Select Committee on Culture, Media and Sport Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 520-539)

DCMS, DTI

10 JANUARY 2006

  Q520  Helen Southworth: Is the focus on getting affordability into the general mainstream set-top boxes? Because you are going to be looking at affordability for people, within your evidence you have said that some people might not afford more sophisticated products required by their specific needs, you are looking at treating that completely separately, rather than trying to get it into mainstream affordability?

  Alun Michael: Is that not partly referring to the question of the extent to which there is interoperability between the receiver of the signal and therefore it is not just a question of the issue of the service; rather than the question of the specific needs of groups?

  James Purnell: I think that is right, but I think it is also about making sure that the basic entry point, which is DTT, is suitable for those people. That is what I am saying is our clear commitment. At that basic entry level point the box will be easy to use for people over 75 and people with disabilities; they will have audio description for the blind; and we will look at how we can make it appropriate for people with other particular needs. When we provide that vulnerable package it will help those people with those particular issues and, in particular, address those issues. How easy it is to use the remote control, for example. How they can fit the technology. The vulnerable package will not be just about sending people a box and then telling them to get on with it. There will be a helpline, and if they are not able to fit it and to learn how to use it purely through the helpline they will get a home visit. That is what we have been trialling in Bolton, and the initial figures we have had, the new figures we have got, show that about one-fifth of people have required a home visit so far, and that is people all over 75. Four-fifths are able to fit the technology themselves with the help of family and friends or the helpline, and about one-fifth have required actual help where people go round and fit the box, look at the aerial and show them how to use the remote control. The vulnerable package will mean not only will those needs of people be directly addressed but they will also get benefit in terms of extra channels. I think an important point of this policy is that people who are isolated, who are older, with disabilities, who live by themselves, for them TV is a really important part of their social life. If you go from having four or five channels to having the range that DTT offers or the other platforms that is a real benefit and in some cases is a life-changing benefit.

  Q521  Paul Farrelly: The biggest by far in the table which has been provided as part of your evidence on the cost of switchover to the consumer is the aerial installation cost if needed. We have been particularly concerned on the Committee on the potential for aerial cowboys to exploit uncertainty. I just wanted to ask you, what considerations have you given and how robust do you want Digital UK to be in encouraging people, firstly, to use only accredited aerial installers, that is quality guidance; and, secondly, cowboys on the ball may forge the digital tick in going around, so how robust should we be in giving price guidance as well on what people can expect to pay and what they should not pay?

  Alun Michael: I think it is worth saying as a background to that when you are referring to aerials that at the moment in the areas where there is coverage for digital terrestrial television some 30% of people have to upgrade their aerial, which is obviously a cost; whereas after analogue switch-off and the boost of the signal it will be something like 3%. That is a very significant saving for the people who are involved directly. I think you are right about the importance of people being able to depend on the quality of the service that they receive. For that reason we have got a working group on the supply chain issues. Like the group that James just referred to, it is focusing very specifically on the question of the quality of service to the public. Secondly, we have got the digital installer training scheme in order to make sure that there is a quality of the skills of people to undertake the work. Clearly the timing of that relates specifically to the timetable region by region. I think you are right, that it is something which needs to be emphasised and very clear. It is something we are engaging with, with the industries concerned. I think the response we have had from industry is very much that they want to be able to give the guarantees of quality. It is an area we will continue to develop and we move towards the start of the programme.

  James Purnell: That is right. The digital tick obviously will be applying to those people as well as to equipment, and it will be one of the central roles of Digital UK to market that to the public so they know to look for the digital tick. I think the point you and the Committee have made about the price points is one which we need to think about. Obviously if you give us some recommendations we will look at those seriously.

  Q522  Mr Sanders: The cost benefit analysis that was undertaken by the Government, how central was it to the case for switchover?

  James Purnell: I think it is worth saying that we do believe the cost benefit analysis is a robust conservative piece of work. As Stephen Carter said if we did it again now it would be likely to be even more positive. It assumes, for example, the cost of a set-top box is going to be £50, and that is already out-of-date. It also assumes a very conservative use of the released spectrum. It would basically be used just for television uses. The key thing about the cost benefit analysis is that it was positive under all scenarios. It has been independently audited. We are going to be publishing that today and we have made it available to the Committee. We do not want to pretend this is a more theological or scientific process than it is. The purpose of the cost benefit analysis is to check your assumptions and your thinking; to work through your assumptions, make sure that they stand up to scrutiny and look at the evidence. I think it is an important and useful piece of work which helped to estimate the decision rather than which determined the decision.

  Alun Michael: I think it is fair to say that the memorandum that was submitted before the recess was carried out by a team involving the Treasury, and in line with the Treasury Green Book, but it has   also been subject, as James indicated, to independent academic examination and audit that has been undertaken by Professor Andrew Chesher from University College London. I suppose you can debate the values for the assumptions in the central case but, again as James said, conservative assumptions have been made, so in many ways it is a worse case scenario. In terms of the advantages to the public of the switchover those are very clear and major, so it does not just depend on the arithmetic within the cost benefit analysis.

  Q523  Mr Sanders: The amount of money to access digital television for the box, £25-£30, is widely quoted, but there does not seem to be any appreciation of some of the other costs. For example, to use that box you are going to need a Scart lead. A Scart lead can cost between £10-£15. It might not sound a lot to you or me but that could actually be a significant problem to somebody on a fixed income, even if they have got a free or subsided box. The costs of having a new aerial, if necessary, or testing the existing aerial, there are the on-costs of having gone digital. An extra piece of electrical equipment will increase their electricity costs. I do not think from what I have seen that all of these costs necessarily have been factored in. Have all of these costs been considered?

  James Purnell: I think they have. I think the cost benefit analysis certainly includes aerials; it includes the electricity costs; it also includes an analysis of consumer benefit based on survey work on consumers. We are confident that it has looked at all the relevant costs. If we did it again now it would be even more positive than it was then. Some of the points which are made about the cost benefit analysis are just worth correcting. For example one of your witnesses talked about the fact we said it was worth £900 and sort of implied it was per year to consumers to have these extra channels—actually that is the net present value of the extra channels over 20 years. Some of the wilder estimates of the costs of this you can only get at by assuming that every digital TV that has been purchased in the country has been as a result of the announcement which we made earlier last year, and clearly that is incorrect. Anybody who bought a digital TV before we made our announcement was not caused by an announcement. It is accepted Green Book methodology that any sunk costs like that are not taken into account. Going forward, we have made a very conservative assumption which is basically all second sets which are upgraded after our announcement are included as a cost, even though probably quite a lot of those would have been upgraded voluntarily.

  Alun Michael: I think there is another point here as well, because you referred to the cost that will be there for some people in terms of upgrading the aerial. The figure I gave earlier was that at the moment 30% have to upgrade an aerial if they are in an area where they have got digital terrestrial television converge; whereas after the signal boost, because the switch-off means that you can have a stronger signal, that will be down to 3%. What that effectively means is that in areas where the service is available at the moment people can either choose to wait for the date of switch-off or 27% of them are going to have to pay for having the aerial upgraded. So there is a cost in not switching off as well a cost to the consumer in the switch-off of analogue. All of the factors obviously have to be taken into account in reaching conclusions on what the policy should be.

  Q524  Mr Sanders: In terms of how this cost benefit analysis works in relation to the economy, are the benefits not partly generated as a result of people being compelled to buy equipment for their TVs; rather than any actual real economic value? Is that not an artificial cost benefit?

  Alun Michael: I think to refer to it as compulsion is artificial. The situation at the moment is that you have the developments into the late 60s of a percentage of people choosing to have digital television for at least one of their sets in a household. That is voluntary because people are assuming, as indeed I have done and many people in this room probably have, to have the increased number of channels and the quality that follows that. The point is that "no change" is not an option—there are costs involved in any decision, costs for consumers. I have just indicated the one in terms of the burden of upgrading aerials, because it is not possible to upgrade the signal until there is analogue switch-off. That is a cost; that is a burden. I think it is a question of making a balanced assessment, and making sure that we move forward. I referred at the beginning to the fact that we have a very well developed market, of a variety of different means of which digital terrestrial television is only one element. I think there is a graph (which if the Committee has not had it may be illuminating for you to have) showing the development of growth; which shows pay digital and digital terrestrial as the two major growth areas and the areas that now dominate as a result of choice; because this is in advance of anything of this sort. What we are doing is sensibly reflecting the technical developments and the choices that people are making and saying: how do we give certainty to people for the long-term future, while protecting the vulnerable in the way James has referred to but creating certainty, which does two things? It enables individuals, the consumer, to plan, but it also enables industry to plan and, therefore, to be able to be more competitive in providing the equipment and the services that people need.

  James Purnell: The only other thing I would just add to that briefly is that the cost of people who are compelled are included as a cost. Where people are facing costs imposed on them by the Government that is subtracted from the benefits and not added to the benefits. For example, as I mentioned, all those second sets are counted as a cost in the cost benefit analysis.

  Q525  Mr Sanders: Finally, on the cost savings for broadcasters for not transmitting both analogue and digital, have you considered any way that they could actually be passed on to the consumer, perhaps in the form of a reduced TV licence or in some other way?

  James Purnell: This is something we are looking at in the licence fee negotiations. I think we work slightly the other way round which is, if there are any increases or reductions in costs the BBC need to look at that in deciding the future level of the licence fee. That is exactly what they put in their proposals to us, and we are looking at that through independent consultants and will make decisions in due course.

  Alun Michael: The licence is a matter for James, but I would put it another way round, which is: if you were to insist on the continuation of analogue as well as digital you would be putting a burden on broadcasters and industry—a duplication in terms of the services which, at the end of the day, the consumer would have to pay for. The choice would be whether it was paid for directly or through taxation. At the end of the day, the burden has to be paid for some way, so the continuation of analogue really requires the answer to the question: who is going to pay for that continuation when it is clearly not a productive or sensible use of the finances that are necessary in order to provide it? Also because it then limits the use of spectrum; it limits the signal that can be used for digital and, therefore, limits the population that is going to be able to benefit from it; whereas the outcome of this will be that at least the 98.5% of people who receive adequate service now will receive the digital service.

  Q526  Paul Farrelly: With respect to costs, we have heard evidence on two counts particularly—there have been the marginal costs of going to 95% which is actually not significant, rather than 94 or 90 as they have got in Germany; and, secondly, if you ran the costs on the basis of a satellite model that would not necessarily come out more favourably. Clearly over the period, since these analyses and audits have been done of the cost benefits, Freesat has emerged more strongly. Have your Departments done a side-by-side analysis of a Freesat model and compared it with the digital terrestrial model that we are now looking at?

  James Purnell: Obviously we have that already today with the Freesat from Sky; and the costs of any Freesat offer from the BBC, ITV and the others would not be much different from that. Satellite, whether free or pay, broadband, cable, wireless, other technologies will provide a very important part of this. For people who want to pay for those extra services that will be a very important part of it for them. At the beginning of this inquiry there was a perception that it would be cheaper just to do the last 10% or 20% through satellite. I think the evidence you had from Arqiva showed that was not the case. Typically the cost for even the smallest relay station was around £150 and that compares to the cost of fitting each satellite of about £150. It is the most economically efficient way of doing it through DTT. It is also very important for the policy overall which is, if we were saying, "We're switching off your signal and in some places you're going to be able to get DTT but in other places you're not", it will be a very, very difficult message for Digital UK to communicate. I think it is important that we go for 98.5% through DTT.

  Alun Michael: I think you are right to concentrate on the cost and the challenge of the final percentage, whichever percentage you are looking at. In trying to deal with the 1.5%, which is what we are looking at at the moment, Ofcom has commissioned some research on this at the present time. I think it is one of those issues where it is quite difficult to keep up with the changes that are developing. I point to the example that we had in broadband where in a previous role I was very involved in this with colleagues at DTI on the question of broadband delivery in rural areas. What we found was, once there was a certainty about what was going to happen in terms of main provision, all of a sudden you are small providers, you had technical innovation, you had a variety of organisations coming up with new ideas; BT itself changing its approach. Therefore, the greater certainty we can give about the 98.5% the more likely it is that there will be a market response that would help towards meeting the provision in relation to the 1.5%, which of course then is going much further than the current availability of analogue. It is also the case of course that some of this depends on the nature of the international agreement which is the subject of debate during the summer months this year, although a lot of preparatory work has already been done. Therefore, it is going to be possible to be a lot more certain about how easy it is to deal with the edges—things like strength of signal and so on—within the course of the next few months.

  Q527  Chairman: Can I just come back to the cost benefit analysis. The costs are very clear—they are concrete expenditure on boxes, aerials and masts; but the benefits, a large part of them, you calculate as being imputed consumer benefit from compulsory migration. That seems to me to be the value to households of getting extra channels which they could get now but have chosen so far not to get?

  James Purnell: Yes, the net effect of those two things. So there is the cost for people who will be moving who do not have to move. As I have said to Adrian Sanders, we have been very conservative in that assumption. We are assuming that everybody from now on who upgrades a second or third set is being forced to do so in a compulsory way. So that cost is estimated. Then we look at the benefit to people having those channels. I think the point you are getting at there is that the cost benefit analysis does impute some benefit to people who got those channels after they got them, even if they had been forced to make that transition. I can see why that would appear slightly odd, but it is surely right. If someone is forced to make the change, you look at the cost to them of doing so—so buying the set and whatever—but then there is a benefit to them in terms of watching the channels. As our pilot in  Ferryside showed, people were extremely enthusiastic after getting digital, even many people who had said they did not want to have the set in the first place. It is just the accepted way of doing it in terms of Green Book methodology and I think it is quite clearly the appropriate way of doing it.

  Q528  Chairman: To put a monetary value on the fact that somebody who previously had never expressed a desire to have extra channels but now can get BBC Three, BBC Four and ITV 2, 3 and 4 and say, "That is worth so many pounds", is that not an entirely notional, artificial construct?

  James Purnell: No, you look at the cost of them doing so and you put that in the model and you look at any benefit from them looking at the channels.

  Q529  Chairman: How can you say that benefit is worth so many pounds to them?

  James Purnell: You do consumer research, which is exactly what we did and we are publishing that today; and then you get independent people, professors, to look at the assumptions you have made, and we are publishing that today and they have said that methodology is entirely appropriate. Even if we took that out, which would be wrong to do, but even if we did it is pretty clear that the cost benefit analysis would still be very significantly positive.

  Alun Michael: I think it is also worth pointing out, you suggested that the benefits are vaguer and the costs are settled. Actually that is not the case, because the reducing price of equipment, including the set-top box, changes over time. The other thing that changes over time is that as the audience increases the service that is provided goes up, and the certainty we are providing to broadcasters is likely to influence the way in which they undertake their work and, therefore, the value of what the consumer gets on both sides of the equation. They are estimates based on a methodology that is quite clear. It is not the same as a pound in your pocket, but it is a very carefully worked out attempt to quantify the costs and the benefits. I agree with James, I think it is absolutely clear that the benefits greatly outweigh the costs.

  James Purnell: Like any assumptions done by economists, sometimes they can look odd to the rest of us; but it is quite clear that people who do not want to switch at the moment are not saying they value the service at nothing; they are saying they value it less than the cost of the service. What you are trying to do in the cost benefit analysis is work out how much they do value it at. Is it £10 a year, £20 a year, or whatever. Then you put that in as a benefit and then the cost of them being forced to switch is put in as a cost.

  Q530  Chairman: There are plenty of people who have said to us, and I have no doubt have said to you, that actually they put zero value on getting extra channels. Indeed they have expressed to us that they positively do not want extra channels. Yet your analysis essentially is saying, "You may think that but actually once you get it you will find it's going to be very valuable"?

  James Purnell: No, we are not saying that everybody who values these services at nothing values them at something. We are saying that within those people who are refusing to switch, some of them value it at absolutely nothing; some people would value it at something, so they will watch the channels after they get them even though they have had to also shell out for a set-top box; and that is exactly the right way of doing it. That is clearly the right economic way.

  Alun Michael: If I could illustrate it from a personal perspective—I think I would have been amongst those who did not see the value of having extra access until having a digital box and then being able to access BBC Three and see the excellent analysis of that excellent Dr Who series produced in Cardiff, which gave a tremendous opportunity and one I took advantage of. If you ask me after the event: do I place value on having installed the digital box; the answer is, "Yes, I do now". I think the analysis is meant to reflect that sort of excitement, which I commend to members of the Committee.

  Q531  Mr Evans: Are you watching any other channel now, Alun?

  Alun Michael: No, that is the only one I have managed to make time for!

  Q532  Paul Farrelly: Put in plain language so I can understand it, it is like me going back to school and saying, "I will not eat my greens", but of course when forced to eat my greens there is a benefit that accrues to me from doing it.

  Alun Michael: You might even start to enjoy your greens!

  Q533  Mr Sanders: There is another way of looking at this. If BBC Radio 3 was taken away from you, would you then be prepared to pay for it?

  Alun Michael: I think that is a very good question. Probably the answer is, yes. That is purely a personal response as a consumer.

  Q534  Mr Sanders: You can also afford to pay for it.

  Alun Michael: Many of us, if you go over the years when BBC 2 started, when ITV started, might not in advance have placed a value on it, but will have placed a value on it subsequently.

  Q535  Mr Sanders: You did not pay for those, did you? You did not have to shell out anything.

  Alun Michael: No, indeed, but you put value on things even if you do not have to pay for them, surely? The question in the cost benefit analysis is: how do you reflect that value in some way? As James has said, because it is trying to analyse the economic benefits, the costs and the benefits, it has to have a methodology in order to do that in respect of things you are not paying for. Yes, there is a sense in which it is artificial but it is surely commonsense to try to do that.

  James Purnell: We will publish the research which this is based on today. In very simple terms, you look at the benefit which people have from asking how much they value their services. For some people it will be nothing; for other people it will be less than the cost of the service; all of those people, the non-voluntary switchers; then you look at the costs and you deduct one from the other. Just to serve these purposes, even if we took out the people who are being compelled to switch, if we did the analysis again today I am sure that it would stand up.

  Q536  Alan Keen: I can remember how much the ability of people to watch the parliamentary channel, including recording this on a Sunday night, made to the total valuation of it! I have not quite been able to bring myself to watch it yet!

  Alun Michael: I think that would come in the same category as Dr Who—they do not know what they are missing until they start watching!

  Q537  Alan Keen: As we have gone through the inquiry we tend to form opinions, obviously—I hope we do anyway. I am sure you will not mind if I make a couple of observations and then stick a question on the end. One of the most interesting series of inquiries that we did on this Committee before the turn of the century was the Dome. There were two lessons we learnt from that. The first one, which is just for your benefit and is not very important, is that there was a minister then who identified himself much too closely with the possible benefits; he fell into temptation and that gave the press the chance to really target him. So that is one good lesson. The main lesson to learn from that was that the big mistake (apart from not doing it at all) was that there should have been two chief executives instead of one. The first one did a great job delivering the structure and the services, but she was also in charge of the content which was a mistake—not that maybe she could not have done it but her main aim was to deliver because there were lots of problems over transport, so she was focused on that delivery. There should have been a chief executive also from the beginning who concentrated on the content of the Dome. In a way this is what is worrying me slightly. I was very impressed by the people we have listened to who have got various responsibilities, but I have a concern that somebody should be identified who is really looking at how to convince people to switch over before we get there. It is a great product, and the market itself is doing its best to sell products; but I still have not seen evidence of how we are trying to get to people who do not know the benefits of it; somebody who is marketing the product as a representative of Digital UK or whatever. I have asked these questions and had answers. It has been mentioned already today so we must have some concern about that. Are we doing absolutely everything to convince people to switch over early, which would reduce any cost at the end and reduce the number of sets that do not work when the switchover happens? Have you thought about that? Are you satisfied there is somebody focussing on that particularly?

  Alun Michael: Can I say, I think the biggest difference between digital switchover—and perhaps almost that term is misleading; what we are talking about is analogue switch-off—with the Dome you had a target for it to be ready, for the doors to open and for what was available to be there for the public. This is a quite different project. This is about drawing a line under a period of duplication and the end of a period of transition done region by region, because that is the way to get it tidy and to give certainty for both the consumers and the market, and certainty to the broadcasters as well as to who is going to be able to have access to their channels. It is also about making sure that the UK remains a leading country in terms of media and ICT more generally. I would stress a point that I made earlier on that, in order for switchover or analogue switch-off to take place in a region everything has to be in place, not just on the day when that takes place but well in advance, so that there is a period in which people know that it is on the first of whatever the month is that that is going to take place; and post that date, if they have prepared for it, they will be able to get the service that is promised in the new arrangement; and the certainty that they need to plan by that date. Obviously everything built in, in terms of support for the vulnerable as well as information for the public generally, is extremely important. I just underline one thing, which is that we ought to be trying to get across the degree of certainty in the information, particularly as we approach the relevant date region by region. James referred earlier to the fact that there is a freephone number for dealing with information needed by the vulnerable groups—which incidentally is 0800 519 2021—but there is also a general helpline number, which is a local rate number for anyone wherever you are in the country—which is 0845 6505050. Yes, it is very important indeed that we make sure people know what is happening; but, unlike the project that you made the comparison to, this is about the ending of a duality rather than about something new.

  Q538  Alan Keen: Maybe I have not clarified what I meant to get over properly. People are concentrating on the switch-off and that is where the big danger comes for everybody, all of us?

  Alun Michael: No, I am sorry, we are not concentrating on the switch-off. We are concentrating on preparing the ground so that there is not a great flurry of worry at a point when there is switchover. That has to be well before the date of the switch-off.

  Q539  Alan Keen: Yes, I understand that. The point I am making is that the danger point is when the switch-off comes. There is a switch-on and a switch-off in a limited period of time. The point I am making is, there would be much less danger if there were 100,000 people who had not switched over to digital rather than if there were half a million people who had not switched over to digital when that switch-off comes. In addition to the market itself and the selling of sets and the people who make money from selling the sets, is there anyone who is actually concentrating on telling people what a great product it is and to switch over now and do not wait for Sky or the BBC to convince you, it is a good product. I would like to see one person with that responsibility, to reduce the number of people left at the switch-off.

  James Purnell: I think that is a very good point. I think your point about the Dome precedent does actually show the idea of having one person trying to do everything actually is not necessarily the right way forward. Marketing is a key responsibility of Digital UK. The first work stream is on communications and the identified person for that is Beth Thoren. There is going to be a very ambitious marketing programme. I think Ford Ennals said it was not less than £100 million for this project. A key part of that will be doing exactly what Alan said, which is laying the ground so people know that they need to switch over and exactly how to do so. I think your point is absolutely right.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 29 March 2006