claimant lawyer will, when asked for the current figure, pitch at a figure which is very high, and we do go through this horse trading to get to what is an end position which happens at present. What we are suggesting is that those transactional costs should be avoided and we cut to the chase and have a system with a tariff that produces the level of settlements that we are currently achieving at the moment.

  Q145  David Howarth: So this seems to work by getting the lawyers to accept what is in the tariff, you are saying?

  Dominic Clayden: What we believe is that the tariff should be subject to transparency and independent scrutiny. We would not wish to as an insurance industry impose numbers. We believe that should be by discussion with stakeholders.

  Justin Jacobs: There is an additional point as well in having transparency for the claimant, because there are the JSB guidelines, there is a lot of case law. It is not as simple as saying that any independent claimant can work out what they are entitled to. We think there is a strong advantage in the claimant being able to see, "I have had this injury. I know therefore I am entitled to this amount." It is both good for them so they know when they are getting a fair offer and also good in relation to the problem we first talked about in terms of clause 1, in terms of managing expectation so that people know what they are entitled to both in terms of how high it is or how low it is, depending on which angle the claimant is coming from.

  Q146  Chairman: Later today we will be hearing from voluntary organisations who are at the sharp end of all these perceptions about compensation culture, and it is quite possible they might refer to the insurance industry and to either their difficulty in securing insurance for some activities and ventures or the conditions the insurers might impose, which could be a discouragement from carrying out these activities, the very issue which clause 1 at a different level seeks to address: balancing desirable activities against all the issues around risk management. Are you the villains of the piece? What would be your answer?

  Nick Starling: We are certainly not the villains of the piece. What the insurance industry wants to do is to encourage sensible risk management, and, for all activities, if you manage risks sensibly and appropriately, then you do not get into trouble. That is the broad principle we take. We try and encourage it. We issued a publication last year on precisely this and directed at the voluntary community. We are very happy to send that to you if we have not done so already. It just sets out the basic rules about ensuring you manage your risks effectively.

  Q147  Chairman: Obviously not just the voluntary community, the public authority sector, the local authority sector in particular, for example, will sometimes cite the same reasons: "Our insurer has told us that if we did this we would have to up the premium or install this that or the other." In the voluntary community it is even harder because of the time and expertise available on the part of volunteers to meet some of these demands.

  Nick Starling: I think that you quite often have to look behind the stories here, but before I joined the insurance industry I was in the Health and Safety Executive where the line was always, "Health and Safety will not allow it." Now I have joined the insurance industry they say, "Insurance will not allow it." Sometimes that means that people have not actually bought the insurance, which is slightly different. Quite often it means that people cannot be bothered, to be honest. I am not saying that your witnesses who are coming up are saying this, but people do not want to think about it, do not want to manage the risk sensibly and use insurance as a bit of a scapegoat. In most of the cases where people say, "Insurance will not allow it", you will find generally it is people over interpreting, being risk averse, not having the right insurance, and we think that is a situation that does not need to be and should not have been.

  Q148  Chairman: Is there anything more you can do to challenge the perception on which that is based, to say, "Yes, of course there is insurance available. No, it does not cost much more money. No, it is not incredibly bureaucratic and beyond the abilities of a scout troop or a church organisation to meet our very limited requirements"?

  Nick Starling: We are extremely keen to participate in this wider risk debate, and the Prime Minister, you will recall, gave a speech on this in May which we supported. As I said, we have issued publications and the next witnesses have started a very interesting debate about this and we are very keen to do this. Sensible risk management is usually commonsense. It is taking the risk in the first place in a managed way, seeing what might go wrong and seeing if you have got mechanisms deal with it, and insurance is there to help you do that. It is not the villain of the piece in stopping it. My own personal advice is if anyone ever says to you, "My insurance company will not let me", ask them what the insurance company has actually said and whether it is simply a matter of not having the cover or not having spoken to the right people.

  Q149  Chairman: Have you come across any cases where the premium you think you are obliged to require in order to meet your level of risk actually turns out to be disproportionate to the amount of money which can be found from, let us say, the parents or whoever else it may be, to fund the particular activity? Have you come across a situation, "We have to admit actually it would cost more to insure than we think could reasonably be raised around this voluntary activity"?

  Nick Starling: I have not.

  Dominic Clayden: I cannot think of a particular example. What I can add in that debate is that how we assess premiums is quite simple, and we look at what we assess the potential claims cost to be and the potential frequency of those claims costs and that helps to build the potential cost of a premium, and that does create difficulties in, for example, riding schools, which was a particular feature, where unfortunately potential claims costs in those establishments historically have been large, and that in itself drives large premiums into an environment where it may be difficult to pass those costs on and it may have an impact on people's ability to enjoy it.

  Justin Jacobs: I think the consequence of that is that the industry is doing everything it can to understand this better and to price premiums according to those risk levels. Naturally therefore the result is that if companies, voluntary organisations and others are managing their risks effectively, those organisations, companies, charities will find competitive insurance. Equally, however, we have to recognise that if there are organisations which are not managing their risks   effectively, despite support and help and encouragement to do so, then the result is that they will find their insurance is higher because that is the nature of effective risk pricing. Those who manage their risk well will benefit, but those who do not, for whatever reason, will find themselves facing high premiums.

  Chairman: Gentlemen, thank you very much indeed for your help this afternoon.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 10 March 2006